You are on page 1of 10

Research Policy 38 (2009) 736–745

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Research Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/respol

Professional guilds, tension and knowledge management


Ram Mudambi a , Tim Swift b,∗
a
Department of Strategic Management, Fox School of Business, Speakman Hall (006-00), Temple University, Philadelphia, PA 19122, USA
b
Management Department, Mandeville 380, Haub School of Business, St. Joseph’s University, 5600 City Avenue, Philadelphia, PA 19131, USA

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Scientific research is a crucial success factor for knowledge intensive firms and is often a joint effort
Received 4 April 2007 of scientists and managers. However, scientists and managers belong to different “professional guilds,”
Received in revised form 22 January 2009 subscribing to different belief systems and valuing different types of incentives. These differences give
Accepted 23 January 2009
rise to tension between scientists and managers. We integrate a large body of literature from knowledge
Available online 24 February 2009
management to develop a new theoretical model predicting that this organizational tension is affected by
environmental factors such as the degree of industry munificence, firm-specific factors like knowledge-
Keywords:
management policies, and the individual roles of boundary spanners within the firm. Further, we argue
Knowledge management
R&D
that this tension can lead to positive or negative outcomes.
Professional guilds © 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Tension

1. Introduction The drug industry is a success story. . . . Unless the drug industry
was given an opportunity to reap the harvests of its successes
It is not uncommon to observe tension in even the most suc- and to invest large portions of it in the development of its facil-
cessful organizations regarding the management of R&D. Today, ities and its research, this phenomenal success would not have
famous scientists working in high-performing firms understand been possible. Without the profit motive, and without the profits
that R&D must be conducted in order to create valuable commercial being reinvested in the industry, the state of the American phar-
knowledge in order to acquire sustainable competitive advantage. maceutical industry today would not be what it is (emphasis
For example, Nobel laureate Arno A. Penzias, as he was serving as added) (El Feki, 2005, p. 4).
vice-president of Research at AT&T Bell Laboratories, emphasized
Scientists and management may be said to belong to different
the importance of conducting research for commercially valuable
“professional guilds,” in the sense that they subscribe to different
purposes:
belief systems and recognize different measures of excellence.1 The
I want to still do fundamental research, but I also want people to different value systems of the two guilds lead to tension between
understand that they are doing it for a purpose. I said to every- R&D scientists and management because their goals overlap only
one, if you don’t like it, please leave (Buderi and Carey, 1993, p. partially (Barnard, 1938; Mayo, 1945; Shephard, 1956; Ouchi, 1980,
79). p. 130). This tension can drive inferior R&D policy decisions, or it can
contribute to a rich, diverse perspective that drives well-informed,
In some industries, the creation of knowledge is critical to
superior decisions.
acquiring sustainable competitive advantage. Much of this knowl-
edge creation depends on successful collaboration between firm
management and R&D scientists–on the mingling of the profit
motive that attracts investment capital, and the opportunity for
1
great scientific advancement that draws the world’s best scientists. American Heritage Dictionary formally defines a guild as “An association or
corporation of persons of the same trade, pursuits, or interests formed for their
A recent report from congressional hearings on the pharmaceuti-
mutual aid and protection, the maintenance of standards, or the furtherance of some
cal industry, where R&D intensity levels are almost 8% (National purpose.” This term is different from other related labels used in the literature. A pro-
Science Foundation, 2005) states: fessional guild is not an epistemic community (Gittelman and Kogut, 2003) because
scientists from different scientific disciplines are viewed as being members of sepa-
rate epistemic communities, yet they belong to the same guild. A professional guild
is not a community of practice (Brown and Duguid, 1991) because communities of
practice are comprised of individuals from many different areas of the firm (e.g.,
∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 215 499 7973; fax: +1 610 660 1229. accounting, marketing, engineering or science) that come together to work on a
E-mail addresses: ram.mudambi@temple.edu (R. Mudambi), tim.swift@sju.edu common task. Members of the same community of practice can be members of
(T. Swift). different guilds.

0048-7333/$ – see front matter © 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.respol.2009.01.009
R. Mudambi, T. Swift / Research Policy 38 (2009) 736–745 737

In this paper, our objective is threefold. First, to identify the 3 offers new research propositions. Section 4 discusses the ramifi-
sources of tension between R&D scientists and R&D managers. Sec- cations of these propositions. Section 5 concludes.
ond, to propose conditions under which that level of tension will
vary. Third, to provide insights into how tension can be managed 2. Major perspectives
to minimize its deleterious effects and harness its positive poten-
tial. Extant theory in knowledge management does not address
Most bodies of research on knowledge management do not adequately the tension between R&D scientists and management.
address this intra-organizational tension directly. We extend However, by drawing upon the literature in three major areas
these perspectives to show how the firm’s level of absorptive (absorptive capacity, social network theory, and knowledge appro-
capacity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989), the industry’s level of knowl- priability), we can uncover the sources of this tension. The key
edge appropriability (Jaffe, 1986; Cohen and Levinthal, 1990), contributions in each area are integrated below. We build upon
and the firm’s position within social and professional networks these important findings to develop a new understanding of intra-
(Granovetter, 1973; Burt, 1992) can influence the level of tension organizational tension.
between the professional guilds within the firm. We show how the Research shows that firms performing only applied research
level of tension can vary with environmental and firm-specific fac- underperform those conducting basic as well as applied research
tors, and explain ways in which the presence of this tension can (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989). Further, firms that prohibit or discour-
yield positive or negative firm outcomes. age their scientists from engaging in scholarly dialogue with their
In the middle of the last century, many argued that govern- professional peers outside the firm perform less efficient and effec-
ment and academia must take the lead in conducting basic research tive research (e.g., Cockburn and Henderson, 1998; Stern, 2004).2
because the free market does not provide adequate opportunity By discouraging scientists from conducting basic research or inter-
and incentive for it (Nelson, 1959). However, theory and practice acting with professional colleagues outside the firm, the firm’s
have evolved, and there is evidence that valuable basic research management can frustrate its scientists. Such discouragement can
is conducted in industry, as well as in collaborative relationships lead to situations where tension between management and R&D
between academia and industry (Arrow, 1962; Cohen and Levinthal, scientists is high.
1989; Cockburn and Henderson, 1998; Cockburn et al., 2004; There is a substantial body of literature concerned with various
Nelson, 1959; Tijssen, 2004). The firm is the nexus of opportu- aspects of knowledge management in the firm. Both appropri-
nity for investors and scientists. Value-seeking investors provide ating value from knowledge (Jaffe, 1986; Youndt et al., 2004)
capital to scientists so that they can create valuable knowledge. and the motivations of the firm’s scientists have received atten-
These scientists receive satisfaction and prestige from creating new tion (Osterloh and Frey, 2000; Stern, 2004). However, there has
knowledge. been little explicit recognition that these two pursuits within
The formation of different factions within the firm forming along knowledge-intensive firms may be potentially incompatible and
the lines of scientific and management objectives is particularly hence give rise to intra-organizational tension.
pronounced in research intensive firms. To management, knowl-
edge is a means to an end and excellence is measured in terms 2.1. Professional guilds
of market performance (Dasgupta and David, 1994; Gittelman and
Kogut, 2003, p. 367). To the scientist, knowledge can be an end Scholars have long recognized that two different value systems
in itself and excellence is measured in terms of the advancement exist within a single firm, having some shared goals but also some
of human understanding (Duncan, 1974, p. 523). In R&D intensive conflicting objectives (Hayek, 1945). Scientists and managers often
firms, market performance is critically dependent on the perfor- have incompatible goals and differing criteria for success, due to
mance of R&D scientists, and important interactions exist between the fact that they belong to different professional guilds. We use the
the work of R&D scientists and managers. term professional guild to refer to an association of people that are
Much of the existing research on knowledge management joined together by the common bonds of their profession. Members
provides clues on how tension between R&D scientists and manage- of the same professional guild can have different educational back-
ment originates and how it varies. We suggest that at the industry grounds (e.g., biochemistry vs. physics; accounting vs. marketing)
level, the level of knowledge appropriability, the presence and den- but subscribe to the same professional values.
sity of knowledge networks, and resource availability influence That tension exists between R&D scientists and management is
the level of tension between management and R&D scientists. At not a new observation. Shephard (1956) observed “frustration” in
the firm level, the effectiveness of boundary-spanning managers the relationship between managers and scientists: “Management
(Tushman, 1977) influences the level of tension, as well as the is frustrated by its inability to determine whether progress on a
impact such tension has on firm performance. project is as good as could be expected; the research staff is frus-
While tension has been characterized as a negative force in the trated by management’s inability to understand the nature of the
firm (La Porte, 1965; Shephard, 1956), we argue that this tension has technical problem” (299). La Porte (1965) identifies the “sources of
beneficial as well as adverse aspects. The negative aspect is related strain and tension between scientists and managers” (22) as “those
to the “frustration” (Shephard, 1956), and to traditional conflicts personal and organizational relationships which increase the per-
as described by agency theory (Bernardo et al., 2001); the positive ceived or recognized incompatibility of organization and scientific
aspect is related to the increased insight that is gained from bring- goals” (25).
ing multiple perspectives to problem-solving (Eisenhardt, 1989; Professional bonds develop as part of a common accultura-
Simons et al., 1999; Zaheer et al., 1998). Understanding the nature tion process. Members of the same professional guild form similar
and sources of intra-organizational tension enables us to mini- personal and business judgments on the basis of their shared pro-
mize the costs while fostering the benefits. Whether this tension fessional values. They solve problems using the same paradigms,
enhances or damages firm performance depends critically on the which influences the way they perceive issues and process infor-
capabilities and effectiveness of the boundary-spanning function
in the firm that brokers relationships between R&D scientists and
management. 2
Efficient R&D is research that maximizes outputs given the inputs to the pro-
Section 2 reviews the relevant literature in an effort to under- cess (Zander and Kogut, 1995). Effective R&D is research that meets important goals
stand the current state of knowledge management theory. Section (Kostova, 1999).
738 R. Mudambi, T. Swift / Research Policy 38 (2009) 736–745

mation (Kuhn, 1962). As a result, high levels of tension may exist to improve the market performance of the firm. Whether research
between corporate constituencies that are affiliated with different yields scientifically valuable knowledge is strictly secondary. The
professional guilds. In this paper, we develop a conceptual model specific focus of this discussion is on research and development
and a set of propositions that will improve our ability to identify and being conducted in profit-seeking firms. Setting aside the impact
understand the sources of tension between the professional guilds that knowledge appropriability, absorptive capacity, and the pres-
of management and scientists, how this level of tension can change, ence of knowledge networks may have on the level and quality of
and how the presence of this tension can enhance or damage firm research conducted by the firm, the level of financial pressure under
performance. Such an understanding will enable us to recognize which the firm operates is also an important determinant of R&D
opportunities to foster symbiosis between the two professional investment.
guilds. In countries that follow U.S. Generally Accepted Accounting
We now proceed to discuss the “tension” that exists and the Practices (GAAP), investment in tangible assets is capitalized and
“tradeoffs” that managers are forced to make between market and depreciated over the useful life of the asset, but R&D expenditures
scientific performance. In order to do so, we describe the conflicting are expensed currently by the firm (Financial Accounting Standards
objectives of scientists and managers that can give rise to tension. Board, SFAS No. 2). R&D expenses reduce current operating income
sharply, but capital investments reduce operating income modestly
2.1.1. Scientists’ objectives in each accounting period over the useful life of the investment. It
Prior research generally recognized two reward systems for sci- follows that firm managers perceive a greater impact to short-term
entists. Both of these incent scientists to disseminate the knowledge earnings performance when spending a dollar on R&D than when
that they create widely. Some researchers observe that members of spending one on capital. An R&D manager may make sub-optimal
the scientists’ professional guild are motivated by creating knowl- R&D expenditure decisions if he or she is faced with severe pressure
edge for knowledge’s sake. They have a “taste for science” (Merton, to meet short-term earnings targets.
1973; Dasgupta and David, 1994; Stern, 2004). New knowledge, Indeed, Baber et al. (1991) find support for the assertion that
whether it translates into commercially valuable innovations or “decisions to invest in R&D are influenced by managers’ concern
not, is valuable as long as it advances scientific understanding about reported earnings” (828). Perry and Grinaker (1994) find
(Shephard, 1956; Kuhn, 1962; Duncan, 1974). that managers reduce R&D expenditures when expected near-term
Osterloh and Frey (2000) help us to understand that the intrinsic earnings will deviate from analysts’ earnings expectations. Bushee’s
motivation of R&D workers can be more powerful than monetary (1998) findings are quite precise and informative; he offers evi-
rewards. They argue that intrinsic motivation is particularly valu- dence that firms that have high levels of institutional investors with
able when tacit knowledge must be transferred. Consistent with high portfolio turnover and engage in momentum trading are more
this argument, survey work done by Dhawan et al. (2002) indicates likely to reduce R&D to reverse an earnings decline. Firms with a
that knowledge workers believe that writing research papers is an greater propensity to cut R&D are likely to possess higher levels of
“energy-generating” activity within the firm. tension between managers and scientists because they are forced
Other researchers point to the formal reward system that to make more difficult choices between R&D and current earnings
exists in scientific communities. This system encourages scien- performance.
tists to share important discoveries and innovations rather than In addition to implementing budgetary control, management
hoard them. Researchers recognize that a “winner-take-all” reward may restrict R&D scientist activities in other ways. In contrast to
(Sorenson and Fleming, 2004, p. 1616) system exists for those the scientists’ desire for primacy, managers prefer secrecy (Cyert
who are first to place a new discovery in a peer-reviewed domain and March, 1963). Such restrictions can arise from the firm’s envi-
(Merton, 1957; Dasgupta and David, 1994). Primacy is a key com- ronmental conditions. For example, McGaughey (2002) asserts:
ponent of the scientific guild’s measures of excellence. Scientists “Network centrality enhances awareness of threats to intellectual
that are recognized for making important discoveries receive indi- asset (IA) scarcity, and, thus, the likelihood of an IA owner’s engag-
rect and direct rewards such as citations, prizes, research grants, ing in strategic interventions” that can enhance or defend the rents
endowed chairs and even fame (Merton, 1957; Dasgupta and David, appropriable from that IA (263). Earlier, we noted that Burt (1992)
1994; Sorenson and Fleming, 2004). Thus, ceteris paribus, firms that shows that a firm’s position in a knowledge network enhances its
permit their scientists to publish their research findings should ability to appropriate value. By locating itself centrally within net-
observe less tension between scientists and managers. works, a firm can become more aware of threats to its IA’s, and
Among the first substantive findings that show that enabling therefore become better prepared to defend them. In the process of
R&D workers to publish is a good motivator is Henderson and placing stronger protections on the firm’s IA’s, managers can frus-
Cockburn’s research (1994) showing that firms that promote scien- trate R&D scientists who value sharing their scientific work with
tists on the basis of their publication activity generate higher R&D professional colleagues.
output. Similarly, Cockburn and Henderson (1998) show that the
relationship between research productivity and co-authorship is 2.2. Knowledge appropriability and R&D intensity
positive and statistically significant. Research continues to emerge
revealing productivity advantages by permitting scientists to pub- This literature seeks to understand how knowledge appropri-
lish. Stern (2004) finds empirical evidence that scientists pay to be ability affects the firm’s R&D intensity. Intuitively, it may seem
scientists. He shows that the salaries of non-academic scientists that R&D intensity and knowledge appropriability would be posi-
that are provided relatively little research freedom are statistically tively related. We might expect that R&D intensity would be higher
significantly higher than the salaries of non-academic scientists (lower) in markets where appropriability is higher (lower), because
that are provided relatively greater research freedom. Further, this the firm is able (unable) to protect the knowledge it creates through
salary differential represents a significant percentage of scientists’ its own R&D. However, empirical research has provided evidence
annual earnings. of a negative relationship between knowledge appropriability and
R&D intensity: industries with lower knowledge appropriability are
2.1.2. Managers’ objectives characterized by higher R&D intensity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990;
The professional guild of management stresses market out- Jaffe, 1986).
comes. To a manager, knowledge is a means to an end (Dasgupta and Cohen and Levinthal (1990) find that highly interdependent
David, 1994; Gittelman and Kogut, 2003). The ultimate objective is industries, which can be characterized by the ease with which
R. Mudambi, T. Swift / Research Policy 38 (2009) 736–745 739

competitors learn from each other, have lower appropriability and Zucker et al. (1998) find that biotech firms are clustered near uni-
higher R&D. Jaffe (1986) confirms empirically that “the existence versities with “star scientists.” Further, Zucker et al. (2002) detect
of technologically related research efforts of other firms . . . allow a research productivity boost—those co-located firms have statisti-
a given firm to achieve results with less research effort than oth- cally significantly higher levels of patents and patent citations. It is
erwise” (984). He finds that a firm’s patents per dollar of R&D, and reasonable to conclude that firms centrally located within knowl-
the firm’s accounting profits, are positively related to the level of edge networks are better able to appropriate critical information
R&D of competing firms in the industry. This provides evidence that from their environment, and combine it with their own internally
it is knowledge spillovers that underpin the negative relationship generated knowledge to create valuable innovations. Since such
between knowledge appropriability and R&D intensity; firms that firms generally conduct more efficient and effective R&D, man-
are able to leverage knowledge created by competitor firms are able agers see a more direct link between basic research and market
to conduct more efficient R&D. performance. This serves to align the interests of firm managers
Intuitively, we can extend these insights to see how the level of and scientists.
industry knowledge appropriability is linked to the organizational While literature on the theory of social networks helps us to
tension in R&D intensive firms. Firms that compete in indus- understand the fundamental social forces that enable knowledge to
tries characterized by low knowledge appropriability are either travel, research on knowledge spillovers provides insights on how
unable or not incented to protect their proprietary knowledge knowledge travels. By bringing together these two literatures, we
from competitors. However, firms that compete in high knowledge can develop a holistic view of the dynamics of knowledge transfer
appropriability industries are able to protect their valuable pro- and how it relates to the tension between scientists and managers
prietary knowledge. Such firms in markets characterized by high within knowledge-intensive firms.
levels of knowledge appropriability should implement knowledge- Cockburn and Henderson (1998) use co-authoring as evidence
management policies that defend their knowledge base from of real collaboration between entities. They argue that co-authoring
competitors (McGaughey, 2002). These restrictions can increase is a more rigorous form of collaboration, as citations become ritu-
tension between management and R&D scientists. alized and are, in the age of the word processor and internet “cheap
and easy” (165). Yet co-authorship represents a real, tangible shar-
ing of information and effort, and is found to significantly affect
2.3. Absorptive capacity
research productivity. They offer a compelling finding: the extent
to which firms are linked to the public sector by co-authorships is an
Cohen and Levinthal (1989) introduced the concept of “absorp-
important determinant of the firms’ creation of important patents.
tive capacity.” They suggest that R&D not only generates new
Cohen and Levinthal (1989) also apply this theory well; they found
information, but also enhances the firm’s ability to assimilate and
firms linked to the public sector through co-authorships create
exploit existing information. A firm’s absorptive capacity refers to
more important patents. These findings highlight the importance
the firm’s ability to capture and leverage publicly available infor-
of structural holes (Burt, 1992; Granovetter, 1973) in our study. A
mation. They find that the relationship between appropriability,
structural hole exists in a network when two entities are not con-
technological opportunity (the ability to capitalize on new technol-
nected via the existing network. Firms that occupy structural holes
ogy in commercially valuable ways) and R&D intensity is moderated
in knowledge networks have better access to the knowledge con-
by the firm’s ability “to recognize, assimilate and exploit informa-
tained within those networks, because all information that flows
tion” (593).
between these unconnected firms must pass through the entity that
Currently, no one has linked the concept of absorptive capacity
occupies the structural hole.
to the level of tension between R&D scientists and management. Yet
Gittelman and Kogut (2003) tie knowledge management
firms that recognize the inherent value of basic research in creating
research to network theory in a profound way. They find that
absorptive capacity can avoid unnecessary tension. By funding basic
useful scientific innovation is generated by a subset of scientists
research, management not only fulfills scientists’ desire to pursue
that is active in creating both scientific publications and patented
pure science, but also provides scientists with the experience that
research. In other words, these scientists occupy structural holes in
enables them to be value-adding applied scientists.
knowledge networks and have the unique ability to translate pure
science into commercially valuable innovations.
2.4. Knowledge spillovers and social network theory We can build upon the findings regarding knowledge spillovers
and social network theory to provide important insights into the
A key aspect of knowledge management in firms is the role of origins of the tension between management and R&D scientists. A
knowledge spillovers. Should the firm “share” or “hoard” knowl- higher likelihood that a firm’s proprietary knowledge can spill over
edge? Permitting or encouraging knowledge workers to publish to competitors is associated with a higher level of tension between
their findings allows them to share knowledge with professional firm management and R&D scientists. In markets where knowledge
colleagues, and become members of knowledge networks. How- spillovers are more likely, firm management is compelled to take
ever, such publication activity could disclose sensitive competitive a more active role in protecting the firm’s proprietary knowledge.
information, thereby imposing costs to the firm (Mudambi, 2008). Thus, firm management is more likely to manage the activities of
Assessing the cost-benefit tradeoffs of firm R&D policy with respect R&D scientists closely, thereby increasing tension.
to publication incentives requires an understanding of how pub-
lished research travels through knowledge networks. 2.5. Tension and boundary spanners
Gulati et al. (2000) tell us that the “. . . image of atomistic actors
competing for profits against each other in an impersonal mar- Certain individuals are well-placed to be able to influence the
ketplace is increasingly inadequate in a world in which firms are impact that tension has on firm decision-making. While research
embedded in networks of social, professional, and exchange rela- generally implies that boundary spanners (Tushman, 1977; Kostova
tionships with other organizational actors” (203). Entities that are and Roth, 2003) are individuals that facilitate relationships between
located more centrally in networks tend to benefit by having more firms (Friedman and Podolny, 1992), we suggest that boundary
social capital (Walker et al., 1997). The theory of social networks spanners exist within the firm–brokering relationships between
helps us to understand how R&D scientists benefit from participa- different constituencies inside the firm. Such individuals have the
tion in certain networks of relationships. special insights required to skillfully balance the needs of the
740 R. Mudambi, T. Swift / Research Policy 38 (2009) 736–745

Fig. 1. Tension and boundary spanning in knowledge-intensive firms.

scientific and management guilds within the firm (Kostova and environments within which R&D is conducted, and provide incen-
Roth, 2003). tives for R&D production. The tools that the firm manager uses to
Previous research supports the assertion that boundary span- influence the work of scientists are the amount of funding allo-
ners in the firm can improve R&D performance. McMillan et al. cated to discrete research efforts, the rules and practices that govern
(1995) show that a higher the percentage of science Ph.D.’s in top scientists’ work and the incentives made available to those scien-
management is associated with more productive the R&D activi- tists. The R&D scientists are those that conduct basic and/or applied
ties. Boundary spanners are particularly effective individuals when research and create new knowledge. Their activities can influence
it comes to mitigating tension. Highly effective boundary spanners both the state of scientific knowledge, and the performance of the
may be able to leverage tension to create superior outcomes. The firms within which they operate. Boundary spanners are individu-
tension experienced by individuals in learning organizations can als that balance the conflicting objectives of each constituency and
lead to “a sustained sense of energy and enthusiasm, which . . . work to find common ground. These constituencies, and their rela-
produces . . . tangible results, which can then make the energy and tionships to one another, are represented in a comprehensive way
enthusiasm stronger” (Senge, 1994, p. 426). in Fig. 1.
Boundary spanners’ crucial contribution is the creation of trust The managers’ professional guild and the scientists’ professional
between organizations (Richter et al., 2006; Casson and Cox, 1993). guild are represented as fairly dense knowledge networks, with
When boundary-spanning individuals foster the creation of trust, very few ties between them. The firm’s managers and scientists
negotiations have been found to proceed more easily (Currall and occupy nodes within the business and scientific professional guilds,
Judge, 1995). “Negotiations are less costly under conditions of high respectively. Relatively few individuals reside in both networks.
interorganizational trust because agreements are reached more Boundary spanners serve the critical role of brokering ties
quickly and easily as parties are more readily able to arrive at a between the scientific and management professional guilds
‘meeting of the minds”’ (Zaheer et al., 1998, p. 144). Further, research (Friedman and Podolny, 1992; Kostova and Roth, 2003; Tushman,
suggests that decisions that involve diverse viewpoints drive supe- 1977). Such individuals are critically important to the relationships
rior results (Simons et al., 1999). Eisenhardt (1989) shows that between the business community, the scientific community, and
teams that are highly effective at decision-making in fast-paced the firm (Gittelman and Kogut, 2003). For example, Shephard (1956)
environments utilize the entire team to reach decisions, without recognizes that the effective R&D manager will understand the
permitting conflict to slow the decision: “Every team making fast needs of multiple constituencies within the firm simultaneously. He
decisions took an active approach to conflict . . . a team attempts to can be the special person who can “interpret” the needs of a team at
reach consensus by involving everyone” (562). Since R&D-related the operational level to higher levels of management, and help such
decisions necessarily involve input from both professional guilds, teams understand management’s requirements (Shephard, 1956, p.
internal boundary spanners are uniquely able to mitigate the ten- 303). Whether tension in the R&D investment decision-making pro-
sion between these constituencies. cess results in a superior outcome rests on the effectiveness of the
boundary-spanning function in the firm.
2.6. Fitting it all together: implications for knowledge creation
3. Towards a new predictive model
Previously, we have identified two professional guilds within the
knowledge-intensive firm: R&D scientists and management. Mem- In general, the tension between scientists and managers is influ-
bers of firm management are those that create and maintain the enced by industry, firm, and role-specific forces. In our research
R. Mudambi, T. Swift / Research Policy 38 (2009) 736–745 741

Table 1
Relevant literature on knowledge management.

Category Author(s) Key Takeaways


Knowledge • Jaffe (1986) Firms conduct more productive R&D in industries where
appropriability R&D • Zucker et al. (2002) knowledge appropriability is lower.
intensity
• Cohen and Levinthal (1989) Firms that conduct more basic research are more capable of
Absorptive capacity • Cohen and Levinthal (1990) identifying and leveraging publicly available information
• Tijssen (2004) into valuable innovations.

• Burt (1992)
Firms that are centrally located in knowledge networks are
• Granovetter (1973)
Social and professional more capable of acquiring valuable knowledge from the
• Gulati et al. (2000)
networks network. Entities that occupy structural holes in networks
• Powell et al. (1996)
are more capable of capturing information.
• Walker et al. (1997)

• Cockburn and Henderson (1998)


• Gittelman and Kogut (2003) Firms that link their R&D to the public sector perform
Knowledge spillovers
• Jaffe et al. (1993) generate more valuable scientific innovations.
• Zucker et al. (1998)

• Cockburn et al. (2004)


The intrinsic motivation to conduct “pure science” can be
• Dhawan et al. (2002)
more powerful than monetary rewards for R&D scientists.
• Henderson and Cockburn (1994)
Implications for firm Permitting scientists to publish while employed by a firm
• McGaughey (2002)
strategy drives more productive R&D. Firms are likely to make
• McMillan et al. (1995)
“strategic interventions” to protect the value of their
• Osterloh and Frey (2000)
intellectual assets under certain conditions.
• Stern (2004)

propositions, we identify the factors that influence the level of ten- benefit by conducting research that internalizes and leverages that
sion between R&D scientists and management. Further, we will external information. In industries with low knowledge appropri-
suggest that certain individuals within the firm are well-placed ability, two phenomena can drive the same outcome. First, because
to mitigate this tension, or even channel it to generate superior there is more publicly available information to leverage, R&D man-
outcomes. agers are more likely to invest in research. Second, since firm
We can leverage the cited literatures (Table 1) to frame management recognizes that knowledge appropriability is low, it
research propositions about the interactions between the firm’s realizes that restricting firm scientists from interacting with the
R&D managers and scientists. Research Propositions 1 through 5 scientific community (e.g., publishing) has little effect on the firm’s
are summarized in the following graphic (Fig. 2). market performance.
Absorptive capacity may be particularly important in industries
where knowledge appropriability is low, since in such industries, Proposition 1. In industries where knowledge appropriability is low,
more publicly available information exists. Therefore, firms can less tension will exist between R&D management and scientists.

Fig. 2. The interaction of tension and individual, firm and industry contexts.
742 R. Mudambi, T. Swift / Research Policy 38 (2009) 736–745

As noted in the accounting literature, ceteris paribus, firms fac- Granovetter, 1973). If a firm occupies a structural hole in a knowl-
ing earnings pressure are less willing to sustain investments in basic edge network, it can appropriate more knowledge than other firms
research (Baber et al., 1991; Bushee, 1998; Elliot et al., 1984; Perry in the same network that do not occupy structural holes. In the
and Grinaker, 1994). There are several situations in which a firm same way that network centrality should lead to less tension, occu-
is more likely to face difficult financial conditions. Each of these pying structural holes should enable the firm to exploit external
industry situations is addressed by the concept of “munificence.” information well, and to align the interests of R&D scientists and
Munificence is “generally seen as the extent to which an environ- managers.
ment can provide sufficient resources for the firms present in it”
Proposition 4. Firms occupying structural holes within knowledge
(Sharfman and Dean, 1991, p. 685). A fast growing industry is not
networks have less tension between R&D management and scientists.
necessarily munificent if it holds many firms; and a slow grow-
ing industry may be munificent if it has high barriers to entry and The ability to balance effectively the concerns of scien-
few firms (Bain and Qualls, 1987). Therefore, the munificence con- tists and management is a special and rare skill. Often, the
cept captures the aspects of industry competitiveness, growth and boundary-spanning function resides within the R&D management
maturity. function—those individuals charged with administering the day-
Previous research posits that firms in munificent industries to-day R&D team activities. It has been suggested that this unique
place a higher emphasis on innovation (Dess and Beard, 1984; ability to bridge the gap between two organizational sub-groups
Sharfman and Dean, 1991; Castrogiovanni, 1991). Aragon-Correa that are sometimes at odds make boundary spanners valuable
and Sharma (2003) argued that “conditions of scarcity in the gen- (Kostova and Roth, 2003, p. 304). Boundary spanners that identify
eral business environment make it more difficult to establish the with the logic of both the managerial and scientific professional
organizational and managerial processes, resources, and capabili- guilds can be particularly effective at crafting agreements that can
ties necessary for developing the dynamic capability of a proactive translate tension into effective R&D decision-making.
environmental strategy” (81). Firms in munificent industries are
more likely to be able to acquire the resources necessary for devel- Proposition 5. Boundary-spanning managers can mitigate the ten-
oping capabilities (Decarolis and Deeds, 1999). sion in between R&D scientists and management.
In highly munificent industries, the relative availability of If boundary spanners fail to foster consensus between manage-
resources, low competitive pressures and less pressure on finan- ment and R&D scientists, they fail to increase the level of trust
cial performance means that R&D managers will be less stringent between the professional guilds, and firm performance suffers. Lack
in reviewing and approving R&D investments. This, in turn, gives of trust increases the likelihood of opportunism, rent-seeking and
R&D scientists more freedom to pursue the R&D projects they find drawn-out, costly negotiations (Williamson, 1975; Mudambi and
appealing. Navarra, 2004). Alternatively, if trust does exist between the guilds,
Proposition 2. Firms in more munificent industries will experience each side is more likely to be open-minded (Zaheer et al., 1998).
less tension than firms in less munificent industries. The diverse viewpoints brought to the decision-making processes
can result in superior results. Breakthrough innovations occur more
Network centrality can be an important determinant of a firm’s often when firms reach beyond familiar sources of ideas (Ahuja
absorptive capacity. Jaffe et al. (1993) find that knowledge travels and Lampert, 2001). Utilizing multiple points of view can enhance
locally—local networks matter. Powell et al. (1996) posit that firms the firm’s ability to find groundbreaking solutions. For example,
more centrally located within knowledge networks generate higher Simons et al. (1999) find that decision-making teams that have
subsequent growth. A strong body of research shows that firm man- higher inter-member diversity, and engage in more debate, have
agers seek to place their scientists within important knowledge a strong positive effect on firm performance.
networks. A firm that is centrally located in a knowledge network
may be more aware of threats to its intellectual assets, thereby tak- Proposition 6. The trust that can be created by boundary span-
ing more proactive steps to protect their value (McGaughey, 2002). ners positively moderates the relationship between intraorganizational
Because firms that are centrally located in a knowledge network tension between R&D scientists and managers and firm performance.
have greater and faster access to the information contained within
the network, such firms will perceive competitive threats more 4. Discussion
astutely than firms less centrally located. As a result, they can do a
better job at undertaking only those management actions that serve A significant body of research finds that higher R&D output is
to prevent spillover to competitors, and avoid frustrating scientists associated with non-financial incentives (Cockburn and Henderson,
unnecessarily. This managerial ‘light touch,’ in turn, leads to more 1998; McMillan et al., 1995; Mudambi et al., 2007). Osterloh and
commercially productive knowledge creation (i.e., more intellec- Frey (2000) knit together a broad base of theory and research to
tual assets) and less tension between scientists and management. argue for the power of intrinsic motivators to drive the performance
In contrast, a firm located less centrally will have inferior access to of R&D scientists. It has been shown that scientists accept less pay
information on competitive threats, and is more likely to undertake in order to conduct quality science on the job (Stern, 2004) and that
ineffective strategic interventions that lower scientists’ morale. they produce superior research outcomes when they are allowed
However, this role of knowledge networks depends upon the greater control of their environment (Mudambi et al., 2007). This
level of absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989) possessed literature reminds us of the tenuous influence that the R&D man-
by the firm. In order to be able to recognize and assimilate the agement exercises over the scientists upon which it depends for
knowledge available from knowledge networks, firms must possess knowledge creation. Tension exists between R&D scientists and firm
absorptive capacity. management; the primacy-based motives of scientists are often in
direct conflict with the secrecy-based motives of managers.
Proposition 3. In firms more centrally located within knowledge net-
This paper directly confronts the challenge of this tension. We
works, less tension will exist between R&D scientists and managers.
find that the major schools of thought in knowledge management
This relationship is moderated by the level of the firm’s absorptive
provide valuable insights into the sources and the nature of ten-
capacity.
sion. We offer ways to predict how tension will change, and make
A review of the literature also indicates support for the value several new recommendations for either mitigating the tension, or
of occupying structural holes within social networks (Burt, 1992; for channeling it into positive outcomes. Our research propositions,
R. Mudambi, T. Swift / Research Policy 38 (2009) 736–745 743

based on solid theoretical foundations, provide a framework for a amount to the group (Ancona and Caldwell, 1992, p. 638). This
new line of research on normative R&D management. requires sufficient immersion in each professional guild to recog-
nize its values and strengths as well as to gain the acceptance of its
4.1. Managing and mitigating tension members.
Boundary spanners utilize a range of tools to resolve conflict
As discussed, the mitigation of tension between these profes- and provide the two guilds with shared understanding, values and
sional guilds can be achieved through individual or organizational goals. The guilds’ value systems typically coalesce around specific
means. At the organizational level, a firm can proactively manage its use of language, jargon and mental models. Boundary spanners can
participation in social networks. In situations where the firm is not help in developing and implementing firm-specific language, rou-
centrally located, or does not occupy structural holes in the right tines (including standardized forms and knowledge recording) and
knowledge networks, R&D management can support policies that operating procedures that are sensitive to the value systems of both
will increase the firm’s interaction with such networks. Increased guilds, thereby serving as integrating devices (Carlile, 2002).
publication from R&D scientists (Henderson and Cockburn, 1994) Recent case study research provides an exemplar of a boundary-
and co-authorships between the firm’s R&D scientists and public spanning member of executive management who improved the
sector scientists (Cohen and Levinthal, 1998; Gittelman and Kogut, performance of the R&D function within the division that he man-
2003) are two examples offered by previous scholars for improving ages (Hill et al., 2009). This executive works for a diversified
network ties.3 While management may view work hours devoted manufacturing firm and holds a Ph.D. in the same discipline as most
to the preparation of published research as lost time (Shephard, of his R&D scientists. For the first two years after he assumed this
1956), or worse as aiding competitors (Nelson, 2004), investing position, he conducted R&D project reviews personally, “rolling up
R&D resources into such efforts can create other important bene- his sleeves” and immersing himself in the details of many R&D
fits. Firms can receive more valuable tacit knowledge than they give projects. Over time, his interaction with the R&D project teams
away by permitting their scientists to engage in public scholarly dia- created an in-depth understanding of how the R&D teams could
logue with scientists from other organizations. It may be wise for conduct top-notch research whilst at the same time meeting the
firms to permit scientists to trade some of their time spent solving division’s financial targets.
the firm’s near-term problems for time spent building knowledge In this role, he was able not only to communicate relentlessly
networks outside the firm. the division’s business objectives, but also to help R&D scientists to
At the individual level, firms can place boundary spanners in understand how reasonable revisions to their efforts could support
roles that enable them to build trust between the two professional the division’s overall business success. Thus by being able to pro-
guilds. Boundary spanners may not only mitigate tension, but also vide valuable technical feedback and advice to R&D scientists while
may be able to leverage tension to generate superior outcomes. By also communicating the tangible aspects of the division’s busi-
increasing the level of trust between R&D scientists and managers ness objectives, this executive vice-president became an effective
(Zaheer et al., 1998), boundary spanners enable the two guilds to boundary spanner.
reach agreement more quickly (Williamson, 1975). When decision-
making units that have highly diverse viewpoints work together 4.2. Incentive systems
in a trusting way, they are able to move rapidly and generate real
synergies (Eisenhardt, 1989; Simons et al., 1999). The tension between the managers’ objectives of secrecy and the
Carlile (2002) posits that effective boundary spanners achieve scientists’ objectives of primacy may be related to the incentives
three objectives. First, they establish a “shared syntax,” (Carlile, faced by the two guilds. Managers are offered increasingly lucra-
2002, p. 451), which enables both constituencies to share their tive financial incentives based on firm performance (Pekkarinen
knowledge with each other. Second, they provide individuals from and Riddell, 2008). This focuses their attention almost solely on
each constituency with a way to understand the “differences and capturing financial returns from the firm’s R&D expenditure, with
dependencies” Carlile, 2002, p. 452) that exist across the bound- the underlying knowledge creation merely a means to an end.
ary. Third, they provide members from both guilds an opportunity In contrast, the scientists’ guild face an incentive system
to jointly transform their knowledge in order to achieve superior composed of relatively modest (fixed) pecuniary and variable non-
outcomes. pecuniary payoffs. Therefore the non-pecuniary payoffs in the
It has been pointed out that boundary spanners need to build form of prizes, acclaim and research grants became dominant
bridges not only across functions but also across levels within the (Scotchmer, 2004). This desire for primacy and consequent acclaim
firm. It has been shown that successful organizational teams build has a long history. It has been documented that Galileo limited
ties to top management as well as to teams in other functional areas access to his telescope in order to preserve his primacy and to
(Ancona and Caldwell, 1992). These teams contain individuals that ensure credit for subsequent discoveries (Biagioli, 2006).
are able to communicate their core values to gain the attention of It is interesting to consider the extent to which the different
non-members and shape their beliefs and behaviors (Bouquet and incentive structures explain the differing value systems of the two
Birkinshaw, 2008). Teams that remain isolated within functional professional guilds. There is evidence that in fields like biomedicine,
silos are less successful. This suggests that boundary spanning is where R&D work has significant and direct commercial value, scien-
composed of developing and sustaining an external rather than an tists are less willing to publicize their findings (Cohen and Walsh,
internal orientation. Boundary spanners are able to negotiate and 2008). It is possible that this “privatization of the scientific com-
coordinate with members of other professional guilds. It is often mons” (Nelson, 2004, p. 456) may serve to align the interests of
necessary for them act as a buffer between the guilds by “filtering” managers and scientists. In the case of young biotechnology ven-
out troubling information from outsiders and delivering a smaller tures, increasing the financial incentives available to R&D scientists
has been shown to make the objectives and scientists and managers
more compatible (Argyres and Liebskind, 2000). Incentive align-
ment may serve as an organizational tool to reconcile the objectives
3
It is important to note that improvements to firm policies can be effective only if of the two professional guilds, by increasing the pool of boundary
the firm also has competent R&D management and marketing. If marketing is unable
to exploit great research, or if R&D does not yield anything of commercial value, then
spanners. This is a fruitful avenue for future research.
no change in the amount of participation in knowledge networks can improve the The findings presented here remind us that knowledge-
situation. intensive firms must not only recruit talented senior managers and
744 R. Mudambi, T. Swift / Research Policy 38 (2009) 736–745

gifted R&D scientists, but also individuals that are uniquely able Barnard, C., 1938. The Functions of the Executive. Harvard, Cambridge, MA.
to enhance trust and communication between professional guilds. Bernardo, A.E., Cai, H., Luo, J., 2001. Capital budgeting and compensation with
asymmetric information and moral hazard. Journal of Financial Economics 61,
These boundary spanners need not possess the impressive creden- 311–344.
tials of seasoned executives or “star scientists” (Zucker et al., 2002). Biagioli, M., 2006. Galileo’s Instruments of Credit: Telescopes, Images, Secrecy. Uni-
However, without such individuals, the negative consequences of versity of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Bouquet, C., Birkinshaw, J., 2008. Weight versus voice: how foreign subsidiaries gain
the tension between the professional guilds described in this paper attention from corporate headquarters. Academy of Management Journal 51 (3),
may be insurmountable. 577–601.
Brown, J.S., Duguid, P., 1991. Organizational learning and communities-of-practice:
toward a unified view of working, learning and innovating. Organization Science
5. Conclusion 2, 40–58.
Buderi, R., Carey, J., 1993. American inventors are reinventing themselves. Business
Week.
The purpose of this article is to develop a framework that can
Burt, R.S., 1992. Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Harvard Uni-
be used to identify the sources of tension between R&D scientists versity Press, Cambridge, MA.
and managers within the firm, the factors that cause this tension to Bushee, B., 1998. The influence of institutional investors on myopic R&D investment
behavior. Accounting Review 73, 305–333.
vary, and to identify the ways that tension can benefit or damage
Carlile, P.R., 2002. A pragmatic view of knowledge and boundaries: boundary objects
firm knowledge creation. This framework draws upon the literature in new product development. Organization Science 13 (4), 442–455.
on absorptive capacity, knowledge spillovers, knowledge appropri- Castrogiovanni, G.J., 1991. Environmental munificence: a theoretical assessment.
ability and social network theory. We use this framework to develop Academy of Management Review 16 (3), 542–565.
Casson, M.C., Cox, H., 1993. International business networks: theory and history.
several propositions. Business and Economic History 22, 42–53.
The level of knowledge appropriability and munificence in the Cockburn, I., Henderson, R., 1998. Absorptive capacity, coauthoring behavior, and the
industry, as well as key characteristics of the knowledge networks organization of research in drug discovery. Journal of Industrial Economics 46,
157–182.
in which the firm operates, will impact the level of tension between Cockburn, I., Henderson, R., Stern, S., 2004. Balancing Incentives in Pharmaceutical
R&D scientists and managers. Firms occupying structural holes in Research. Northwestern University, Evanston, IL.
knowledge networks will experience lower tension, as will firms Cohen, W.M., Levinthal, D.A., 1989. Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&D.
Economic Journal 99, 569–596.
that are centrally located in knowledge networks. Boundary span- Cohen, W.M., Levinthal, D.A., 1990. Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learn-
ners that help to integrate knowledge from both the scientific and ing and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly 35, 128–152.
management professional guilds into decisions can mitigate ten- Cohen, W.M., Walsh, J.P., 2008. Real impediments to academic biomedical research.
NBER Innovation Policy & the Economy 8 (1), 1–30.
sion effectively, or even leverage tension for superior results.
Currall, S.C., Judge, T.A., 1995. Measuring trust between organizational boundary
The tension between R&D scientists and management is a role persons. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 64, 151–
double-edged sword. Permitting R&D scientists to interact with 170.
Cyert, R.M., March, J.G., 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Prentice-Hall, Engle-
professional colleagues outside of the firm can lead to the disclo-
wood Cliffs, NJ.
sure of proprietary information to firm competitors; it can also Dasgupta, P., David, P., 1994. Towards a new economics of science. Research Policy
place firm scientists within valuable knowledge networks. Group 23, 487–521.
decision-making involving diverse viewpoints can result in lack of Decarolis, D., Deeds, D.L., 1999. The impact of stocks and flows of organizational
knowledge on firm performance: an empirical investigation of the biotechnology
consensus and strategic drift; it can also lead to more informed industry. Strategic Management Journal 20, 953–968.
decisions that result in breakthrough innovations that would not Dess, G., Beard, D., 1984. Dimensions of organizational task environments. Admin-
be discovered by a homogenous group. Yet the best firms strike a istrative Science Quarterly 29, 52–73.
Dhawan, S., Roy, S., Kumar, S., 2002. Organizational energy: an empirical study in
balance. They permit scientists to create valuable knowledge while Indian R&D laboratories. R&D Management 32, 397–408.
engaging in worthwhile scientific pursuit. Management shapes the Duncan, D.M., James, M., 1974. Miller’s living systems theory: issues for management
R&D process to ensure that shareholder value is created. Boundary thought and practice. Academy of Management Journal 15, 513–524.
El Feki, S., June 18, 2005. Prescription for Change. The Economist.
spanners bridge the chasm between these divergent objectives. Eisenhardt, K., 1989. Making fast decisions in high-velocity environments. Academy
of Management Journal 32, 546–576.
Financial Accounting Standards Board, 1974. Statement of financial accounting
Acknowledgements
standards no. 2: accounting for research and development costs. Financial
Accounting Standards Board.
We would like to thank Mark Casson, Arun Kumaraswamy, Sara Friedman, R.A., Podolny, J., 1992. Differentiation of boundary spanning roles: labor
negotiations and implications for role conflict. Administrative Science Quarterly
McGaughey, Magnus Persson, David Reeb, Steven Tallman and the
37, 28–47.
session participants at the 2006 Academy of Management meeting Gittelman, M., Kogut, B., 2003. Does good science lead to valuable knowledge?
for helpful comments. Biotechnology firms and the evolution logic of citation patterns. Management
Science 49, 366–382.
Granovetter, M.S., 1973. The strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology 78,
References 1360–1380.
Gulati, R., Nohria, N., Zaheer, A., 2000. Strategic networks. Strategic Management
Ahuja, G., Lampert, C.M., 2001. Entrepreneurship in the large corporation: a longitu- Journal 21, 203–215.
dinal study of how established firms create breakthrough inventions. Strategic Hayek, F.A., 1945. The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review 35,
Management Journal 22, 521–543. 519–530.
Ancona, D.G., Caldwell, D.F., 1992. Bridging the boundary: external activity and Henderson, R., Cockburn, I., 1994. Measuring competence? Exploring firm effects in
performance in organizational teams. Administrative Science Quarterly 37 (4), pharmaceutical research. Strategic Management Journal 15, 63–84.
634–665. Hill, T.L., Mudambi, R., Swift, T., Wadhams, T., 2009. Proactive R&D Management and
Aragon-Correa, J.A., Sharma, S., 2003. A contingent resource-based view of proac- Organizational Form. Discussion Paper, Temple University, Philadelphia, PA.
tive corporate environmental strategy. Academy of Management Review 28 (1), Jaffe, A.B., 1986. Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D: evidence from
71–88. firms’ patents, profits and market value. American Economic Review 76,
Argyres, N., Liebskind, J., 2000. The role of prior commitment in governance choice. 984–1001.
In: Foss, N., Mahnke, V. (Eds.), Competence, Governance & Entrepreneurship. Jaffe, A.B., Trajtenberg, M., Henderson, R., 1993. Geographic localization of knowledge
Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 232–239. spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108,
Arrow, K.J., 1962. Welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In: Nelson, 577–598.
R. (Ed.), The Rate and Direction of Economic Activity. NBER/Princeton University Kostova, T., 1999. Transnational transfer of strategic organizational practices: a con-
Press, Princeton, NJ. textual perspective. Academy of Management Review 24, 308–332.
Baber, W.R., Fairfield, P.M., Haggard, J.A., 1991. The effect of concern about reported Kostova, T., Roth, K., 2003. Social capital in multinational corporations and a micro-
income on discretionary spending decisions: the case of research and develop- macro model of its formation. Academy of Management Review 28, 297–
ment. Accounting Review 66, 818–829. 317.
Bain, J.S., Qualls, P.D., 1987. Industrial Organization: A Treatise. JAI Press, Greenwich, Kuhn, T.S., 1962. The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. The University of Chicago
CT. Press, Chicago, IL.
R. Mudambi, T. Swift / Research Policy 38 (2009) 736–745 745

La Porte, T.L., 1965. Conditions of strain and accommodation in industrial research Richter, A.W., West, M.A., van Dick, R., Dawson, J.F., 2006. Boundary spanners: iden-
organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly 10, 21–38. tification, intergroup contact, and effective intergroup relations. Academy of
Mayo, E., 1945. The Social Problems of an Industrial Civilization. Division of Research Management Journal 49, 1252–1269.
Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University, Boston, MA. Scotchmer, S., 2004. Innovation and Incentives. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
McGaughey, S.L., 2002. Strategic interventions in intellectual asset flows. Academy Senge, P., 1994. The Fifth Discipline Handbook. Currency/Doubleday, New York, NY.
of Management Review 27, 248–274. Sharfman, M.P., Dean Jr., J.W., 1991. Conceptualizing and measuring the organiza-
McMillan, G.S., Klavans, R.A., Hamilton III, R.D., 1995. Firm management of scientific tional environment: a multidimensional approach. Journal of Management 17,
information: some predictors and implications of openness versus secrecy. R&D 681–700.
Management 25, 411–419. Shephard, H.A., 1956. Nine dilemmas in industrial research. Administrative Science
Merton, R.K., 1957. Priorities in scientific discovery: a chapter in the sociology of Quarterly 3.
science. American Sociological Review 22, 635–659. Simons, T., Pelled, L.H., Smith, K.A., 1999. Making use of difference: diversity, debate
Merton, R.K., 1973. The Sociology of Science: Theoretical and Empirical Investigation. and decision comprehensiveness in top management teams. Academy of Man-
University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL. agement Journal 42, 662–673.
Mudambi, R., 2008. Location, control and innovation in knowledge-intensive indus- Sorenson, O., Fleming, F., 2004. Science and the diffusion of knowledge. Research
tries. Journal of Economic Geography 8 (5), 699–725. Policy 33, 1615–1633.
Mudambi, R., Navarra, P., 2004. Is knowledge power? Knowledge flows, subsidiary Stern, S., 2004. Do scientists pay to be scientists? Management Science 50,
power and rent-seeking within MNCs. Journal of International Business Studies 835–853.
35 (5), 385–406. Tijssen, R.J.W., 2004. Is commercialization of scientific research affecting the pro-
Mudambi, R., Mudambi, S., Navarra, P., 2007. Global innovation in MNCs: the effects duction of public knowledge? Global trends in the output of corporate research
of subsidiary self-determination and teamwork. Journal of Product Innovation articles. Research Policy 33, 709–733.
Management 24 (5), 442–455. Tushman, M., 1977. Special boundary roles in the innovation process. Administrative
National Science Foundation, 2005. Division of Science Resources Statistics, National Science Quarterly 22, 587–606.
Patterns of Research and Development Resources: 2003, NSF 05-308, Brandon Walker, G., Kogut, B., Shan, W., 1997. Social capital, structural holes and the formation
Shackelford (Arlington, VA). of an industry network. Organization Science 8, 109–125.
Nelson, R.R., 1959. The simple economics of basic scientific research. Journal of Williamson, O.E., 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. The Free Press, New York, NY.
Political Economy 67, 297–306. Youndt, M.A., Subramaniam, M., Snell, S.A., 2004. Intellectual capital profiles: an
Nelson, R.R., 2004. The market economy and the scientific commons. Research Policy examination of investments and returns. Journal of Management Studies 41,
33, 455–471. 335–361.
Osterloh, M., Frey, B., 2000. Motivation, knowledge transfer, and organizational Zaheer, A., McEvily, Perrone, V., 1998. Does trust matter? Exploring the effects of
forms. Organization Science 11, 538–550. interorganizational and interpersonal trust on performance. Organization Sci-
Ouchi, W.G., 1980. Markets, bureaucracies and clans. Administrative Science Quar- ence 9, 141–159.
terly 25, 129–141. Zander, U., Kogut, B., 1995. Knowledge and the speed of the transfer and imita-
Pekkarinen, T., Riddell, C., 2008. Performance pay and earnings: evidence from per- tion of organizational capabilities: an empirical test. Organization Science 6,
sonnel records. Industrial & Labor Relations Review 61 (3), 297–319. 76–92.
Perry, S., Grinaker, R., 1994. Earnings expectations and discretionary research and Zucker, L., Darby, M., Armstrong, J., 2002. Commercializing knowledge: university
development spending. Accounting Horizons 8, 43–51. science, knowledge capture, and firm performance in biotechnology. Manage-
Powell, W., Koput, K., Smith-Doerr, L., 1996. Interorganizational collaboration and ment Science 48, 138–153.
the locus of innovation: networks of learning in biotechnology. Administrative Zucker, L., Darby, M., Brewer, M., 1998. Intellectual human capital and the birth of
Science Quarterly 49, 1252–1269. the U.S. biotechnology enterprises. American Economic Review 88, 290–306.

You might also like