You are on page 1of 15

A Theory of Global Strategic Alliances: The Case of the Global Auto Industry

Author(s): Willem P. Burgers, Charles W. L. Hill, W. Chan Kim


Source: Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 14, No. 6 (Sep., 1993), pp. 419-432
Published by: John Wiley & Sons
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2486753 .
Accessed: 14/01/2011 01:03

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at .
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=jwiley. .

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

John Wiley & Sons is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Strategic
Management Journal.

http://www.jstor.org
Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 14, 419-432 (1993)

A THEORYOF GLOBALSTRATEGICALLIANCES:
THE CASE OF THE GLOBALAUTO INDUSTRY
WILLEMP. BURGERS
College of Business Administration, University of New Orleans, New Orleans,
Louisiana, U.S.A.
CHARLESW. L. HILL
School of Business Administration, University of Washington, Seattle, Washington,
U.S.A.
W. CHAN KIM
INSEAD,Fontainebleau, France

The theory articulated in this paper suggests that the desire to reduce demand and competitive
uncertainty are two separate, important motives for alliance formation. Taking this as a
starting point, we predict the configuration of horizontal alliances that we might expect to
observe within an industry when firms experience these uncertainties to different degrees.
An empirical test of this theory using data from the global auto industry yields results
consistent with the view (1) that alliances are a device for reducing both the uncertainties
that arise from unpredictable demand conditions and those that arise from competitive
interdependence, and (2) that variation of demand uncertainty and competitive uncertainty
across firms explains differentials in both the intensity and structure of their horizontal
alliance activity.

INTRODUCTION Thus, this study looks at alliance activity within


a single industry. Although the issue of alliances
One of the most notable trends in recent years among competitors has received increasing atten-
has been the growth in the popularity of alliances tion in the literature (Harrigan, 1985, 1986, 1988;
between competitors (Harrigan, 1985, 1986, 1988; Kogut, 1988; Nielsen, 1988) there has been a
Hergert and Morris, 1987). This development lack of theory development regarding the overall
raises two questions; (1) what motivates firms to configuration of alliance activity within an industry
enter into alliances with their competitors, and (Porter and Fuller, 1986; Walker, 1988; Nohria
(2) given motivations, which other firms in an and Garcia-Pont, 1991). Indeed, one of the basic
industry will a firm ally itself with? In the sections stumbling blocks challenging researchers when
that follow we draw on established theory to analyzing interorganizational relations within an
outline a set of hypotheses regarding both of industry has been to find a way to explain the
these questions. Data from the global auto configuration of relations among incumbent firms
industry is then used to test these hypotheses. (Van de Ven, Walker, and Liston, 1979). In
addition, much of the empirical research on
alliances has looked at alliance formation across
Key words: Strategicalliances,networks,auto indus- industries (e.g., Pfeffer and Nowak, 1976). There
try has been very little empirical research focusing

0143-2095/93/070419-14$12.00 Received9 May 1990


(? 1993 by John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Final revisionreceived14 January1993
420 W. P. Burgers, C. W. L. Hill and W. Chan Kim

upon the configuration of alliance activity among purchasing patterns. Predictability will be lower,
competitors within an industry (exceptions being and demand uncertainty will be greater, whenever
Nohria and Garcia-Pont, 1991; Walker, 1988). an industry is being subjected to an event
that threatens to change established purchasing
patterns (e.g., an innovation or new entry). To
MOTIVES FOR ENTERING INTO survive in an uncertain environment firms must
HORIZONTAL ALLIANCES be able to adapt quickly to changing demand
conditions. However, organizational inertia and
Our focus is on alliances between competitors the constraints of administrative heritage may
within an industry. Alliances between competitors make it difficult for firms to internally develop
are referred to as horizontal alliances. They can or purchase the strategic capabilities required to
be distinguished from vertical alliances between deal with rapidly changing demand conditions
firms operating in adjacent stages of a value (Bartlett and Ghoshal, 1989; Hannah and Free-
chain (Harrigan, 1988). We take the term man, 1989). In this context, it has been argued
horizontal alliance to mean a long term (three that firms can gain access to the requisite strategic
years or more) explicit contractual agreement capabilities by entering into alliances with firms
pertaining to an exchange and/or combination of that already possess those capabilities (Nohria and
some, but not all, of a firm's resources with a Garcia-Pont, 1991; Kogut, 1988; Porter and Fuller,
competitor. This definition includes, but is not 1986). Thus, by enabling the firm to quickly gain
limited to, joint ventures. access to key strategiccapabilities, strategic alliances
Our arguments are drawn from two main help firms to cope with unpredictable changes in
theoretical perspectives. One perspective, based consumer purchasing patterns.
in transaction cost economics, emphasizes the However, alliances are not without problems.
use of alliances as an efficient way to expand They are prone to failure (Harrigan, 1988),
strategic capabilities. The other perspective, difficult to manage (Killing, 1983), demand
based in classic industrial organization, empha- considerable attention from top management
sizes the use of alliances as a means for (Berg and Friedman, 1980; Koot, 1988), and
reducing competition (through market power and decrease organizational autonomy (Aldrich, 1979;
collusion). These perspectives are not mutually Provan, 1982). Such problems suggest that firms
exclusive, and indeed, both have received empiri- will hesitate to enter into alliances unless they
cal support (Kogut, 1988). Drawing on these have a clear incentive to do so. Within the
perspectives, we argue that environmental uncer- context of a single industry, it is possible that
tainty is a catalyst that drives competitors into the incentive to enter into an alliance is a
strategic alliances with each other (Pfeffer and function of firm performance. Insofar as firm
Salancik, 1978; Provan, 1982; Whetten and performance is an indicator of firm efficiency,
Leung, 1979). Two sources of environmental poorly performing (inefficient) enterprises are
uncertainty can be identified: (1) demand uncer- probably less able to deal with the adverse
tainty, and (2) competitive uncertainty (Harrigan, consequences of demand uncertainty than their
1988). Below we argue that demand uncertainty more efficient competitors. As such, their incen-
motivates competitors to enter into alliances with tive for entering into alliances is likely to be
each other in order to gain access to the greater than the incentive that high performing
capabilities required to cope with such uncertainty firms have. Thus:
(the efficiency motive), while competitive uncer-
tainty motivates firms to enter into alliances with Hypothesis 1: The number of long-term hori-
each other in order to reduce that uncertainty by zontal alliance agreements a firm enters into will
reducing competition (the market power motive). be negatively related to the firm's performance.

DEMAND UNCERTAINTY COMPETITIVE UNCERTAINTY

Demand uncertainty is the uncertainty that Competitive uncertainty is the uncertainty that
arises from unpredictable changes in consumer arises from competitive interdependence. Com-
Global Strategic Alliances 421

petitive interdependence exists whenever the uncertainty. The degree of uncertainty they face
competitive actions of a firm have a direct effect is high since their competitive moves might upset
upon the market position of its rivals, thereby any equilibrium in the industry, as might the
risking a response in kind (Hay and Morris, moves of their largest rivals. On the other hand,
1979). The extent of competitive interdependence a number of factors work to reduce the incentive
that a firm faces is a function of industry that large firms have to engage in horizontal
structure (Hay and Morris, 1979). Competitive alliances in order to reduce competitive uncer-
interdependence is low in fragmented industries tainty. Alliances between large firms are likely
and in monopolies. It is highest in oligopolies to come under close antitrust scrutiny in both
where a limited number of evenly balanced the U.S. and the E.C. The incidence of alliance
competitors confront each other. activity among large firms will be moderated by
Competitive interdependence produces com- this factor. A further consideration is that large
petitive uncertainty because a firm never knows firms are more likely than intermediate or small
in advance whether its actions will invite retali- firms to have the cost structure and financial
ation, or whether its rivals will initiate competitive resources required to survive a sustained competi-
moves that directly impact upon its market share tive battle. This moderates the incentive that
and require a response in kind. For this reason large firms have to enter into a horizontal
it has been argued that the desire to co-opt alliance for the purposes of reducing competitive
one's competitors, thereby reducing competitive uncertainty. These factors suggest that among
uncertainty, represents an important motive for large firms within an industry, the need and
entering into horizontal strategic alliances (Pfeffer inclination to enter into horizontal alliances for
and Nowak, 1976; Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978; the purpose of managing competitive uncertainty
Pennings, 1981; Kogut, 1988; Contractor and is moderated.
Lorange, 1988). Now consider intermediate firms; when com-
Within the context of a single industry, pared to the smallest firms the larger effects of
our basic proposition is that the competitive competitive actions by intermediate firms are
uncertainty facing a firm varies with its position more likely to elicit a response in kind on the
within the industry's size distribution. Accord- part of their rivals. When compared to the largest
ingly, so does the firm's incentive for entering firms, the intermediate firms' lesser size and
into an alliance to reduce competitive uncertainty. more limited resources make it less likely they
More specifically, we shall argue that the incentive can successfully fight a sustained competitive
to enter into an alliance to reduce competitive battle-they are less insulated from the adverse
uncertainty is greatest for intermediate sized consequences of competitive interdependence.
firms, and least for the smallest and largest firms Thus, on average, the intermediate firm faces a
in an industry. higher degree of competitive uncertainty. The
Consider the smallest firms in an industry. intermediate firm is too large to go unnoticed, but
Their low market share implies that their actions not sufficiently large enough to deter retaliation or
will impact less on other players in the industry. survive a competitive battle undamaged. As a
Consequently the competitive moves of small consequence, intermediate firms are likely to
players will be less likely to invite a response in have a greater incentive to enter into horizontal
kind. Moreover, their small market share implies alliances to reduce competitive uncertainty. Thus:
that they are limited in their ability to use
horizontal alliances to reduce competitive uncer- Hypothesis 2: The number of competitors
tainty. Since small firms are not the cause of linked to afirm will be highest at an intermediate
competitive interdependence, they can't really level of firm size. Put differently, the number
reduce it by entering into an alliance. They do of competitors linked to afirm will be negatively
not have much in the way of market share to related to the deviation of firm size from the
bring to the table. intermediate value of firm size in the industry.
Next consider the largest firms in an industry.
On first examination it might appear that the Note that Hypothesis 2 is framed in terms of
largest firms have a much greater incentive the number of competitors linked to the firm
to enter into alliances to reduce competitive through alliances, rather than the number of
422 W. P. Burgers, C. W. L. Hill and W. Chan Kim

alliances (as was Hypothesis 1). This is because tions may be inappropriate. Intermediate firms,
only one alliance with a given competitor are unlikely to be specialized niche companies.
is required to reduce competitive uncertainty, Moreover, compared to large firms they may
whereas several alliances with a single competitor lack the resources required to develop strategic
may be called for when the aim is to get access capabilities internally. Thus:
to strategic capabilities.
Hypothesis 4: The number of horizontal
alliance agreements the firm enters into will be
ADDITIONAL CONSIDERATIONS highest at an intermediate level of firm size.
Put differently, the number of horizontal
In addition to the above hypotheses, we should alliance agreements a firm enters into will be
also consider whether firm performance would negatively related to the deviation of firm size
affect the number of competitors linked to the from the intermediate value of firm size for the
firm, or if firm size also would affect the number industry.
of alliance agreements entered into by the
firm. In any event these possibilities should be
controlled for in order to avoid specification THE MODEL
error or spurious results when testing Hypotheses
1 and 2. However, it is possible to go beyond Figure 1 summarizes Hypotheses 1 through 4 in
this methodological consideration and extend the a single model. This model is used as the basis
above theoretical arguments, albeit tentatively, for subsequent empirical work. As shown in
to justify formal hypotheses concerning these Figure 1, we also intend to control for a potential
potential relationships. association between firm performance and the
All else being equal, better performance by deviation of firm size from the intermediate
the firm may signal to potential adversaries that value of firm size in the industry. This is necessary
the firm can fight successfully when challenged. since the idea that firms of intermediate size are
This would reduce the likelihood that the 'stuck in the middle' has gained considerable
competitive actions of firms with successful currency (Porter, 1980). In addition, we control
performance will be challenged aggressively, for the possibility that the number of alliance
alleviating competitive uncertainty and the com- agreements a firm enters into is related to the
mensurate need for negotiated linkage with number of competitors to which it is linked.
competitors. Hence:

Hypothesis 3: The number of competitors CHOOSING FIRMS TO ALLY WITH


linked to the firm will be negatively related to
the level of firm performance. It is now time to turn our attention to the second
question raised in the introduction, that is: given
As for the relationship between firm size and motivations, which otherfirms in an industry will
the number of alliance agreements, it is possible
to argue that intermediate firms are the most
threatened by demand uncertainty and, therefore,
have a greater incentive to enter into alliances Number of
Firm
than either large or small firms. Large firms, Performance H1() Alliance
because of their greater resources, are more Agreements
/ _
likely to be able to internally develop the H3(-)
strategic capabilities required to deal with demand
H4(-)
uncertainty than intermediate firms. Therefore, Firm Size Number of
large firms have less need to enter into alliances Deviation from H2(-) Competitors
in order to access such capabilities. As for small Intermediate Linked to the
Firm Size Firm
firms, often such organizations are specialized
niche companies. Given this, the kind of strategic
capabilities that they can get from other organiza- Figure 1. Motivesfor allianceformation-hypotheses
Global Strategic Alliances 423

a firm ally itself with? Our argument here is that (thereby reducing demand uncertainty). How-
the other firms that a firm chooses to (and is ever, there is a downside to seeking a central
able to) ally itself with will be a function of the position in a network of alliances. The central
performance and relative size of that firm. As a firm may find itself locked into a number of
lead into this argument, note first of all that long-term relationships from which it has difficulty
over time the operation within an industry of exiting should they prove to be less viable than
the forces described in the previous section will originally thought. The financial, physical, and
result in the emergence of a network of alliance human resources committed to an alliance consti-
agreements between industry participants. Such tute an exit barrier that may significantly decrease
networks can be viewed as interorganizational the firm's strategic flexibility and autonomy,
organizations. A firm's position will be more thereby limiting its ability to adapt to changing
central the greater the number of direct and circumstances (Harrigan, 1980, 1985, 1988). Thus,
indirect linkages that it maintains with other the firm faces a dilemma. On the one hand,
organizations in the network (Freeman, 1979). having multiple alliance agreements with multiple
Other things being equal, there are two reasons partners increases the firm's ability to reduce
why a firm will prefer to take a central position demand and competitive uncertainty. On the
in a network of alliances. First, firms that take other hand, it decreases the firm's long-term
a central position in a network are able to strategic flexibility.
exercise greater control or influence over the Aldrich and Whetten (1981) have pointed to
actions of less central firms in the network (Boje a way in which this dilemma can be attenuated.
and Whetten, 1981). For example, a central firm They have argued that interorganizational net-
may be able to persuade a less central firm from works are often made up of several subnetworks.
initiating damaging price cuts by threatening to A subnetwork is a group of organizations which
direct the network as a whole to respond in kind are more densely linked with one other than
if it does so. In other words, a central firm may with other organizations in the industry wide
be able to use its position to establish some kind interorganizational network. Each subnetwork
of discipline over the network as a whole, thereby may be structured in a hierarchical fashion, with
reducing competitive uncertainty. Consistent with more powerful members influencing the actions
this view, Laumann and Pappi (1976) and taken by less powerful members. Thus, an
Galaskiewicz (1979) have reported evidence industry wide network of competitors may be
which suggests that organizations attempt to divided into a number of subnetworks. Joining
enhance their influence over other organizations a subnetwork enables firms to reap some of the
by adopting a central position in interorgani- benefits that flow from being part of a network,
zational networks. with suffering an extreme loss of strategic
Second, the more central a firm's position in flexibility that would occur from being commit-
a network, the greater its ability to hedge its teed to too many partners.
bets concerning the best way to satisfy consumers This observation has implications for the trade-
in a highly uncertain environment where demand off between uncertainty reduction and strategic
conditions are unpredictable (Harrigan, 1985, flexibility. Poor performing firms that find their
1988). Harrigan argues that given demand uncer- strategic capabilities lacking may have a need
tainty there are clear advantages to be gained for a greater number of alliance agreements. All
(in terms of hedging bets) by positioning the else being equal, we would also expect these
firm at the hub of a 'spiders web' of parallel same firms to be less attractive as potential
joint ventures, all of which serve the same partners. They may be hard put to find a
strategic purpose (i.e., access to the capabilities hospitable subnetwork willing to adopt and
of other firms). support them while respecting their interests. In
The above suggests that firms need to seek contrast, firms that perform well will have a
multiple partners and establish a central position greater ability to concentrate and focus their
in a network in order to (1) maximize their agreements on competitors of their choice within
influence within the network (thereby reducing a subnetwork. The division of an industry
competitive uncertainty), and (2) hedge their wide network of competitors into a number of
bets by maximizing access to strategic capabilities subnetworks of competitors may thus leave
424 W. P. Burgers, C. W. L. Hill and W. Chan Kim

weaker performers adrift in the industry as they of hierarchical authority suggests that it would
may find it difficult to position themselves be difficult to maintain the cohesion of such a
unambiguously within the confines of one subnet- subnetwork. Thus:
work. Thus:
Hypothesis 6: While large and small firms
Hypothesis 5: While firms with high perform- will tend to concentrate their alliances within
ance will tend to concentrate their alliances the boundaries of a subnetwork, intermediate
with competitors within the boundaries of a firms will not. That is, for each firm the
subnetwork, firms with low performance will proportion of partners found within the bound-
not. That is for each firm the proportion of aries of a richly joined subnetwork will be
partners found within the boundaries of a positively related to the deviation of firm size
subnetwork will be positively related to firm from the intermediate value of firm size in the
performance. industry.

The division of an industry into densely linked The arguments underlying Hypothesis 6 put
subnetworks may also have different implications an additional twist on the role of competitive
for firms of different size. Large firms may to a uncertainty in the industry. In effect, it may be
degree limit the trade-off between benefits of said that large firms and the small firms under
cooperation and reduced long-term strategic their guidance, seek to control rather than reduce
flexibility by concentrating their linkages within competitive uncertainty. Their hypothesized
the boundaries of a richly joined subnetwork alliance within hierarchical densely linked subnet-
within which they have a dominant position. works would reduce the competition among
Such a strategy will maintain their autonomy and them, but may well serve to increase competitive
strategic flexibility vis-a-vis the total industry- pressure on outsiders. Implicitly, the arguments
wide network, yet also give them a central underlying Hypothesis 6 therefore suggest that
position within a subnetwork and, therefore, large firms seek to augment their power in the
power over their partners in the subnetwork. It industry by building interorganizational organiza-
is also possible that smaller organizations will be tions under their control. These ideas suggest
led by their larger partners to concentrate their that large firms are unlikely to favor alliances
alliance relationships within the boundaries of with other large or intermediate firms, since
subnetworks. As Harrigan points out (1985, these may strengthen the competitors most likely
1988), larger organizations may seek to augment to challenge their market position and control
their power over smaller partners by isolating (Contractor and Lorange, 1987; Reich and
their smaller partners within the confines of Mankin, 1986).
a subnetwork which the larger organization For their part, smaller firms are also likely to see
dominates. advantages in linking up with large enterprises.
In contrast, intermediate organizations are Access to the resources of larger firms increases
expected to disperse their linkages across the probability that small firms will survive.
several subnetworks. On the one hand, they Large firnms may provide the cash resources
are less likely to be strong enough to individually necessary to ride out demand downturns and
control and dominate a network of their own. underwrite new investments, and the access to
On the other hand, they are less likely to be distribution channels necessary to maximize sales.
weak enough to submit to the dominance of a While intermediate firms can provide these things
large organization. An alternative solution too, large firms can provide more of them by
would be for intermediate players to band virtue of their superior market position. Thus,
together and jointly form a subnetwork. The large firms make better alliance partners for
disadvantage with this arrangement is that a small firms. In sum, this suggests the following
subnetwork containing evenly matched organi- hypothesis:
zations will lack a hierarchical structure. As a
consequence, its effectiveness as an instrument Hypothesis 7: The larger the size of the firm,
for coordination may be impaired (Phillips, the smaller on average will be the size of its
1960; Whetten, 1987). Specifically, the absence partners.
Global Strategic Alliances 425

EMPIRICAL RESEARCH and has broken down previously well established


rules of the game, thereby raising competitive
The above hypotheses were tested on data taken uncertainty. Third, the specter of excess pro-
from the global auto industry. The incidence of ductive capacity in both North America and
alliances in the global auto industry increased Western Europe (due to Japanese inward
throughout the 1980s. As a result, by 1990 most investment) has further increased competitive
of the world's car makers were linked by a web uncertainty. By the late 1980s it was apparent
of cross-shareholdings, joint ventures, and joint that planned increases in Japanese capacity in
manufacturing and sales arrangements. (The both the U.S. and Western Europe would result
Economist, 1990a). The increase in alliance in substantial excess capacity in those markets,
activity in the auto industry does seem to be a thereby increasing the probability of a dangerous
response to increased demand and competitive price war occurring.
uncertainty. The entry of new competitors into
formally protected national markets has increased
the level of demand uncertainty in the industry. DATA AND MEASURES
The entry of Japanese, Korean, and European
(mainly German) producers into the North Our sample is made up of the 23 largest global
American market during the 1970s and 1980s competitors in the free world car market in 1987,
resulted in a significant increase in both the based on World Motor Vehicle Data (see Table
number of competitors and the range of product 1). These companies account for all significant
offerings in that region. Outside entry, though global competitors. We excluded companies
less dramatic, was also significant in Europe operating only in local or protected markets
during this time period. The threat of increased (generally third world countries or countries of
competition following the creation of a single the former communist bloc) since these companies
market in the E.C. after 1992 has increased neither influence nor are influenced by global
further the level of demand uncertainty facing competition. Also excluded were a number of
European producers. As a result of actual and very small 'craft based' sports car manufacturers
threatened new entry, demand conditions in both (e.g., Aston Martin, Ferrari, Lotus). Most of
North America and Europe therefore became these companies produce less than 100 cars per
much less predictable than they had been in the year. Due to their extreme small size and
past. specialized clientele, these companies also neither
In addition, the level of competitive uncertainty influence nor are influenced by global compe-
can be judged to be high in this industry for tition.
three reasons. First, the industry is concentrated Data on competitive alliances established by
enough for competitive interdependence to come 1983 in the global auto industry were available
into play. As of 1989 the top eight firms in the from the United Nations Industrial Development
market accounted for 70.1 percent of global Organization (UNIDO). Additional data were
market share (Business Week, 1990). The level obtained from the Funk and Scott index, the
of concentration in each of the three major Wall Street Journal index, and various editions
regional markets was even higher. The largest of Mergers and Acquisitions. Based on these
six firms accounted for 90.9 percent of car and data, the empirical analysis takes into account
light truck sales in the U.S., 75.5 percent of car 214 observations of individual firm participation
sales in Western Europe, and 84.2 percent of in horizontal alliance agreements that had been
the car sales in Japan (The Economist, 1990). established by 1988. Note that some agreements
Second, the increasing globalization of the involved more than two competitors. These
industry is destabilizing the competitive environ- agreements resulted in 58 pairwise linkages
ment in many once protected national markets. among the 23 firms studied.
Historically the 'rules of the game' were well Production data for each firm were obtained
established in most national markets, the majority from World Motor Vehicle Data. Average annual
of which were tightly knit oligopolies or duopolies. unit production by the firm {AAPf} was used to
New entry into many formerly protected national assess firm size. The distribution of firm size was
markets has increased the intensity of competition skewed by a proportionally larger number of
426 W. P. Burgers, C. W. L. Hill and W. Chan Kim

Table 1. Car manufacturers: average (MS, = oL + f3 + c,) and MS is the arithmetic


annual worldwide production mean of the MS time-series. This growth statistic
(thousands of units) in 1988
correlates highly with the generally accepted log-
General Motors (GM) 7,743 linear model, but is not affected by negative or
Ford Motor (FO) 6,226 zero values in the MS time-series which have to
Toyota (TO) 4,084 be further transformed in the log-linear model
Volkswagen (VW) 2,875 (Hunter and Coggin, 1983). In addition, the
Nissan (NI) 2,699 measure is easily interpreted providing an esti-
Peugeot-Citroen (PE) 2,465
Chrysler (CH) 2,337 mate of the average percent growth or decline
Renault (RE) 2,101 in market share per unit of time.
Fiat (FI) 2,049 Mean firm size {ln(AAPf) = _ ln(AAPf)/
Honda (HO) 1,709 23} served as the benchmark for intermediate
Mazda (MA) 1,383 firm size. Firm size deviation was calculated as
Mitsubishi (MI) 1,261
Suzuki (SU) 845 the absolute deviation of actual firm size from
Daimler-Benz (DB) 801 mean firm size {Iln(AAPf) - ln(AAPf)I}.
Hyundai (HY) 647 To measure intensity of cooperation we counted
Daihatsu (DA) 643 the number of alliance agreements that a firm
Fuji-Subaru (FU) 595 had with its competitors. While this approach is
Isuzu (IS) 575
Rover Group (RO) 548 objective it can only give an indication of intensity
Volvo (VO) 481 of cooperation. The degree of cooperation that
BMW (BM) 463 is established in different alliances will certainly
Daewoo (DA) 162 vary a great deal. However, more accurate data
Saab-Scania (SA) 158 on the hidden subtleties of the different alliances
among competitors worldwide are simply not
Source: World Motor Vehicle Data, 1989
editions,publishedby MotorVehicle Manu- available.
facturersAssociation.

TESTING HYPOTHESES 1-4


smaller firms. Therefore, we used the natural
log of size {ln(AAPf)} to compress the large Hypotheses 1 through 4 are tested using a path-
firm tail of the size distribution. analytic structural equation model (the LISREL
Firm performance was assessed on the basis VI program-see Joreskog and Sorbom, 1984).
of market share performance (change in market This approach allows us to simultaneously investi-
share). There are a number of reasons for gate the hypothesized relationships among the
operationalizing performance by using market variables of interest while controlling for possible
share as opposed to profit data. In the global interrelationships that may exist between the
setting market share data for different firms independent variables or between the dependent
are more nearly equivalent than are firms' variables.
reports of profit performance since the latter: Market share performance and deviation of
(1) are subject to national differences in firm size from intermediate firm size were
accounting methods, (2) are of uncertain com- measured across the period 1978-87. Then we
parability due to persistent differences in firms' counted the number of alliance agreements firms
cost of capital, and (3) will vary greatly with entered into and the number of competitors that
currency fluctuations. Further, it is likely that they were linked to through alliances during the
profit performance in the capital intensive auto same period. Hence, the analysis provides a
industry in any case is related strongly to broad cross-sectional assessment of Hypotheses
market share performance. 1-4. The 1978-87 period approximates to the
Market share performance (MSP) was meas- time period during which cooperation among
ured by the Hunter and Coggin (1983) growth competitors in the global auto industry became
statistic as follows: MSP = 13/MS(x 100), where endemic.
13is the raw score regression coefficient from the The results of the path analysis are reported
simple linear MS (market share) trend regression in Figure 2 and Table 2. Hypothesis 1, which
Global Strategic Alliances 427

Firm | Number of
variation in the number of competitors linked to
Performance - _6* Alliance the firm.
(MSP) Agreements However, it is possible that alliance agreements
(NoA)
led to poor performance, rather than poor
_ ~~~~-128\/_ performance leading to alliance agreements. To
-.022 ensure that this was not the case we calculated
Firm Size Number of for each year a firm's market share performance
Deviation from Competitors
Intermediate -.470* during the previous 5 years (using the Hunter
Linked to the
Firm Size Firm (NoP) and Coggin statistic described earlier). Then we
lSIZEDEVI established for each year the alliance agreements
implemented by the firms in our sample. Based
Figure2. Results for Hypotheses 1 to 4
on these data we used simple regression analysis
to examine the relationship between previous
performance and subsequent entry into alliance
posited that higher levels of performance are
agreements. The standardized regression coef-
negatively related to the number of alliance
ficient of - 0.446 with p < 0.001 obtained from
agreements that firms enter into, was supported
the simple regression analysis linking alliance
(p < 0.043). Hypothesis 2, which posited that
activity with previous market share performance
deviation from intermediate firm size will reduce
strongly suggested that poor performances did
the number of competitors linked to the firm,
indeed cause firms to seek additional cooperation
was also supported (p < 0.046). Hypotheses 3
with competitors.
and 4 were not supported.
While the results summarized in Figure 2 give
us an overall picture of the relationships of
interest during the 1973-87 period, they do not TESTING HYPOTHESES 5 AND 6
indicate causation per se. This does not present
a problem for interpretation of the result linking Hypotheses 5 and 6 state that high performance
the deviation from intermediate firm size to the and deviation from intermediate firm size,
number of competitors linked to the firm. It is respectively, will lead firms to concentrate their
highly unlikely that firm size was determined by linkages with competitors within a single subnet-
the number of competitors that a firm was work. To test Hypotheses 5 and 6 it was necessary
linked to through alliance agreements. The only to identify subnetworks within the industry
reasonable causal interpretation here is that the network. To do this, for each company we
deviation from intermediate firm size caused the determined its distance to all other companies in

Table 2. Path analysis testing the relationships between the firm's market share performance
{MSP}, absolute deviation of size from intermediate firm size {SIZEDEV}, number of alliance
agreements {NoA}, and number of partners {NoP}, 1978-87

Independent Hypothesis Dependent Path


variables and sign variable coefficient t-Statistic Probability

MSP H1(-) NoA -0.496 -2.123 0.043


MSP H3(-) NoP -0.128 -0.570 0.570
SIZEDEV H2(-) NoP -0.470 -2.088 0.046
SIZEDEV H4(-) NoA -0.022 -0.096 0.924

Notes
(1) MSP = 1/MS(x 100); where: MS is the firm's average market share during the 1978-87 period, and b is
the raw-scoreregressioncoefficientof the MS trend regression(i.e., MS, = (x + P +et),
(2)SIZEDEV= lln(AAPf)- ln(AAPf)I,where: AAPf is firm f's average annual productionduring 1978-87,
and ln(AAPf = 131ln(AAPf)/23.
(3) NoA = the numberof allianceagreementsthe firm entered into duringthe 1978-87 period.
(4) NoP = the number of competitorswith whom the firm entered into one or more alliance agreements
duringthe 1978-87 period.
428 W. P. Burgers, C. W. L. Hill and W. Chan Kim

the network. We started with a determination of spatial solution, aside from simple visual inspec-
the number of links contained in the geodesic tion, involves cluster analysis (Green and Car-
between each pair of companies. A geodesic is mone, 1972; Kruskal and White, 1991).
a measure of distance in the interorganizational Accordingly, we applied the between group
setting. It is defined as the shortest path by average-linkages clustering program in SPSS-X to
which a pair of organizations may be linked, either the output of the Proximities program. The
directly or via one or more other organizations average-linkage approach joins a case to a cluster
(Freeman, 1979). A geodesic contains one link provided that the case is more similar, on average,
if the two companies are related directly, two to all other cases in the cluster than it is to all
links if two companies are related indirectly via other cases, on average, in an alternative cluster.
one other company to which both are linked, As is well known, no statistical grounds exist
three links if the companies are each linked to for determination of an 'appropriate' number of
two other companies who in turn are linked clusters within a population of cases. An objective
directly to one another, and so forth. Indirect cutoff was arrived at by specifying as subnetworks
linkages between companies matter since two only those clusters where a majority of companies
firms, even when not linked directly, nonetheless in the cluster maintained a majority of their
may belong to the same subnetwork by virtue of linkages within the cluster. Within the constraints
their common relationship with other members of that specification, we identified the maximum
of the subnetwork and their common lack of possible number of subnetworks. A four cluster
relationship with members of other subnetworks. solution yielded three clusters that satisfied the
To detect such commonalities between compa- subnetwork specification, and one cluster made
nies, in reference to their relationships with other up of BMW only. Additional clustering did not
companies, we used the Proximities program in generate any further combinations of firms that
SPSS-X to compute the Euclidean distance were linked more closely to one another than
between each pair of companies based on the with competitors outside the combination.
similarity of their geodesic distance to their As can be seen from Figure 3, the reduced
competitors. The resultant Euclidean distances space solution separates rather compact groupings
took into account all direct and indirect linkages of firms. The boundaries drawn in Figure 3
between the pairs of companies. Next, following represent the four cluster solution. All firms with
Green and Carmone (1972), we applied multidi- the exception of BMW are included in a
mensional scaling (MDS) to the output of subnetwork. Accordingly, BMW was dropped
the Proximities program in order to identify from the subsequent analysis. We can distinguish
subnetworks. More precisely, we employed the two American-Japanese subnetworks, and a
ALSCAL procedure in SPSS-X, which uses the European third subnetwork joined by Nissan.
alternating least-squares approach developed by While several firms, e.g., Volkswagen, Rover,
Takane, Young, and DeLeeuw (1977), to produce and Nissan, in the European subnetwork have
the two-dimensional nonmetric multidimensional relationships with firms in both of the
scaling solution shown in Figure 3. American-Japanese subnetworks, the latter sub-
Interpretation approaches in MDS may focus networks are only connected through GM's
on the dimensions and/or the regions of the cooperation with Mazda.
spatial solution (Kruskal and White, 1991). To test Hypotheses 5 and 6, for each firm we
A dimensional interpretation seeks to reduce determined the degree to which it constrained
similarity along multiple dimensions to a similarity its linkages within the boundaries of a single
along fewer dimensions. A regional or 'neighbor- subnetwork. To achieve this we first of all
hood' interpretation seeks to identify regions in identified the number of a firm's partners found
the spatial solution that have meaning in reference within the subnetwork in which most of its
to the similarity along multiple dimensions. Here partners were based {NOPm}. For example, four
we are interested in neighborhood interpretation of Suzuki's total of five partners in Figure 1 are
since we seek to identify subnetworks within the found in the 'GM-Toyota' subnetwork, one in the
overall network of car companies. One way to 'Volkswagen' subnetwork, and none in the 'Ford'
locate the boundaries of relevant regions of space subnetwork. Hence NOPm for Suzuki equals 4,
in a neighborhood interpretation of an MDS while its total number of partners {NoP} equals
Global Strategic Alliances 429
BMW

HY GM

7
F
ml\
MA u

Is
/I
H
FU

r.

.VW
NI

c-
DS - k -- = vo

Fl

Figure 3. Reduced spaced solution

5. Each firm's highest proportion of linkages within during the 1978-87 period, based on the size
a single subnetwork {HPLWSS-N} was then distribution of the other firms in the industry:
calculated by dividing each firm's NOPm by its
22
total number of partners {NoP}. For example,
Suzuki's highest proportion of linkages focused on {ln(AAPp) = E ln(AAPp)/22}
p=1
a single network equals 4/5 = 0.8.
The HPLWSS-N variable was then regressed
We then computed the average size of its actual
against the variables measuring each firm's market
partners:
share performance {MSP} and absolute deviation
from the mean size value in the industry NoP
{SIZEDEV} during the 1978-87 period. The {ln(AAPa) E ln(AAPa)/NoP}
results are reported in Table 3. Hypothesis 5 was a=1
rejected (p < 0.393) indicating that performance
differences did not affect the degree to which The difference between average actual and
firms concentrated cooperation within a single average potential partner size {DPAPS =
subnetwork. Hypothesis 6 was accepted ln(AAPa) - ln(AAPp)} indicates a firm's prefer-
(p < 0.046), indicating that large and small firms ence for larger or smaller partners relative to
tend to concentrate their alliances within the what would be expected if choices were made at
boundaries of a subnetwork, whereas intermediate random among potential partners. This difference
firms do not. was then regressed against firm size. Construction
of the DPAPS variable and the results of its
regression against size are shown in Table 4.
TESTING HYPOTHESIS 7 Consistent with Hypothesis 7, the statistically
significant negative regression coefficient
Hypothesis 7 states that the larger the size of (p < 0.037) suggests that the larger the firm, the
the firm, the smaller on average will be the size smaller the size of its actual partners relative to
of its partners. To test this we first computed the size of its potential partners. Put another
the average size of each firm's potential partners, way, larger firms have a preference for entering
430 W. P. Burgers, C. W. L. Hill and W. Chan Kim
Table 3. Regression of firms' highest proportion of Table 4. Regression of the difference between aver-
linkages within a single subnetwork {HPLWSS-N} on age actual and average potential partner size {DPAPS}
firm performance {MSP} and on absolute deviation on firm size {ln(AAPf)}
of firm size from mean firm size {SIZEDEV}
Independent Regression
Independent Regression variables coefficient Probability
variables coefficient Probability
ln(AAPf) -0.3567 0.037
MSP 0.0024 0.393 (2.21)
(0.875) Constant 8.924 0.000
SIZEDEV 0.0880 0.046 (8.00)
(2.130)
R-Squared 0.189
Constant 0.6337 0.000
(12.88) Notes
(1) t-statisticin parentheses
R-Squared 0.294 (2) DPAPS = ln(AAPa) - ln(AAP,) where:
N 22 ln(AAP,I) = N,P
ln(AAPa)/NoP with
AAPa = actual partner a's 1978-87 average annual
production
Notes ln(AAPp) = X.= 1ln(AAPP)/22with
(1) t-statistic in parentheses
(2) HPLWSS-N = NoPm/NoP, where: NOPm is the number
AAPP = potential partner p's 1978-87 average annual
production
of a firm's partners found in that subnetwork in which most (3) AAPf = firm f's 1978-87 averageannualproduction.
of the firm's partners are found, and NoP is the total number
of partners for the firm.

into alliances with small organizations (and vice from uncertainty reduction against the costs of
versa). decreased strategic flexibility when deciding
whether to enter into an alliance. Large and
small firms solved this dilemma by focusing their
CONCLUSION alliances within a single subnetwork. Intermediate
firms, however, considered unable to control
The theory articulated in this paper suggests that their own subnetwork and unwilling to be
the desire to reduce demand and competitive controlled within a subnetwork not of their own,
uncertainty constitute two important motives for were more inclined to develop linkages across
alliance formation. Taking this as a starting point, subnetwork boundaries.
we generated a number of hypotheses that predicted Differences in performance, however, were
the configuration of cooperative alliances that we not associated significantly with firms' focus,
might expect to observe within an industry when or lack thereof, on linkages within a single
the pressures of these uncertainties vary across subnetwork. While we theorized that weak firms
firms. These hypotheses were tested on data from should not seek and would not find 'sanctuary'
the global auto industry. The results provide within a single subnetwork, our results proved
support for the view that cooperative alliances are differently. Time will reveal if indeed a choice
a device both for reducing demand uncertainty of sanctuary within a single subnetwork can
and for reducing competitive uncertainty. Poor remedy poor performance, or whether a balancing
performance led firms to negotiate a greater strategy of alliances across subnetwork bound-
number of alliance agreements, but without seeking aries will prove more beneficial.
out a greater number of partners. A position 'in Beyond the immediate and traditional concep-
the middle' led firms to focus on negotiated linkage tions of horizontal cooperation as a means of
with a greater number of partners, but without efficient access to expanded capabilities, or
entering into a greater number of alliance agree- alternatively as a means to reduce competition,
ments. our results hint also at a new dynamic of
The observed network configuration of horizontal cooperation that over time may come
alliances within the industry further provided to supersede considerations of competitors' orig-
some evidence that was consistent with the notion inal motives for cooperation with one another.
that firms trade-off the benefits that arise Specifically, the arguments advanced in reference
Global Strategic Alliances 431

to large firms' preference for smaller partners, one of transition, approximating the period of
in combination with the results showing large time during which alliance formations redefined
and small firms' focus on single subnetworks, the nature of competition in the industry.
suggest that large firms and the small firms under Insufficient time has passed to assess the ultimate
their guidance may arrive or may have arrived effects on firms' survival and prosperity taken as
at a point where the subnetwork becomes a tool a function of their cooperative strategies.
for controlling the process of competition. Rather Not only is additional empirical research, as
than merely a tool for efficiency, or for reduced well as the passage of time, needed. Given the
competition, cooperation then becomes a means pervasiveness of alliance formation in nearly
to create a new competitive agent, an interorgani- every important industry today, our present
zational organization with its own competitive understanding of the firm as an independent
dynamic and purposes. agent may lose much of its current meaning.
Nonetheless, we have focused on just one New theoretical approaches may be needed
industry. Therefore, we must be cautious about to explain the behavior and performance of
making any broad generalizations based on this organizations operating as parts of larger inter-
study. Although we believe that the arguments organizational networks. Furthermore, new theo-
contained herein will ultimately be shown to help retical approaches may be needed to study the
explain alliance formation in a wide variety of interorganizational organization as a new form
industries, additional studies of alliance formation of competitive agent. Possibly, such approaches
in other settings are required to confirm this. may be developed from sociological theories of
Our paper is intended only as a first cut at what group behavior.
is undoubtedly a large and complex topic. There
is a need to explore the performance implications
of alternative cooperative strategies. A series of REFERENCES
questions might be raised about how firm Aldrich, H. E. (1979). Organizations and Environ-
performance and alliance performance might be ments. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
affected by the degree to which a firm adheres Aldrich, H. E. and D. A. Whetten (1981). 'Organi-
or deviates from the cooperative strategy that is zational sets, action sets, and networks: Making
theoretically appropriate given its competitive the most of simplicity'. In P. C. Nystrom and W.
H. Starbuck (eds.), Handbook of Organizational
standing. Another fruitful avenue for investi- Design. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
gation might be to explore the relationship pp. 385-408.
between the structuring of alliances and alliance Bartlett, C. A. and S. Ghoshal (1989). Managing
success. For example, will the failure rate of Across Borders: The Transnational Solution. Har-
alliances within subnetwork boundaries differ vard Business School Press, Boston, MA.
Berg, S. V. and P. Friedman (1980). 'Corporate
from the failure rate of alliances across subnet- courtship and successful joint ventures', California
work boundaries? And will the alliance failure Management Review, 23, pp. 85-91.
rate for the promiscuous firm differ from the Boje, D. M. and D. A. Whetten (1981). 'Effects of
alliance failure rate for the firm that concentrates organizational strategies and contextual constraints
its alliance agreements in linkages with just a on centrality and attributions of influence in
interorganizational networks', Administrative Sci-
few competitors? ence Quarterly, 26, pp. 378-395.
Empirical research is also needed on the Business Week (May 7, 1990). 'The Business Week
competitive behavior of firms belonging to global auto scoreboard', pp. 54-55.
different subnetworks. For example, does the Contractor, F. and P. Lorange (1987). 'Why should
subnetwork structure induce a greater degree of firms cooperate?' In F. Contractor and P. Lorange
(eds.), Cooperative Strategies in International Busi-
conscious parallelism among member firms? Will ness. Lexington Books, Lexington, MA, pp. 3-30.
member firms come to direct their competitive The Economist (December 15, 1990). 'The people's
energies away from one another, but intensify car heads east', p. 74.
joint competitive pressure on firms outside the Freeman, L. C. (1979). 'Centrality in social networks:
subnetwork? Will such effects ultimately come Conceptual clarification', Social Networks, 1,
pp. 215-239.
to haunt firms which lack a single subnetwork Galaskiewicz, J. (1979). 'The structure of community
focus? organizational networks', Social Forces, 57,
The time period we studied in this paper was pp. 1346-1364.
432 W. P. Burgers, C. W. L. Hill and W. Chan Kim
Green, P. E. and F. J. Carmone (1972). Multidimen- Management Journal, 12, pp. 105-124.
sional Scaling and Related Techniques in Marketing Pennings, J. M. (1981). 'Strategically interdependent
Analysis. Allyn & Bacon, Boston, MA. organizations'. In P. C. Nystrom and W. H.
Hannah, M. T. and J. Freeman (1989). Organizational Starbuck (eds.), Handbook of Organizational
Ecology. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Design. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
MA. pp. 433-455.
Harrigan, K. R. (1980). 'The effect of exit barriers Pfeffer, J. and P. Nowak (1976). 'Joint ventures and
upon strategic flexibility', Strategic Management interorganizational interdependence', Administra-
Journal, 1, pp. 165-176. tive Science Quarterly, 21, pp. 398-418.
Harrigan, K. R. (1985). Strategies for Joint Ventures. Pfeffer, J. and G. R. Salancik (1978). The External
Lexington Books, Lexington, MA. Control of Organizations: A Resource Dependence
Harrigan, K. R. (1986). Managing for Joint Venture Perspective. Harper & Row, New York.
Success. Lexington Books, Lexington, MA. Phillips, A. (1960). 'A theory of inter-firm organiza-
Harrigan, K. R. (1988). 'Joint ventures and competitive tion', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 74,
strategy', Strategic Management Journal, 9, pp. 602-613.
pp. 141-158. Porter, M. A. (1980). Competitive Strategy. Free Press,
Hay, D. A. and D. J. Morris (1979). Industrial New York.
Economics: Theory and Evidence. Oxford Univer- Porter, M. A. and M. B. Fuller (1986). 'Coalitions
sity Press, Oxford. and global strategy'. In M. Porter (ed.), Competition
Hergert, M. and D. Morris (1987). 'Trends in in Global Industries. Harvard Business School
international collaborative agreements'. In F. Con- Press, Boston, MA, pp. 315-343.
tractor and P. Lorange (eds.), Cooperative Strategies Provan, K. G. (1982). 'Interorganizational linkages
in International Business. Lexington Books, Lexing- and influence over decision making', Academy of
ton, MA, pp. 99-110. Management Journal, 25(2), pp. 443-451.
Hunter, J. D. and D. T. Coggin (1983). 'Measuring Reich, R. B. and E. D. Mankin (March-April, 1986).
stability and growth in annual EPS', Journal of 'Joint ventures with Japan give away our future,
Portfolio Management, 2, pp. 75-78. Harvard Business Review, pp. 77-86.
Joreskog, K. G. and D. Sorbom (1984). LISREL Takane, Y., F. W. Young and J. DeLeeuw (1977).
VI (4th ed). International Educational Services, 'Nonmetric individual differences multidimensional
Chicago, IL. scaling: An alternative least squares method with
Killing, J. P. (1983). Strategies for Joint Venture optimal scaling features', Psychometrika, 42,
Success. Praeger, New York, NY. pp. 7-67.
Kogut, B. (1988). 'Joint ventures: Theoretical and Van de Ven, A. H., G. Walker and J. Liston (1979).
empirical perspectives', Strategic Management Jour- 'Coordinating patterns within an interorganizational
nal, 9, pp. 319-332. network', Human Relations, 32, pp. 19-36.
Koot, W. T. M. (1988). 'Underlying dilemmas in the Walker, G. (1988). 'Network analysis for cooperative
management of international joint ventures'. In F. interfirm relationships'. In F. J. Contractor and P.
J. Contractor and P. Lorange (eds.), Cooperative Lorange (eds.), Cooperative Strategies in Inter-
Strategies in International Business. Lexington national Business. Lexington Books, Lexington,
Books, Lexington, MA, pp. 347-368. MA, pp. 227-240.
Kruskal, J. B. and M. White (1991). Multidimensional Whetten, D. A. (1987). 'Interorganizational relations'.
Scaling. Sage University Paper Series on Quantita- In J. W. Lorsch (ed.), Handbook of Organizational
tive Applications in the Social Sciences, 07-011. Behavior. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ,
Sage, Beverly Hills and London. pp. 238-253.
Laumann, E. 0. and F. Pappi (1976). Networks of Whetten, D. A. and Th. K. Leung (1979). 'The
Collective Action. Academic Press, New York. instrumental value of interorganizational relations:
Nielsen, R. P. (1988). 'Cooperative strategy', Strategic Antecedents and consequences of linkage forma-
Management Journal, 9, pp. 475-492. tion, Academy of Management Journal, 22(2),
Nohria, N. and C. Garcia-Pont (1991). 'Global pp. 325-344.
strategic linkages and industry structure', Strategic

You might also like