You are on page 1of 18

2

http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

Theories of Bank Loan


Commitments
by O. Emre Ergungor

O. Emre Ergungor is an economist at


the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
This article was originally an essay in
his doctoral dissertation. He is grateful to
Professor Anjan Thakor and Assistant
Professor Sugato Bhattacharyya of the
University of Michigan for their guidance
and thanks Joseph Haubrich, James
Thomson, and an anonymous referee
for many valuable suggestions.

Introduction unused credit. A loan commitment contract sel-


dom includes all three kinds of fees together.
Bank loan commitments—contractual promises Booth and Chua (1995) study a sample of
to lend to a specific borrower up to a certain 1,347 loans and find that only 46 percent had
amount at prespecified terms—are widely used a commitment fee, 38 percent had an annual
in the economy. A recent Federal Reserve sur- fee, and 69 percent had a usage fee. A loan
vey shows that 79 percent of all commercial commitment without a fee structure is rare
and industrial lending is made under commit- but possible.
ment contracts.1 Moreover, as of March 2001, The second important feature, the MAC
outstanding (unused) loan commitments of clause, grants the bank some measure of dis-
U.S. corporations exceeded $1.6 trillion, up cretion over whether to honor the contract.
from $743 billion in 1990.2 A typical MAC clause reads: “Prior to [loan]
As the use of loan commitments has grown, closing, there shall not have occurred, in the
so has the literature on them. This article seeks opinion of the Bank, any material adverse
to summarize what we have learned after years change in the Borrower’s financial condition
of research and to determine whether we have
a reasonable idea of what value loan commit-
ments provide to borrowers and lenders. ■ 1 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Survey of
Two features of loan commitment contracts— Terms of Business Lending,” Federal Reserve Board Statistical Releases,
various fees, which must be paid over the life E.2 (June 2000)
of the commitment, and the material adverse <http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/E2/200008/e2.pdf>.
change (MAC) clause—turn out to be particu- ■ 2 Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Statistics on Banking,
larly important in theoretical models.3 table RC-6 (August 2001)
The fee structure may include a commitment <http://www.fdic.gov/bank/statistical/statistics/0103/cbrc06.html>.
fee, which is an up-front fee paid when the
■ 3 Because banks do not disclose the features, such as the fee
commitment is made, an annual (service) fee, structure, of the commitments they are selling, the loan commitment
which is paid on the borrowed amount, and a literature contains few empirical papers. Consequently, this article focuses
usage fee, which is levied on the available on theoretical models.
3
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

from that reflected in its annual report for its interest rate, purchased by very large firms.
fiscal year ending December 31, ____, or in the Table 2 presents their summary statistics.
Borrower’s business operations or prospects.” Shockley and Thakor find that the market
Note that a bank may repudiate the contract interest rate used is usually prime or LIBOR (the
based solely on its own opinion about a bor- London interbank offered rate). The borrowing
rower’s financial condition. That is, the clause firm is offered takedown alternatives of prede-
allows the bank to use its private information termined markups over several different indexes,
about the borrower, which outsiders may be such as Treasury, federal funds, CD, and A1/P1
unable to verify. commercial paper rates. These authors also
To show what a typical loan commitment observe that although few commitments carry
looks like, table 1 provides a sample of 15 loan all three fees, many combine a usage fee with
commitments. To give a more informative either a commitment fee or an annual fee.
picture, Shockley and Thakor (1997) study a I organize this review around three main
sample of 2,513 variable-rate loan commitments, questions. Because these are very general,
offering funds at a fixed markup over a market however, the literature has divided them into

T A B L E 1

Sample of 15 Loan Commitment Contracts

Fees (basis points)


Credit limit Annual
Commitment buyer (millions of dollars) Stated use Commitment servicing Usage Take-down alternatives

Turner Broadcasting 200 Commercial paper backup 0 0 62.5 Prime + 75, LIBOR +175, CD + 187.5
Levi Strauss 500 Debt repayment/consolidation 12.5 0 0 Prime, LIBOR + 100, CD + 112.5
Safeway Stores 480 Debt repayment/consolidation 0 0 0 Prime
Seagull Energy 60 Debt repayment/consolidation 0 12.5 17.5 Prime, LIBOR + 87.5, CD + 87.5
Blockbuster
Entertainment 200 General corporate purposes 0 12.5 12.5 Prime, LIBOR + 50, CD + 62.5
J.C. Penney 750 General corporate purposes 0 0 18.75 Prime, LIBOR + 37.5
AT&T 6,000 Takeover 79.17 13 0 Prime, LIBOR + 37.5, CD + 50
Union Pacific 550 General corporate purposes 0 0 15 Prime, LIBOR + 25, CD + 37.5
UAL Corporation 1,300 Leveraged buyout 157.64 0.69 50 Prime + 100, LIBOR + 200
John Fluke Manufacturing 37.5 Stock buyback 0 0 0 Prime, LIBOR + 50, CD + 50
Universal Corporation 150 Working capital 0 14.17 0 Prime, LIBOR + 37.5
Dunkin’ Donuts 35 Working capital 28.57 0 37.5 Prime, LIBOR + 100
L.A. Gear 150 Working capital 0 0 50 Prime + 100
R.H. Macy & Co. 600 Working capital 150 4.84 50 Prime + 150, LIBOR + 250
American Oil and Gas 20 Working capital 0 0 50 Prime, LIBOR + 300

SOURCE: Greenbaum and Thakor (1995).


4
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

T A B L E 2

Summary Statistics of a Sample


of 2,513 Loan Commitments

Mean, (Standared deviation), [Minimum–Maximum]


Interest rate mark-up
(basis points) Fees (basis points)
N Size Duration
Stated use (percent of total) (millions of dollars) (months) Prime + LIBOR + Upfront Annual Usage

Commercial 42 557.5 39 45.8 47.8 3.1 6.2 11.4


paper backup (1.7) (800.5) (16.3) (26.0) (37.8) (8.7) (7.9) (17.9)
[30–4,300] [11–84] [25–75] [12.5–175] [0–50] [0–25] [0–62.5]
Liquidity 857 56.9 28.4 115.6 135.4 24.2 6.1 22.8
(34.1) (148.7) (22.3) (73.2) (81.4) (52.0) (18.7) (25.5)
[0.1–2,000] [1–126] [–75–500] [9–350] [0–366] [0–200] [0–400]
Capital 470 142.6 39.7 115.6 148.4 28.6 3.6 27.8
structure (18.7) (352.0) (26.8) (64.4) (82.8) (56.7) (10.6) (21.3)
[.2–5,500] [3–121] [–50–450] [15–425] [0–550] [0–100] [0–125]
General 931 179.1 38 105.6 90.6 18.6 4.5 19.6
corporate (37.0) (449.2) (27.7) (72.9) (77.2) (49.3) (11.0) (19.8)
purposes [.1–6,000] [1–198] [–50–500] [15–425] [0–550] [0–135] [0–100]
Takeover 65 74.6 36.2 111.3 125.1 13.8 3.2 29
(2.6) (136.6) (25.2) (82.3) (80.3) (26.5) (8.5) (20.1)
[0.3–845] [3–120] [12.5–450] [12.5–325] [0–100] [0–40] [0–50]
Leveraged 137 139.3 65.2 149 244.6 89.8 4.2 40.3
buyout (5.5) (288.4) (26.4) (32.6) (43.5) (88.3) (9.6) (19.0)
[1.5–1,848] [11–122] [75–400] [80–475] [0–302] [0–54] [0–62.5]
Debtor-in- 11 120 14.2 188.6 293.7 112.8 16.7 43.18
possession (0.4) (100.9) (8.6) (30.3) (31.5) (106.8) (44.5) (16.2)
[3.3–250] [1–30] [150–250] [250–325] [0–235] [0–150] [0–50]
SOURCE: Shockley and Thakor (1997), table 1.

smaller, related questions: On the first main question, presented in this


1) Why do loan commitments exist and how article’s section I, the essence of what we know
are they priced? is that loan commitments are a contractual
a) Why do borrowers demand them? mechanism for optimal risk sharing when bor-
b) Why do banks offer them? rowers are risk averse and future interest rates
c) Why are loan commitments sold by are random. Even under universal risk neutral-
banks and not by individuals or other ity, loan commitments may still be used to
financial intermediaries? attenuate moral hazard or resolve precontract
d) Are loan commitments put options? informational asymmetry. On the valuation
e) Why are loan commitments not exer- question, the principal insight is that loan com-
cised up to the credit limit? mitments can be priced as put options where
2) How do loan commitments affect the the borrower’s debt is the underlying deliver-
bank’s risk exposure? able. The main findings are summarized below:
a) How should the bank’s risk exposure • Borrowers demand loan commitments
be managed? because
b) Do loan commitments affect the – Loan commitments prevent banks from
bank’s risk exposure? exploiting borrowers and extracting
c) Should loan commitments be rents by threatening to withhold credit;
regulated? – Loan commitments can prevent market
3) How do loan commitments affect the failure by attenuating moral hazard
interest rate and rationing channels of and resolving precontract informational
monetary policy? asymmetry.
5
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

• Banks sell loan commitments because • Capital requirements, imposed on loan com-
– Loan commitments facilitate forecasting mitments by regulators to protect the deposit
future loan demand; insurer, are not needed because loan com-
– By honoring discretionary loan commit- mitments with a MAC clause do not impose
ments, banks may enhance their repu- any additional credit risk on the bank.
tation for keeping their promises and The third main question, presented in
charge higher fees for future promises; section III, deals with loan commitments’
– Lenders may use the fee structure of effects on the transmission of monetary policy.
loan commitments as a screening Monetary policy is conducted through quantity
mechanism for distinguishing among rationing and interest rate channels by altering
borrowers with a priori unobservable the quantity of credit and its price, the interest
characteristics. rate. Loan commitments help attenuate rationing
• Loan commitments are sold by banks by providing a guarantied source of funds,
alone because and thus reduce monetary policy’s ability to
– It is more costly for an organization not affect bank lending. The main finding is:
to honor its contractual commitments than • Loan commitments introduce significant lags
it is for an individual; in the effect of monetary policy.
– Reserves that the bank keeps to fund While the current literature improves our
unexpected demand deposit withdrawals understanding of loan commitments consider-
can also be used to fund unexpected loan ably, some stylized facts remain unexplained.
commitment takedowns. Therefore, First, courts limit banks’ use of discretionary
deposit-taking institutions have a cost powers, often ruling that a bank’s use of the
advantage over other financial inter- MAC clause is an abuse of power and lack of
mediaries in issuing loan commitments. good faith. (See Goldberg [1988], Mannino
• Loan commitments can be priced as put [1994], and Budnitz and Chaitman [1998]). If
options where the underlying deliverable is the MAC clause is so difficult and costly to
the debt instrument of the commitment exercise, then why do banks continue to incor-
buyer. porate it into contracts? Second, moral hazard
• Borrowers limit their loan takedown because in spot lending, which can be resolved by loan
banks penalize borrowers that fully exploit commitments, can also be resolved through
their put options with higher future fees. relationship (repeated) lending (Sharpe [1990],
The second main question, presented in Rajan [1992], Petersen and Rajan [1995], and
section II, asks about the effect of loan com- Boot [2000]); why, then, do we have loan com-
mitments on the bank’s risk exposure. In mitments? I discuss these and other unresolved
selling fixed-interest-rate loan commitments, issues briefly in the final section of this article.
banks assume the risks associated with three
uncertain quantities: the future level of interest
rates, the borrower’s uncertain credit needs, I. The Purpose and
and the borrower’s future creditworthiness. Pricing of Loan
The issues are how a bank can manage these Commitments
risks and whether loan commitments should
be regulated to protect the deposit insurer. The I will investigate the existence and pricing
main conclusion is that banks have the tools literature in four subsections. First, I will dis-
they need (for example, the MAC clause) to cuss why borrowers demand loan commit-
protect themselves against the risks involved in ments (demand-side explanations). Then, I
selling loan commitments. There is little theo- will explain why banks sell loan commitments
retical or empirical support to justify regula- (supply-side explanations). Next, I will focus
tion. The important findings are: on the question of why banks alone sell loan
• The bank cannot fully hedge against interest commitments. Finally, I will recapitulate what
rate and takedown-quantity risks through we know about the similarities between loan
financial futures contracts. commitments and put options.
• Loan commitments reduce the bank’s risk
exposure by inducing it to manage its credit
portfolio better.
6
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

Demand-Side greater than (Xl µ l – Xh µ h ) ( µ l – µ h ) –1, the


Explanations borrower prefers the risky project as a con-
sequence of limited liability.6
The literature has suggested five benefits that Boot, Thakor, and Udell (1987, 1991) and
loan commitments offer purchasers.4 Boot, Greenbaum, and Thakor (1993) propose
the following solution to this problem. At
time 0, the bank sells the borrower a loan
Loan Commitments commitment with a fixed interest rate of
Improve Risk Sharing
between the Bank and R = (Xl µ l – Xh µ h ) ( µl – µh ) –1.
the Borrower If the market interest rate is less than R, the
borrower is free to use the market. Otherwise,
When a bank sells a fixed-rate loan commit- he exercises his option and takes down the
ment, it accepts the interest rate and quantity loan from the commitment contract. Hence,
risk that the borrower would bear if he were to the loan commitment guarantees that the bor-
borrow in the spot market. Borrowers who are rower always chooses the safe project. Note
more risk-averse than the bank are willing to that the bank suffers a loss when the borrower
pay the bank a premium for taking the interest exercises the option. To break even, the bank
rate risk on their behalf. In Campbell (1978), charges a commitment fee at time 0 equal to
the premium is the usage fee. In Thakor and the expected loss to the borrower at time 1.
Udell (1987), it is the commitment fee. With a Also note that because the commitment fee
fixed-rate commitment, the bank bears the risk becomes a sunk cost at time 1, when the bor-
of changes in the index rate as well as of rower makes the investment decision, it does
changes in the borrower’s credit risk premium. not affect the borrower’s incentives.
With a variable-rate commitment, the bank Boot, Thakor, and Udell also show that loan
bears only the latter risk. I will further investi- commitments are more effective than equity
gate this issue in section II, where I discuss the investment in attenuating moral hazard. The
bank’s risk exposure.5 intuition is as follows: When a borrower
invests in equity, he reduces his interest bur-
Loan Commitments den for all realizations of future interest rates.
Help Attenuate This is clearly inefficient because low interest
Moral Hazard rates are not distortionary, yet the equity still
reduces the payment burden in those states.
With risky debt and limited liability, the higher The effect of a loan commitment, on the other
the loan interest rate, the lower the borrower’s hand, is selective across interest rates. When
net return from a project and the greater his market rates are low, the borrower can still
incentive to switch to a riskier project (Boot, benefit from them. The loan commitment
Greenbaum, and Thakor [1993]) or to under- reduces the interest burden only when market
supply effort (Boot, Thakor, and Udell [1987, rates are high. Therefore, the commitment fee
1991]). To illustrate this concept, consider the required to mitigate moral hazard is less than
following example. the equity investment needed to create the
There are two periods and three points in same effect.
time {0,1,2}. At time 0, the borrower knows that
he needs funds next period (t =1) to invest in
one of two mutually exclusive projects {h, l }.
Each project requires a $1 investment, which is ■ 4 Some of these benefits arise from the possibility of solving
assumed to be financed by a bank loan. The information problems by using the multiple-fee structure. Clearly, these
projects have the following characteristics: If papers could be reviewed as part of the pricing literature discussed at the
the project is successful with probability µ i , end of section I, but I prefer to group all the demand-side explanations in
it generates a cash flow Xi , i{h,l } and zero a single section.
otherwise. It is also assumed that Xh > Xl and ■ 5 Also see Hawkins (1982) and James (1982).
µ h < µ l . Hence, l is a low-risk project and h is
a high-risk project. It is further assumed that ■ 6 (Xl l –Xh h ) (l – h )–1 is the rate at which the borrower’s
expected profit from the safe project equals its expected profit from the
Xl µ l >Xh µ h . That is, the low-risk project is risky project if the lender believes that the borrower will invest in the safe
socially optimal. At time 0, the market interest project and prices the loan accordingly. In other words, if the spot rate is
rate at time 1 is random. It can be shown that greater than this critical value, the lender must believe that the borrower
when the market interest rate at time 1 is will invest in the risky project if it borrows from the spot market.
7
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

Boot, Thakor, and Udell’s model explains ment is random. A risk-neutral borrower con-
the commitment fee and the interest rate guar- siders only the expected time-1 investment and
anty of loan commitments. Other important takes the project at time 0 if the expected net
aspects of the contract, such as the multiple fee present value (NPV) is positive. With equity
structure or the MAC clause, are assumed away financing, the time-0 investment is a sunk
by simplifying modeling choices, which are cost at time 1, so the borrower continues the
summarized below. project if the expected terminal cash flows
One-period simple projects: A sure invest- exceed the second-period investment. With
ment is made at time t and the outcome is debt financing, however, the borrower pro-
realized at time t +1. After the loan commit- ceeds differently. He repays the initial loan
ment is purchased, no new information about when cash flows are realized at the end, so
the project is revealed to the borrower or the the initial investment is not sunk and causes
bank, which may induce parties to renegotiate underinvestment if the repayment obliga-
or walk away from the deal. This assumption tion is sufficiently large.
will be relaxed in the next section. A loan commitment with a usage fee
Homogeneous investors: Every investor has reduces the borrower’s payment burden from
the same project choice at the time the loan the first-period loan without negative profit
commitment is negotiated, so problems like implications for the bank. The usage fee, paid
adverse selection are not at issue. This assump- on the available unused credit, compensates
tion will be relaxed when we discuss the the bank for the interest rate concession, but
informational role of loan commitments. its incidence is selective across borrowers.
Credible precommitment: In the model of More fortunate investors, with lower second-
Boot, Thakor, and Udell, the bank commits stage requirements, pay more because of the
itself to provide a subsidy at time 1 and is com- gap between their borrowing and the credit
pensated for the expected subsidy at time 0. limit of the loan commitment. Investors with
Note that at time 1, when the market rate is higher second-stage requirements pay smaller
high, the actual subsidy is greater than the fees because their borrowing is closer to
expected subsidy. Despite the obvious loss, the credit limit. That is, borrowers with low
the bank still honors the commitment. We will funding needs subsidize the less fortunate
discuss this issue further in the “Loan Commit- borrowers, giving not-so-lucky—but still
ments Help Banks to Balance Reputational and profitable—investors an incentive to proceed
Financial Capital Optimally” section, below. with their projects.
A final caveat: The results of Boot, Thakor, In a similar setting, Houston and
and Udell apply only to fixed-rate commit- Venkataraman (1996) further relax the “simple-
ments. Within their sample of 2,526 loan project” assumption and analyze the firm’s
commitments, Shockley and Thakor (1997) liquidation decision. This time, the equity-
found only 13 (0.5 percent) that had fixed financed firm compares its liquidation value
rates. Therefore, although preventing moral at time 1 to future cash flows and liquidates if
hazard is a plausible reason for the existence the liquidation value is greater. With short-
of loan commitments, it does not seem to be term debt, the initial investment is not sunk,
the driving force behind them. but is a liability to be covered by the expected
payoff. The firm liquidates when the debt
obligation (not the liquidation value) is greater
Loan Commitments than the expected payoff. As a result, bond-
Help Reduce Other holders receive the liquidation value, which is
Investment Distortions less than the expected payoff. Thus, short-term
debt leads to too-frequent liquidations. With
Moral hazard created by debt financing is
long-term debt, firms never liquidate when the
not limited to the asset-substitution problem
firm’s liquidation value is less than the initial
described above. Loan commitments also
borrowing, because the liquidation value goes
address overinvestment, underinvestment, and
to bondholders. Thus, long-term debt causes
suboptimal liquidation problems. From a
too-infrequent liquidations.
modeling point of view, papers in this category
A short-term loan with a loan commitment
use Boot, Thakor, and Udell’s “tax now, subsi-
for future funding alleviates the problem. The
dize later” idea but relax the “simple-project”
assumption.
Consider a project with two investment
periods, 0 and 1.7 At time 0, the time-1 invest- ■ 7 This example is from Berkovitch and Greenbaum (1991).
8
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

bank gives an interest rate subsidy and reduces ever, as I explain next, loan commitments
the borrower’s debt burden. This solves the create a selective debt overhang problem in
too-frequent liquidation problem. The bor- this model. Houston and Venkataraman
rower compensates the bank with a commit- assume that in a competitive banking mar-
ment fee. However, because the fee must also ket, the borrower’s project quality may be
be financed ex ante, the amount of debt that revealed to other lenders with positive proba-
the firm must issue at the outset increases as bility. So, although the high interest rate also
well. This offsetting effect limits commitments’ hurts the good project, a borrower with a
ability to reduce the costs of suboptimal good project can borrow from another bank
liquidations. and avoid commitment financing altogether
One problem with this explanation is that if his type is revealed. Therefore, the loan
the subsidized interest rate on the initial loan commitment’s high interest rate hurts borrowers
may cause overborrowing. Shockley (1995) with bad projects that cannot find an alterna-
points out that a loan commitment that includes tive funding source more than it hurts borrowers
a MAC clause mitigates this distortion; the com- with good projects. Selective debt overhang
mitment interest rate can be set low enough to resolves the moral hazard problem because the
prevent debt overhang, while the MAC clause borrower increases his effort supply to avoid
allows the bank to prohibit excessive reinvest- the high interest rate and the bad project.
ment. As usual, the bank breaks even with the The literature shows that loan commitments
commitment fee.8 Shockley provides evidence also solve precontract information problems.
that loan commitments reduce the cost of debt. This is what I discuss next.
Therefore, the capital structure of firms that use
loan commitments is tilted in favor of more debt. Informational Role of
In all the papers discussed above, the bank Loan Commitments
provides a sufficiently low interest rate and
the borrower always takes the right action. In this section, I relax the “homogeneous
However, these papers do not consider an investors” assumption and introduce borrowers
important question: If the bank commits itself with unobservable characteristics.
to provide a subsidy, can the borrower exploit James (1981) is one of the early papers
that commitment and extract rents from showing that loan commitment parameters can
the bank? be designed to reveal a borrower’s unobserv-
Houston and Venkataraman (1994) address able characteristics. By demonstrating that the
this question.9 Banks acquire private infor- cost of maintaining compensating balances
mation about their borrowers, which enables differs among customers of different credit
them to extract rents from successful firms by quality, James proved that the customer’s
threatening to withhold further credit.10 This choice of payment option can be an effective
reduces the borrower’s effort input, which tool in separating borrowers with different
determines the probability that the borrower’s credit qualities.
project will turn out to be good or bad ; that is, The observation that loan commitments can
the project will have safe and positive NPV or be used as a screening or signaling mechanism
risky and negative NPV. By providing a pre- helps clarify a puzzle in the loan commitment
arranged source of funds, loan commitments market. Borrowers often purchase loan com-
limit the lender’s ability to extract rents from mitments in order to back up commercial
successful projects. However, when the bank paper issues. The argument is that loan com-
commits itself to lend, two problems arise. The mitments provide insurance to commercial
borrower may exploit the commitment and paper lenders. If the borrower’s cash flows are
extract rents from the bank by threatening to not sufficient to cover its repayment obligation,
liquidate when the project is good and contin- it can always take down a loan under the com-
uing when liquidation is more advantageous. mitment to meet its obligation. The problem
More specifically, when the project is bad, the with this argument is the MAC clause. The fact
borrower refuses to liquidate unless the bank
is willing to share the liquidation value with
the borrower. With a loan commitment, the
bank charges a sufficiently high interest rate
to induce liquidation. Note that this argument ■ 8 Also see Morgan (1993).
contradicts previous papers that found that
■ 9 I will present a simplified version of the intuition here.
banks reduced the interest rate by using a loan
commitment to prevent debt overhang. How- ■ 10 See, for example, Rajan (1992).
9
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

that the borrower cannot repay its commercial rate themselves through contract choice. One
paper loan is sufficient reason for the bank to contract will have a high commitment fee and
void the commitment. Then why do borrowers a low service fee, whereas the other will have
purchase back-up loan commitments? Kanatas a low commitment fee and a high service fee.
(1987) solved this puzzle.11 He showed that a A borrower with a high takedown probability
loan commitment reduces a corporation’s bor- will want to avoid a large service fee because
rowing cost in the commercial paper market, the likelihood of actually paying it is greater.
not because it provides a guaranty to commer- On the other hand, a borrower with a low
cial paper investors but because the purchase takedown probability is less averse to accept-
of the loan commitment, along with its associ- ing a high service fee because the likelihood
ated price and future borrowing rate, commu- of actually paying that fee is lower. Such a
nicates payoff-relevant information to the com- borrower would like to minimize the commit-
mercial paper market. ment fee because it is a sunk cost that is
The intuition is as follows: As of time 0, incurred regardless of whether he exercises
there are three possible states at time 1. If the his commitment option. The borrower with a
firm realizes the “good” state, it will be viewed high takedown probability finds the large
as an improved credit risk and be able to roll commitment fee less burdensome because it
over its first-period commercial paper at a represents the price of an option that he is
lower cost than it would have by exercising very likely to exercise. Thus, the difference in
the commitment. Alternatively, the firm may be takedown probabilities fundamentally alters
in one of the unobservable states in which its the appeal of varying combinations of commit-
default risk has increased. In the “impaired” ment and service fees to different borrowers,
state, the firm’s default probability has inducing each borrower to reveal his type.
increased in such a way that the commitment- The commitment and service fee combina-
borrowing rate is lower than the new commer- tion is not the only screening mechanism.
cial paper rate and the commitment is exer- Shockley and Thakor (1997) develop a ratio-
cised to repay the first-period commercial nale for using commitment and usage fees
paper debt. In the “very bad” state, the firm’s jointly. In their model, there are three types of
default risk has increased to such an extent borrowers: good (G ), medium (M ), and bad
that the commercial paper market denies the (B ). G is more likely than M to have a profit-
firm further credit and the bank refuses to able project and therefore more likely to take
honor the commitment. The firm is thus forced down the loan. B does not have a project to
to default. Firms with a greater probability of invest in. The bank wants to lend to G and M
exercising the commitment (a higher prob- but not to B. In this case, the commitment fee
ability of being in the impaired state, given that alone is not enough to separate the types
the default risk has increased) are induced to because if the fee is set to a level at which M
purchase a larger commitment. An increase in can invest and B does not wish to invest, G
the commitment fee (expressed as a percent- will mimic M although he can pay a higher fee.
age of the credit line) and a decrease in the Note that the commitment is more valuable to
interest rate with increasing probability of the G than to M because G is more likely to exer-
impaired state is incentive compatible. Firms cise its option. Solving this problem requires
with a high probability of being in the impaired making M’s contract less attractive to G ’s man-
state recognize their greater likelihood of ager. This is achieved by reducing the payoff
being able to exercise the commitment advan- to firm M in the state in which the loan is
tageously and are therefore willing to pay a taken down, by increasing the interest rate.
higher fee. Firms with a low probability of This increase diminishes the value of the com-
impairment (higher likelihood of the very bad mitment less for M than for G because M has a
state) pay a lower fee in exchange for a higher lower probability of taking down the loan.
commitment-borrowing rate in the unlikely Because the bank operates in a competitive
event that they are able to exercise the market, it reduces the commitment fee to
commitment. compensate M for the higher interest rate. The
Deterioration in the borrower’s credit quality
is not the only risk a bank faces. Whether the
borrower will actually take down the loan is
another uncertainty. Thakor and Udell (1987)
■ 11 Also see Calomiris (1989).
show that when the bank does not know bor-
rowers’ takedown probabilities, commitment ■ 12 The paper refers to usage fees, but it is more accurate to call
and service fees12 induce borrowers to sepa- fees levied on the borrowed amount service fees.
10
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

problem is that this simultaneous reduction in with low success probabilities. Therefore, a
the commitment fee makes the contract attrac- borrower with a high probability of success
tive to B . A usage fee makes the contract can use overinvestment to distinguish itself
expensive for B because he never takes down from other borrowers, anticipating that it will
the loan. On the basis of their model, Shockley be treated favorably in terms of loan pricing.
and Thakor make the following four predic- That is, the credit limit can be used to signal
tions and provide evidence to support them. a borrower’s quality. Once the credit lines are
First, if the fee structure helps reveal the bor- in place, the firms with higher success proba-
rower’s type, loan commitments should con- bilities will engage in suboptimal investments
tain a pricing structure with multiple fees when when future spot rates are higher than loan
the firm has assets that are hard to value or commitment rates. Thus, the signaling
the firm’s credit quality is poor. Second, equilibrium destroys value.
there must be a negative correlation between
interest rate markups and usage fees. Third,
Loan Commitments Give
announcing a loan commitment purchase
Borrowers a Strategic
should generate an abnormal positive price
Advantage
reaction. Fourth, the price reaction must be
greater if the commitment has a multiple fee Maksimovic (1990) shows that the structure of
structure because the commitment reveals the borrower’s industry determines the terms
information about a firm that is hard to value. of loan commitments. In industries with im-
Although it is possible to obtain a full sepa- perfect competition, the option to acquire
ration of types by using the multiple fee struc- financing at predetermined rates enhances the
ture, this method is limited to two—or at most borrower’s strategic position and creates value
three—types. If there are several unobservable for the borrower. A firm that has access to
types, the multiple fee structure alone may not resources at a lower marginal cost than its
be enough to separate all of them. Thakor competitors has a strategic advantage that it
(1989) analyzes this case, deriving the condi- can exploit to gain a larger market share and
tions under which a forward contract is more higher profits. A firm can create such an advan-
effective than a spot contract in separating tage by purchasing, for a fixed initial fee, an
types. The intuition is that in the forward mar- option to acquire financing on favorable terms.
ket, the future state of the world is still uncer- The ability to exercise the commitment makes
tain. If the relationship among types is such the firm a strategic threat to its rivals and moves
that, for each type, there is at least one state of the industry to an equilibrium more favorable
the world where that agent type is the most to that firm. Therefore, it is optimal for all
likely to attain that state, state-specific subsi- firms to acquire bank loan commitments,
dies can be used as an additional contracting altering the industry equilibrium in the process.
variable. For example, at some point in time, All the models that attempt to explain why
the bank promises an agent of a given type a loan commitments exist have two major short-
subsidized contract in a particular state at the comings. First, as I noted earlier, the models
next point in time. In exchange, the bank that assume a fixed interest rate can justify only
demands a fee at the first point in time. Types a small fraction of the outstanding loan com-
that are less likely to attain that state find the mitments. Second, models that rationalize the
subsidy too expensive. A separate fee-subsidy multiple fee structure as a screening mecha-
combination can be designed to be the most nism are applicable only to situations in which
attractive for each agent type. there are at most three unobservable types of
Finally, Duan and Yoon (1993) explain how borrowers. Although Thakor (1989) allows for
loan commitments can be used as a signaling several types, his model imposes very strong
device. Like Shockley (1995) and Morgan restrictions on the attributes of types. The
(1993), Duan and Yoon recognize that the sub- conclusion is that we still have a lot to learn
sidized funds provided by a loan commitment about the significance of loan commitments’
lead to overinvestment. So the larger a bor- fee structure.
rower’s credit line is, the higher is the cost of
overinvestment. Note that borrowers with high
success probabilities (high expected profits)
can operate at higher costs than borrowers
11
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

Supply-Side demand information. The usage fee will be


Explanations higher for firms that report higher expected
loan demand, whereas the loan rate offered to
such firms will be lower. The intuition is that
firms with high loan demand are insensitive to
Loan Commitments Help
high usage fees because they will most likely
Lower Regulatory Taxes
use the entire credit line and not pay the usage
for Banks
fee. Firms with low loan demand will report
Regulatory taxes are defined as the costs of their information truthfully despite the low
the federal deposit insurance premium, the interest rate offered to investors with high
constraints placed on increased financial inter- demand because they wish to avoid the high
mediation by regulators’ capital requirements, usage fee.
and the opportunity cost of maintaining legally
required reserves. It has been argued that off- Loan Commitments
balance-sheet activities allow banks to generate Help Banks Balance
fee income and bypass regulatory taxes. For Reputational and
example, until the commitment is taken down, Financial Capital
there is no loan, which means that the bank Optimally
does not have to collect deposits, keep
reserves, or pay deposit insurance premiums. Loan commitments are discretionary contracts
Actually, the bank can sell the commitment, because the MAC clause gives the bank the
collect the fee, and avoid regulatory taxes al- right to refuse a loan when the borrower
together by selling the loan to another bank as requests it. However, if a bank honors its
soon as it is originated.13 However, Kareken commitment even when it is costly to do so,
(1987) reports that there was no change in it can enhance its reputation for keeping its
bank regulatory policy of the sort that would promises. A good reputation makes its future
have prompted banks to start issuing loan commitments more valuable because borrow-
commitments suddenly. From April 1969 ers are willing to pay a premium for a credible
through mid-1973, the Federal Reserve System’s commitment. Thus, a bank may use the loan
reserve requirement schedule was changed commitment to enhance its reputation.
only once, in November 1972, when the aver- Boot, Greenbaum, and Thakor (1993) for-
age reserve requirement was decreased. The malize this idea. The party that has discretion
effective per dollar deposit insurance premium gains the option of taking a costly action. If the
was not changed in that period either. In 1971, cost is sufficiently high, only agents that can
there were no minimum capital-asset ratios. afford to pay the cost can take the action, sig-
Thus, regulatory taxes fail to explain the exis- nal their types, and improve their reputations.
tence of loan commitments. In Boot, Greenbaum, and Thakor’s model,
future spot rates are uncertain. The bank
promises to give the borrower an interest rate
Loan Commitments
subsidy if the future spot rate is too high. The
Improve Banks’
bank is compensated beforehand with a fee
Forecasts of Future
that represents the expected cost of the sub-
Loan Demand
sidy.14 The cost of honoring a discretionary
Greenbaum, Kanatas, and Venezia (1991) loan commitment is that when the borrower
suggest that loan commitments reduce banks’ takes down the loan, the actual subsidy is
uncertainty about future loan demand and its greater than the expected subsidy that the
attendant costs. In their setting, banks can
borrow after the loan demand is known or by
prearrangement. Prearranged funds can be
obtained at a lower interest rate. Recognizing
■ 13 Greenbaum (1986) argues that banks became high-cost lenders
their informational disadvantage, banks offer to because the Federal Reserve and the FDIC ceased to set limits on the rates
share the benefit of their lower funding costs, that banks could pay to creditors; as a result, banks are burdened by higher
provided that clients disclose private informa- borrowing costs as well as regulatory taxes. However, they still maintain
tion regarding prospective credit demand. A their cost advantage as raters of borrowers. Hence, they offer loan commit-
ments and then sell the loans they originate.
loan commitment contract incorporating a
usage fee and a forward interest rate motivates ■ 14 I discussed the same model in the section titled “Loan
honest disclosure of the borrower’s loan Commitments Help Attenuate Moral Hazard.”
12
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

bank was compensated for when the spot rate Banks Can Commit
was still uncertain. Therefore, it is costly for a Themselves Credibly but
bank to honor a commitment. Then, high- Individuals Cannot
quality banks with more economic power than
low-quality banks can signal their type and When individuals sign up for the future
improve their reputational capital by honoring delivery of a product or service, they prefer to
the discretionary contract and reducing their contract with a firm or organization rather than
current financial capital, while low-quality another individual. Thus, individuals buy in-
banks repudiate their commitments, preserve surance from insurance companies and rarely
their financial capital, and forgo the future from other individuals; loan commitments are
benefits of a better reputation. In other words, sold by banks and not by individuals. Why
a loan commitment helps the bank to manage can firms—but not individuals—credibly
its portfolio of financial and reputational commit themselves to supply a product or
capital optimally. service in the future in exchange for current
The idea that banks can use loan commit- compensation?
ments as a signaling mechanism has been Boot, Thakor, and Udell (1991) offer the
empirically verified by Mosebach (1999). His intuition that it is more costly for an organiza-
argument is based on a paper by Billett, tion not to honor its contractual commitments
Flannery, and Garfinkel (1995) reporting that than it is for an individual. In a setting where
“more reputable” lenders give the market more risky debt and limited liability create moral
new information than “less reputable” lenders hazard at sufficiently high interest rates, the
do. Billett, Flannery, and Garfinkel also pro- lender gives the borrower a subsidized rate to
pose that firms endeavor to send the strongest prevent moral hazard and recovers that sub-
signal possible to the market by using the best sidy with an up-front fee paid when the com-
lender. Mosebach argues that large companies, mitment is sold. The problem with an individ-
wishing to send the strongest possible signal to ual lender offering a commitment is that he
the market, use the best bank and largest line can collect the commitment fee, consume his
of credit available. So the purchase of a loan entire wealth, and repudiate the commitment.
commitment transmits the following informa- No penalty or other legal enforcement mecha-
tion: First, by selecting a particular bank, the nism can remedy the situation. To prevent the
borrower signals his belief that this is the best individual lender from consuming his wealth,
lender available to him. Second, the purchase an individual banker with a nonconsumable
communicates to the market new, positive project endowment can collect this wealth as
information about the bank’s current and a deposit and sell a commitment to the bor-
future financial position. Mosebach’s findings rower. If the banker repudiates the contract,
show a positive and significant market reaction a court can seize the banker’s project endow-
to the bank’s stock when the bank grants a ment. The trouble with this setting is that
line of credit. because the subsidy is provided only when
interest rates are high, the commitment fee
reflects only the subsidy’s expected cost and
Banks’ Advantages therefore is less than the ex post amount of the
over Individuals and subsidy. Therefore, the banker will repudiate
Other Institutions the contract if the loss from honoring it (the
in Providing difference between the commitment fee and
Liquidity through the subsidy) is greater than the cost of losing
Commitments its project endowment. In contrast, a bank is
made of a countable infinity of individual
If loan commitments have the benefits described bankers (equity holders), each with a project
in the previous section, then why do not other endowment that will be seized if the commit-
financial intermediaries offer them? The litera- ment is repudiated. Note that in this case, the
ture on this question builds on literature deal- loss incurred by each banker from honoring
ing with the emergence of organizations. So I the commitment is zero because a finite loss is
first explain why institutions’ commitments are divided among an infinity of bankers, while
more credible than individuals’ and then repudiation entails the loss of each banker’s
describe banks’ advantage over other financial project endowment. Clearly, the bank always
intermediaries in selling loan commitments. honors the commitment. Hence, the emer-
gence of organizations prevents market failure
13
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

that might be caused by individuals not honor- count facility makes their expected cost of
ing contracts. Although this result is quite funding commitments lower than that of non-
intuitive, it is unclear why individuals cannot bank competitors. If this subsidy more than
place a fraction of their wealth in an escrow offsets the cost of the reserve requirement,
fund that the courts may seize if the individual only banks will sell commitments.
fails to honor his commitment. Such an escrow Similarly, Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (forth-
fund would easily make individuals’ commit- coming) allude to the cost of the reserve
ments credible. requirement to formalize the cost advantage
Finally, note that the courts play an impor- issue and explain why the intermediary selling
tant role in Boot, Thakor, and Udell (1991) by the loan commitment must be a bank. They
penalizing bank shareholders when commit- show why deposit taking and lending activities
ments are not honored. Boot, Greenbaum, and are carried out by a single institution (commer-
Thakor (1993) ignore the judiciary and show cial bank) rather than separate institutions.
that reputational concerns may be enough to They argue that loan commitments let a bank
induce the banks to keep their promises. How- take advantage of economic synergies between
ever, reputational concerns are not enough to its deposit-taking and lending activities.
explain why banks alone sell loan commit- Demand deposits and loan commitments both
ments; an individual might have similar con- provide liquidity on demand to bank cus-
cerns and honor his commitments. tomers who have unpredictable liquidity
needs. If these contracts require costly over-
head in the form of cash and security holdings,
Banks Have a Cost
a synergy will exist to the extent that the two
Advantage over Other
activities can share some of the costly over-
Institutions
head. A bank that offers both deposits and
It is clear from the previous discussion that loan commitments can get by with a smaller
loan commitments will be sold by institutional total volume of cash and securities on its bal-
lenders. The question is, why must this institu- ance sheet than would two separate institu-
tion be a bank and not another form of finan- tions, each specializing in only one of the two
cial intermediary? Kareken (1987) argues that functions. Hence, efficiency is enhanced.
technological advances decreased the cost of
acquiring and processing information, which
opened the direct credit market to a large Pricing Loan
number of borrowers. These borrowers, how- Commitments
ever, have to be rated and monitored by mar- as Put Options
ket participants. Kareken assumes that techno-
logical advances created a larger decrease in Loan commitments have several similarities to
banks’ information acquisition costs than in put options. The commitment buyer pays a
those of other lenders. Then, purchasing a commitment fee for the right to sell a security
bank loan commitment results in lower direct to the bank at a prespecified price over some
costs for lending, rating, and monitoring previously established time interval. The secu-
because the bank assumes the default risk and rity is the commitment owner’s debt, and the
does the monitoring. Two objections may be strike price is the dollar amount of the borrow-
raised against this argument. First, it is not clear ing. The buyer will exercise the put option and
why technological advances benefit banks take down the loan if the value of his debt on
more than they benefit other intermediaries. the exercise date is less than the committed
Second, Kareken ignores the MAC clause that loan amount. Clearly, this description excludes
relieves the bank of its commitment when the the two most important features of loan
borrower’s financial condition deteriorates. commitments that the literature attempts to
Therefore, Kareken’s argument does not explain explain: the multiple fee structure and the MAC
why banks alone offer loan commitments. clause. Yet, these and other simplifying assump-
Kanatas (1987) provides an informal solu- tions, which I review next, are needed to apply
tion to this puzzle, arguing that only banks sell the option pricing theory to loan commitments.
loan commitments because they have access to
the discount window. Their ability to meet
unexpectedly high commitment loan demand
with relatively low-cost funds from the dis-
14
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

Thakor, Hong, and Greenbaum (1981) net costs to the bank since they imply that the
made the first attempt to rationalize and price borrower is exercising his put option more.
loan commitments as put options.15 Their As the bank obtains new estimates of the bor-
paper develops a model for valuing variable- rower’s productivity, the average of those esti-
rate bank loan commitments within the frame- mates yields a less noisy signal of productivity,
work of the Black and Scholes methodology.16 so price adjustments to unexpectedly high
It is a preliminary step in the valuation of loan takedowns become less significant over time.
commitments and therefore ignores several key The interest rate smoothing that results from
factors in order to obtain a valuation formula. the bank–borrower relationship prevents the
There are four key differences between loan borrower from switching to other banks. This
commitments and exchange-traded put options. last result, however, depends on the strong, if
1) Exchange-traded options are binding, not unrealistic, assumption that the new bank
while loan commitments are discretionary knows nothing about the client’s takedown
because of the MAC clause. history and that new customers are indistin-
2) Loan commitments are not transferable. guishable from switching customers.
3) Loan commitments have a different
pricing structure (usage and service fees).
4) A put option is either exercised in full or II. The Effects of
not at all. Loan takedowns, however, are Loan Commitments
usually only a fraction of the commit- on the Bank’s Risk
ment’s face value. Exposure
The literature has not addressed the ques-
tion of how the first three points affect the I have already mentioned that when a bank
valuation of loan commitments as put options. sells a loan commitment, it accepts the interest
Attempts have been made, however, to explain rate and quantity risk that the customer would
the partial takedown phenomenon. bear if he were to borrow in the spot market.
Thakor, Hong, and Greenbaum (1981) Although the commitment fee is expected to
provide the first explanation of the partial take- compensate the bank for its risk exposure,
down phenomenon. They argue that the future regulators believe that loan commitments
pricing and availability of bank services are increase the risk exposure of banks and the
influenced by the degree to which a customer deposit insurer. Regulators argue that because
exercises his loan commitment, because a gain the potential liability of a loan commitment is
for the customer is a loss to the bank. In estab- not quantified and reflected in the deposit
lishing the price of the commitment and the insurance premium, a bank may be tempted to
size of the fixed mark-up, the bank considers take on excessive risk by expanding its loan
expected borrower behavior under alternate commitments, which may result in an under-
states of the world. If the borrower surprises estimation of the deposit insurer’s risk expo-
the lender by borrowing more than expected, sure. Therefore, regulators have imposed
the lender revises his expectations and adjusts capital requirements against bank loan com-
upward the price and/or the mark-up appli- mitments to control their growth. Some of the
cable to future commitment transactions. literature on loan commitments provides
Therefore, when the firm chooses the take- insight on the merit of these arguments.
down fraction, it minimizes the expected cost
of the next loan plus the opportunity loss from
not taking down the current loan fully.
In Thakor, Hong, and Greenbaum, the bank
uses an exogenous process for updating the
commitment fee and the fixed mark-up based
on take-down behavior. Greenbaum and
Venezia (1985) endogenize this process by
assuming that the loan amount taken down by
the borrower depends on his productivity,
unobservable to the bank. The borrower’s
productivity is subject to random mean-zero ■ 15 Hawkins (1982) argues that revolving credit agreements (loan
changes. The bank infers the borrower’s pro- commitments with infinite maturity) are similar to callable bonds. He bases
his argument on transaction costs to rationalize loan commitments.
ductivity from the takedown. High takedown
signals high productivity; this means that high ■ 16 See Thakor (1982) for the valuation of fixed-rate loan
future takedowns are associated with higher commitments.
15
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

Early papers (Ho and Saunders [1983] and make spot loans to less risky borrowers. The
Koppenhaver [1985]) asked whether the bank intuition is that the bank’s current loan com-
could use financial futures contracts to hedge mitment revenue is an increasing function of
against interest and quantity risks. The main the likelihood that the bank will be solvent in
finding is that unless the spot loan price and the future when it will honor the commitment.
the expected quantity of loan takedowns are Hence, an increase in the riskiness of its spot
perfectly correlated, the bank cannot hedge its loan portfolio causes a reduction in its loan
risks fully. That is, it can hedge against one of commitment revenue. From this result, Boot
the two variables by buying or selling futures and Thakor draw the following important
contracts, but if the two variables are not per- policy implication: The deposit insurer should
fectly correlated, a single type of contract is insist that all of the bank’s outstanding commit-
insufficient to hedge against both types of risk. ments be voided if the bank cannot pay off its
Clearly, these early papers took the increase in depositors and is bailed out by the insurer.
banks’ risk exposure as a given and did not That is, the deposit insurer should transfer
investigate whether loan commitments actually some of the risk to loan commitment cus-
increase the bank’s risk exposure. Avery and tomers to give them an incentive to monitor
Berger (1991) and Boot and Thakor (1991) the bank’s spot loan portfolio.
addressed this issue.17 Clearly, the capital requirements that regula-
Avery and Berger argue that selling a loan tors impose on loan commitments to protect
commitment is risky because the bank is the deposit insurer are not needed because,
locked into lending to a borrower who might unlike other off-balance-sheet liabilities, such
suffer a decline in creditworthiness that would as standby letters of credit for which the bank
otherwise dictate a higher interest rate or no acts as a guarantor, loan commitments with a
loan at all. To make this argument, they assume MAC clause do not impose any credit risk
that invoking the MAC clause is costly and the on the bank. In fact, as Boot and Thakor show,
bank bears the legal costs. However, they do they lower the bank’s asset risk when the bank’s
not clarify why the bank cannot recover loan portfolio is observable to customers.
the costs ex ante with the commitment fee.
Because the borrower’s creditworthiness may
change over time, the bank has less informa- III. Loan Commitments
tion about the borrower when the loan com- and Monetary Policy
mitment is sold than when spot contracts are
signed. This leads to moral hazard. Now, sup- Regulators conduct monetary policy through
pose there are borrowers with and without quantity rationing and interest rate channels by
moral hazard problems. Due to informational altering the quantity of credit and its price, the
difficulties, the bank may ration moral hazard interest rate. Tighter monetary policy creates a
borrowers. If those who are rationed and wait reserve shortage that raises the cost of funds to
for the spot market are safe borrowers (infor- banks. When their cost of funds rise, banks
mation is revealed in the spot market and raise loan rates, which causes businesses and
these borrowers can borrow there), the bank’s consumers to cut down expenditures. The
loan commitment portfolio consists of riskier- interest rate channel implies a relationship
than-average borrowers and the bank’s risk between monetary policy and bank loan rates,
exposure is augmented. Otherwise, if moral loan volume, and economic activity. The quan-
hazard borrowers are the risky ones, the tity rationing channel refers to the possibility
bank’s risk exposure is reduced. Avery and that when banks’ funds costs rise, they choose
Berger empirically find that fewer problem to reduce the volume of loans above any
loans and higher bank income are associated reduction caused by an increase in interest
with loan commitments. Therefore, commit- rates on loan demand. This channel implies a
ments reduce the bank’s risk exposure. direct link between monetary policy and the
Boot and Thakor (1991) find that loan com- quantity of bank loans.
mitments lower bank asset portfolio risk for
two reasons: First, the loan commitment con-
tract can be designed to resolve the asset sub-
stitution problem between the bank and the
borrower.18 Second, if the bank’s existing spot
■ 17 Hassan and Sackley (1994) showed empirically that loan
loan portfolio in a given period is observable
commitments reduce a bank’s risk exposure.
to its loan commitment customers in that
period, then optimally the bank will choose to ■ 18 See the discussion on moral hazard in section I.
16
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

Since loan commitments protect borrowers banks acquire private, firm-specific information
from quantity rationing, in the short run, mon- during their relationship with borrowers and
etary policy changes will affect loans under exploit their informational advantage relative
commitment only through the interest rate to other lenders to earn positive profits in the
channel (Duca and Vanhoose [1990], Morgan future.19 An important implication is that banks
[1994], and Woodford [1996]). If monetary are willing to take losses early if they expect to
policy tightens, banks resort to rationing cus- recover them in the future. In a setting like
tomers without commitment agreements this, a bank can give the borrower a subsidy
(Sofianos, Wachtel, and Melnik [1990] and with a standard debt contract and recover the
Glick and Plaut [1989]). In the long run, as loan subsidy from future transactions rather than
commitments expire, quantity rationing appears with the commitment fee. So it is not clear why
in the form of refusing to renew a commitment a borrower would choose a loan commitment
or reducing its size. Therefore, loan commit- over a spot loan or vice versa. Therefore, we
ments introduce significant lags in the effect of need a model that rationalizes loan commit-
monetary policy (Deshmukh, Greenbaum, and ments in a relationship setting.
Kanatas [1982] and Morgan [1998]). Finally, a loan commitment is an incomplete
contract. Important issues, such as loan maturity
and debt covenants, are left open to negotia-
IV. Concluding tion and are finalized before the loan closes.
Remarks Although loan commitments have been metic-
ulously scrutinized, we know nothing about
I have provided a summary of what we know the properties of loans made under commit-
about loan commitments after years of research. ment. How much the final loan agreement
Although we have gained some understanding differs from the terms specified in the loan
of what value loan commitments provide, our commitment deserves further investigation.
knowledge has clear limitations. For example,
in many instances, economists’ conclusions
depend on the use of fixed-rate commitments,
which are rather uncommon in the market. In
papers where loan commitments can be used
to distinguish between borrowers with a priori
unobservable characteristics, the results are
limited to settings where there are at most
three unobservable types, which is far too
restrictive.
There is still much to be learned about loan
commitments. I conclude by briefly reviewing
three of the major unresolved issues.
First, the courts have often obstructed
banks’ right to invoke the MAC clause and
deny credit to a loan commitment owner,
arguing that the banks had not acted in good
faith (Edelstein [1991] and Budnitz and Chaitman
[1998]). That is, the courts have often inter-
preted banks’ use of the clause as an abuse of
power. This is at odds with the current litera-
ture, which views the MAC clause in loan com-
mitments as providing the bank discretion that
has economic value (Boot, Greenbaum, and
Thakor [1993]). Courts’ reasons for intervening
and the welfare effects of their intervention
remain to be understood. ■ 19 Boot and Thakor (1994) show that long-term relationships are
Second, the analysis of loan commitments feasible even without the learning component. In their model, the bank
has been limited to models where, in most initially lends with a secured contract (collateral is costly) at a high
interest rate. Once the borrower succeeds, future loans are unsecured and
instances, the bank collects a fee at time 0 and
subsidized. This feature induces the borrower to work hard at the outset to
in return provides a subsidy at time 1. Unfor- succeed as soon as possible. In contrast to Rajan’s (1992) relationship
tunately, all these models ignore the fact that setting, in which the borrower is subsidized initially and taxed later, in
bank loans are relationship loans. That is, Boot and Thakor taxation occurs before the subsidy.
17
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

References Calomiris, C.W. “The Motivations for Loan


Commitments Backing Commercial Paper,”
Avery, R.B., and A. Berger. “Loan Commit- Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 13
ments and Bank Risk Exposure,” Journal (1989), pp. 271–77.
of Banking and Finance, vol. 15 (1991),
pp. 173–92. Campbell, T.S. “A Model of the Market for
Lines of Credit,” Journal of Finance, vol. 33
Berkovitch, E., and S.I. Greenbaum. “The (1978), pp. 231–44.
Loan Commitment as an Optimal Financing
Contract,” Journal of Financial and Quanti- Deshmukh, S. D., S.I. Greenbaum, and
tative Analysis, vol. 26 (1991), pp. 83–95. G. Kanatas. “Bank Forward Lending in
Alternative Funding Environments,” Journal
Billett, M.T., M.J. Flannery, and J.A. of Finance, vol. 37 (1982), pp. 925–40.
Garfinkel. “The Effect of Lender Identity on
a Borrowing Firm’s Equity Return,” Journal Duan, J., and S.H. Yoon. “Loan Commit-
of Finance, vol. 50 (1995), pp. 699–718. ments, Investment Decisions and the
Signaling Equilibrium” Journal of Banking
Boot, A.W.A. “Relationship Banking: What Do and Finance, vol. 17 (1993), pp. 645–61.
We Know?,” Journal of Financial Interme-
diation, vol. 9 (2000), pp. 7–25. Duca, J.V., and D.D. Vanhoose. “Loan Com-
mitments and Optimal Monetary Policy,”
________, S.I. Greenbaum, and A.V. Thakor. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking,
“Reputation and Discretion in Financial vol. 22 (1990), pp. 178–94.
Contracting,” American Economic Review,
vol. 83 (1993), pp. 1165–83. Edelstein, P.M. “Effective Letters of Intent and
Commitment Letters,” Journal of Commer-
________, and A.V. Thakor. “Off-balance cial Bank Lending, vol. 73 (1991), pp. 6–16.
Sheet Liabilities, Deposit Insurance and
Capital Regulation,” Journal of Banking Glick, R., and S.E. Plaut. “Money Demand
and Finance, vol. 15 (1991), pp. 825–46. and Off-Balance Sheet Liquidity: Empirical
Analysis and Implications for Monetary
________, and ________. “Moral Hazard and Policy,” Journal of Accounting, Auditing,
Secured Lending in an Infinitely Repeated and Finance, vol. 4 (1989), pp. 147–59.
Credit Market Game,” International Eco-
nomic Review, vol. 35 (1994), pp. 899–920. Goldberg, K.J. “Lender Liability and Good
Faith,” Boston University Law Review, vol. 68
________, ________, and G.F. Udell. “Compe- (1988), p. 653.
tition, Risk Neutrality and Loan Commit-
ments,” Journal of Banking and Finance, Greenbaum, S.I. “Securitization, Regulatory
vol. 11 (1987), pp. 449–71. Reform, and Bank Asset Quality,” Unpub-
lished manuscript, 1986.
________, ________, and ________. “Credible
Commitments, Contract Enforcement Prob- _________, and A.V. Thakor. Contemporary
lems and Banks: Intermediation as Credibil- Financial Intermediation. Fort Worth, Texas,
ity Assurance,” Journal of Banking and Dryden Press, 1995.
Finance, vol. 15 (1991), pp. 605–32.
_________, and I. Venezia. “Partial Exercise of
Booth, J.R., and L. Chua. “Structure and Loan Commitments under Adaptive Pricing,”
Pricing of Large Bank Loans,” Federal Journal of Financial Research, vol. 8 (1985),
Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic pp. 251–63.
Review, no. 3 (1995), pp. 52–62.
________, G. Kanatas, and I. Venezia. “Loan
Budnitz, M.E., and H.D. Chaitman. Law of Commitments and the Management of
Lender Liability. Arlington, Va.: A.S. Pratt & Uncertain Demand,” Journal of Real Estate
Sons, 1998. Finance and Economics, vol. 4 (1991),
pp. 351–66.
18
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

Hassan, M.K., and W.H. Sackley. “A Method- Koppenhaver, G. D. “Variable-Rate Loan


ological Investigation of Risk Exposure of Commitments, Deposit Withdrawal Risk and
Bank Off-Balance Sheet Loan Commitment Anticipatory Hedging,” Journal of Futures
Activities,” Quarterly Review of Economics Markets, vol. 5 (1985), pp. 317–30.
and Finance, vol. 34 (1994), pp. 283–99.
Maksimovic, V. “Product Market Imperfec-
Hawkins, G.D. “An Analysis of Revolving tions and Loan Commitments,” Journal of
Credit Agreements,” Journal of Financial Finance, vol. 45 (1990), pp. 1641–54.
Economics, vol. 10 (1982), pp. 59–81.
Manino, E.F. “Lender Liability and Other Com-
Ho, T.S.Y., and A. Saunders. “Fixed Rate plex Litigation Involving Financial Institu-
Loan Commitments, Take-Down Risk and tions,” study materials, ALI-ABA Conference,
Dynamics of Hedging with Futures,” February 17–18, 1994, Palm Beach, Florida.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis, vol. 18 (1983), pp. 499–516. Morgan, D.P. “Financial Contracts when Costs
and Returns are Private,” Journal of Mone-
Houston, J.F., and S. Venkataraman. “Infor- tary Economics, vol. 31 (1993), pp. 129–46.
mation Revelation, Lock-In, and Bank Loan
Commitments,” Journal of Financial Inter- _________. “Bank Credit Commitments, Credit
mediation, vol. 3 (1994), pp. 355–78. Rationing and Monetary Policy,” Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 26 (1994),
________, and ________. “Liquidation Under pp. 87–101.
Moral Hazard: Optimal Debt Maturity and
Loan Commitments,” Journal of Banking _________. “The Credit Effects of Monetary
and Finance, vol. 20 (1996), pp. 115–33. Policy: Evidence Using Loan Commitments,”
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking,
James, C. “Self-selection and the Pricing of vol. 30 (1998), pp. 102–18.
Bank Services: an Analysis of the Market for
Loan Commitments and the Role of Com- Mosebach, M. “Market Response to Banks
pensating Balance Requirements,” Journal Granting Lines of Credit,” Journal of
of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Banking and Finance, vol. 23 (1999),
vol. 16 (1981), pp. 725–46. pp. 1707–23.

________. “An Analysis of Bank Loan Rate Petersen, M.A., and R. Rajan. “The Effect of
Indexation,” Journal of Finance, vol. 37 Credit Market Competition on Lending Rela-
(1982), pp. 809–25. tionships,” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
vol. 110 (1995), pp. 407–42.
Kanatas, G. “Commercial Paper, Bank Reserve
Requirements, and the Informational Role of Rajan, R. “Insiders and Outsiders: The Choice
Loan Commitments,” Journal of Banking Between Informed and Arm’s-Length Debt,”
and Finance, vol. 11 (1987), pp. 425–48. Journal of Finance, vol. 47 (1992),
pp. 1367–1400.
Kareken, J.H. “The Emergence and Regu-
lation of Contingent Commitment Banking,” Sharpe, S.A. “Asymmetric Information, Bank
Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 11 Lending, and Implicit Contracts: A Stylized
(1987), pp. 359–77. Model of Customer Relationships,” Journal
of Finance, vol. 45 (1990), pp. 1069–87.
Kashyap, A.K., R. Rajan, and J.C. Stein.
“Banks as Liquidity Providers: An Expla- Shockley, R.L. “Bank Loan Commitments and
nation for the Co-Existence of Lending and Corporate Leverage,” Journal of Financial
Deposit-Taking,” Journal of Finance, Intermediation, vol. 4 (1995), pp. 272–301.
(forthcoming).
19
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 2001 Q3

_________, and A.V. Thakor. “Bank Loan


Commitment Contracts: Data, Theory and
Tests,” Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, vol. 29 (1997), pp. 517–34.

Sofianos, G., P. Wachtel, and A. Melnik.


“Loan Commitments and Monetary Policy,”
Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 14
(1990), pp. 677–89.

Thakor, A.V. “Toward a Theory of Bank Loan


Commitments,” Journal of Banking and
Finance, vol. 6 (1982), pp. 55–83.

_________. “Competitive Equilibrium with


Type Convergence in an Asymmetrically
Informed Market,” Review of Financial
Studies, vol. 21 (1989), pp. 49–71.

________, H. Hong, and S.I. Greenbaum.


“Bank Loan Commitments and Interest Rate
Volatility,” Journal of Banking and Finance,
vol. 5 (1981), pp. 497–510.

________, and G.F. Udell. “An Economic


Rationale for the Pricing Structure of Bank
Loan Commitments,” Journal of Banking
and Finance, vol. 11 (1987), pp. 271–89.

Woodford, M. “Loan Commitments and Opti-


mal Monetary Policy,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, vol. 37 (1996), pp. 573–605.

You might also like