You are on page 1of 4

NOTE NUMBER 305

35668
P U B L I C P O L I C Y F O R T H E

privatesector
MARCH 2006

Postconflict Infrastructure
Jordan Schwartz and Trends in Aid and Investment Flows
Pablo Halkyard
As war and civil strife subside, can governments turn to the private
Jordan Schwartz
sector to restore basic ser vices? Postconflict countries suffer from
(jschwartz3@worldbank.org)
is a senior infrastructure dispropor tionately low levels of private investment in infrastructure,
specialist in the Finance,
T H E W O R L D B A N K G R O U P PRIVATE SECTOR DEVELOPMENT VICE PRESIDENCY

with only small-scale ser vice providers likely to emerge during and right
Private Sector, and
Infrastructure Department after conflict. Larger investors are slow to enter, and when they do they
of the World Bank’s Latin focus almost exclusively on the easily secured and most profitable
America and the Caribbean
Region. Pablo Halkyard subsectors. Yet some countries have been able to couple aggressive
(phalkyard@worldbank.org) reform and liberalized policies to attract infrastructure investments
is a private sector
development associate in the
soon after conflict abates. What does their experience tell us?
World Bank and
Developing countries affected by conflict, par- vate participation in infrastructure in post-
International Finance
Corporation’s Private Sector
ticularly those that can be characterized as weak conflict countries.2
Development Vice Presidency. or nonfunctioning states, have been markedly
less successful than others in attracting private The paradox of postconflict aid flows . . .
This Note summarizes an investment in infrastructure.1 These countries Aid tends to peak immediately after conflict
analysis from a paper by also face the greatest needs, because of the lack (figure 1). As a country emerges from conflict
Jordan Schwartz, Shelly of investment during conflict and because of and captures the attention of the international
Hahn, and Ian Bannon their low income levels—more than three- community, donors generally increase aid to
(2004). A companion quarters of the nonfunctioning states are classi- support peace and begin reconstruction. Using
Note explores policy fied as low income. Thus while poor com- aid effectively during the early postconflict years
options for postconflict munities in all developing countries suffer from is extremely difficult, however. Within the first
countries seeking to lack of access to infrastructure services, those in decade aid tends to initially spike, then to grad-
attract private investment conflict-affected countries suffer disproportion- ually decline. But during this initial period most
in infrastructure ately (table 1). postconflict countries face political and admin-
(Schwartz and Halkyard Despite the challenges these high-risk coun- istrative constraints that limit their capacity to
2006). tries face in attracting significant, long-term pri- absorb this increased aid.
vate investment in infrastructure, private activity The constraints on absorptive capacity are
does occur. The patterns of this activity suggest especially severe for project aid. Setting up
policy approaches that could help expand pri- administrative, accounting, financial manage-
P O S T C O N F L I C T I N F R A S T R U C T U R E TRENDS IN AID AND INVESTMENT FLOWS

Infrastructure services: indicators of access, use, and quality


time postconflict countries develop the capacity
Table
to efficiently absorb it. This is also precisely

1 Infrastructure
Sub-Saharan Africa
Conflict-
affected
Non-conflict-
affected South
High-
income
when such countries badly need infrastructure
investments to sustain the initial postconflict
growth spurt and help prevent a relapse into
service countries countriesa Africa countries conflict.3 Research has shown that faster growth
Electricity (kilowatt-hours tends to reduce the risk of further conflict
used per capita) 96 384b 3,793 8,421 directly and cumulatively by raising income lev-
Telecommunications (fixed
els (Collier and others 2003).
and mobile lines
per 1,000 people) 19 67 410 1,283
. . . and of postconflict investment flows
Roads (percentage paved) 13 27 20 93
Water (percentage of The initial period of high growth and large aid
population with access inflows in postconflict countries is paralleled by
to improved source) 52 67 86 96c a period of inactivity in private investment in
infrastructure: little such investment typically
Note: Data are for the most recent year available in the source. Averages weight each country equally.
a. Excludes South Africa. occurs for the first five years after conflict abates
b. Based on nine countries for which data were available. (figure 2). Large-scale investments in infra-
c. Based on data for Australia, the Republic of Korea, Spain, and the United Kingdom.
Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators database (2003 edition). structure tend to materialize only after post-
conflict countries have maintained stability for
ment, fiduciary, and procurement systems takes a sufficient period—that is, at about the time
time, especially in countries where conflict has that aid slows and growth declines. Again para-
weakened institutions and human capacity. doxically, it is during those initial postconflict
Immediately after conflict, countries can better years that investments are most needed to pro-
absorb aid provided as direct budgetary support. vide basic services, reignite the local private sec-
But many donors face restrictions on providing tor, strengthen growth prospects, and lessen the
such support or have governance concerns that likelihood of a return to conflict.
dissuade them from doing so. So, for a post-
conflict country needing substantial investments Small-scale private providers step in
in infrastructure, aid-funded projects offer little In contrast to large investors, small-scale private
relief in the initial postconflict phase. service providers are quick to set up shop after
To make matters worse, paradoxically aid conflict abates—and sometimes even during
begins to decline precipitously at just about the conflict. In Cambodia hundreds of tiny private

GDP growth and official development Investment in infrastructure projects with


Figure assistance by year after conflict Figure private participation by year after conflict

1 Percent
20
ODA as a percentage
2 El Salvador

Year 0 400
Other countries
2002 US$ millions
800 1,200 1,600
of GDP 0
10
1
GDP growth 2
0 3
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
4
Year
5
–10
6
7
–20 8
Note: Based on data for 10 countries that have emerged from war since 1990 and for Note: Based on data for 10 countries that have emerged from war since 1990 and for
which eight years of consistent data were available: Azerbaijan, Cambodia, El Salvador, which eight years of consistent data were available: Azerbaijan, Cambodia, El Salvador,
Georgia, Lebanon, Mozambique, Nicaragua, Rwanda, Tajikistan, and the Republic of Yemen. Georgia, Lebanon, Mozambique, Nicaragua, Rwanda, Tajikistan, and the Republic of Yemen.
Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators database (2003 edition). Source: World Bank, Private Participation in Infrastructure (PPI) Project Database.
power networks established themselves through- Investment in infrastructure projects with private participation by
out the countryside during and after the civil Table country and conflict status, 1990–2002
strife of the 1990s, effectively filling the void left
by the nonfunctioning national utility. Similar
stories can be found throughout postconflict
countries. Indeed, about half the countries with
2 Indicator
Non-conflict-
affected
countries (107)
All conflict-
affected
countries (31)
Nonfunctioning
conflict-affected
countries (25)
Average total investment
significant small-scale private provision of water
in 1990–2002
and electricity services are conflict affected (US$ billions) 5.9 3.6 0.6
(Kariuki and Schwartz 2005). Average annual
investment (US$ millions) 455 278 46
Diverging trends in investment levels Average annual
Developing countries affected by conflict have investment as a
attracted far less large-scale private participation percentage of GDP 0.92 0.93 0.74
in infrastructure than other developing coun- Countries with no
tries (table 2). Still, the trend in private partici- investment (percent) 3 13 16
pation in conflict-affected countries is similar to
Note: Figures in parentheses are the number of countries in the category.
that for all developing countries (figure 3). That Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from World Bank, Private Participation in Infrastructure (PPI) Project Database and World
Development Indicators database (2003 edition).
suggests that, as a whole, conflict-affected coun-
tries are subject to the same supply-side con-
Trends in investment in infrastructure projects with private participation
straints as other developing countries. Figure by country group, 1990–2002
But the trend for nonfunctioning conflict-
affected states, which face even greater chal-
lenges in attracting investment, diverges
dramatically from the general ups and downs of
3 Conflict-affected and
non-conflict-affected countries
(US$ billions)
100
Nonfunctioning
conflict-affected countries
(US$ billions)
4
the overall trend. The likely reason is that the
risks associated with investing in infrastructure 80 Non-conflict affected 3
in nonfunctioning states are so great that they
deter all but a few investors, with a profile far dif- 60 2
ferent from that of the general community of
infrastructure investors. 40 1
Nonfunctioning conflict affected
The sectoral sequencing of investment
20 All conflict affected 0
Private investment in infrastructure in post-
conflict countries follows a clear sequence of
0 –1
sectors, with mobile telephony the only one 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002
likely to attract significant investment immedi-
Source: World Bank, Private Participation in Infrastructure (PPI) Project Database.
ately after conflict (figure 4). All the post-
conflict countries analyzed had at least one pri-
vate mobile operator investing in the country retail risks make privatizing distribution difficult,
after it emerged from war. The willingness of particularly in the early postconflict years. In
mobile operators to invest in high-risk environ- transport most private investment goes to sea-
ments reflects the rapid cost recovery allowed ports, probably because container terminals offer
by the sector’s economics. the potential for earning hard currency and
Beyond telecommunications, the attractive- because bulk facilities can be incorporated into
ness of infrastructure investments in postconflict vertically integrated logistics systems. Investments
countries drops precipitously (Schwartz, Hahn, in rail, roads, and airports normally occur only sev-
and Bannon 2004). Power projects remain some- eral years after conflict. The water and sanitation
what attractive, particularly in generation, where sector receives the least investment and is the last
projects start to emerge three years after conflict to receive foreign investment—though it often
and increase in frequency after five years. But has the greatest needs.
P O S T C O N F L I C T I N F R A S T R U C T U R E TRENDS IN AID AND INVESTMENT FLOWS

Sector distribution of infrastructure infrastructure are more sensitive to perceptions


projects with private participation by year of political and economic instability than those in
Figure after conflict other businesses, such as extractive or final assem-

4 Year 0
Telecoms

4
Energy Transport
Number of projects
8 12
Water

16
bly industries. Infrastructure investors also are
more sensitive to improvements in country risk
ratings in conflict-affected countries than in oth-
viewpoint
0 ers; and these countries are rated riskier on aver-
age. That means that improving the underlying
1 is an open forum to
factors influencing political and economic risk
encourage dissemination of
2 ratings may lead to faster growth in infrastructure
public policy innovations for
3 investment in conflict-affected countries than in private sector–led and
other developing countries.
4 market-based solutions for
development. The views
5
published are those of the
6 authors and should not be
7 Notes attributed to the World
1. For a list of conflict-affected countries (broken Bank or any other affiliated
8
down between functioning and weak or nonfunctioning organizations. Nor do any of
Note: Based on data for 10 countries that have emerged from war since 1990 and for states), see Schwartz, Hahn, and Bannon (2004, annex 1). the conclusions represent
which eight years of consistent data were available: Azerbaijan, Cambodia, El Salvador,
Georgia, Lebanon, Mozambique, Nicaragua, Rwanda, Tajikistan, and the Republic of Yemen. Except where otherwise noted, data for conflict-affected official policy of the World
Source: World Bank, Private Participation in Infrastructure (PPI) Project Database.
countries in this Note refer to that set of countries. Bank or of its Executive
2. For an in-depth discussion of policy options, see Directors or the countries
The effect of country risk Schwartz and Halkyard (2006). they represent.

While trends in general foreign direct investment 3. Collier and others (2003) estimate that a country
(FDI) cannot be correlated with country risk rat- emerging from a civil war typically faces a 44 percent To order additional copies

ings for developing countries, trends in private chance of returning to conflict within five years. contact Suzanne Smith,

investment in infrastructure can be—for both managing editor,


Room F 4K-206,
conflict-affected and non-conflict-affected coun- References
The World Bank,
tries (figure 5). That suggests that investors in Collier, Paul, V. L. Elliott, Håvard Hegre, Anke
1818 H Street, NW,
Hoeffler, Marta Reynal-Querol, and Nicholas Sambanis.
Washington, DC 20433.
Correlation between country risk and 2003. Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development
private participation in infrastructure in Policy. New York: Oxford University Press.
conflict-affected and other developing Telephone:
Figure countries Kariuki, Mukami, and Jordan Schwartz. 2005. “Small-
001 202 458 7281
Scale Private Service Providers of Water and Electricity.”

5 Country risk
rating
50
Policy Research Working Paper 3727. World Bank,
Washington, D.C.
Schwartz, Jordan, and Pablo Halkyard. 2006.
Fax:
001 202 522 3480
Email:
ssmith7@worldbank.org
Conflict affected
“Rebuilding Infrastructure: Policy Options for Attracting
40 Private Funds after Conflict.” Viewpoint series, Note 306. Produced by Grammarians,
FDI/GDP in developing World Bank Group, Private Sector Development Vice
countries Inc.
30 Presidency, Washington, D.C.
Non-conflict affected
Schwartz, Jordan, Shelly Hahn, and Ian Bannon. 2004. Printed on recycled paper
20 “The Private Sector’s Role in the Provision of
0 1 2 Infrastructure in Post-Conflict Countries: Patterns and
Investment in infrastructure projects with private
participation as a percentage of GDP Policy Options.” CPR Working Paper 16. World Bank,
Washington, D.C.
Note: Excludes Mozambique and the Philippines from conflict-affected countries. Country
risk ratings are by Euromoney. They range from 0 (lowest) to 100 (a perfect score).
Source: Authors’ analysis based on Euromoney country risk ratings and data from
World Bank, Private Participation in Infrastructure (PPI) Project Database and
World Development Indicators database (2003 edition).

This Note is available online:


http://rru.worldbank.org/PublicPolicyJournal

You might also like