You are on page 1of 15

Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 2008, 1, 115–129

doi:10.1093/cjres/rsm002

The place of ‘place’ in theories of poverty: mobility,


social capital and well-being

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
Bill Jordan
School of Applied Psychosocial Studies University of Plymouth, Drake Circus, Plymouth, PL4
8AA, UK bill.jordan@plymouth.ac.uk

This article argues that theories about the spatial distribution of poverty since World War II
have always combined analyses of the impact of the built environment, of culture and of
mobility of populations. However, the form taken by these combinations has varied with the
logic of the underlying political economy adopted by governments in the USA, UK and
continental Europe. The author argues that a new version may be emerging, reflecting ideas
from theory on social capital and well-being.

Key words: poverty, mobility, social capital, well-being, community


JEL classifications: H3, H4, I3, O2

Introduction (i) As part of the welfare state tradition, in which


This article will trace how three elements in the theory Squalor was one of Beveridge’s Five Giants to
of poverty and place have been related to each other in be slain (Beveridge, 1942), the built environ-
social science since the Second World War. These ment was the primary focus of post-war theories
three are the physical infrastructure (or built environ- of poverty and place. The targets of theorizing
ment); mobility (the turnover of population, and the were slum clearance and building standards, the
social characteristics of those coming, staying and age of the housing stock and its state of repair,
leaving); and culture (interactions between residents, and ‘the problem of rent’ in income mainte-
leading to shared norms and collective practices). nance policy. Mobility entered the equation
These three have always been parts of social mainly in terms of the relocation of old slum
scientific theorizing about how poverty relates to communities on new estates, and culture in
place, but the way that they have been combined terms of the better opportunities for quality of
has varied markedly over time. We may at present life in these salubrious environments.
be in a new transition, in which mobility is perhaps (ii) In the 1970s the emphasis began to shift towards
replacing culture as the key factor in explaining the cultures of deprived communities as a factor
the dynamics of impoverishment in deprived dis- in their poverty, and to individual exit as a rem-
tricts, and its impact on well-being is being criti- edy to the social problems of these communities.
cally assessed in the light of research on well-being. As governments started to look to markets and
To summarize the argument, it will be suggested market-like solutions to what had been seen as
that the most influential theorists, first in the UK collective issues, mobility and choice were
and then in the USA, connected up these elements regarded as features of social relations to be pro-
as follows: moted, and the culture of deprived communities

Ó The Author 2008. Published by Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.
For permissions, please email: journals.permissions@oxfordjournals.org
B. Jordan

as a brake on these opportunities, which held In other words, there was an in-built set of cultural
members back. and political analyses, in terms of the failure of cap-
(iii) Thirty years on, and after countless initiatives italism to supply an adequate physical infrastructure

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
for ‘social inclusion’, ‘community cohesion’, for working-class citizenship, and the need for state
‘civil renewal’, ‘respect’ and ‘integration’, action to enable not just the new culture of democratic
which focused on both the regeneration of the membership appropriate for the post-war world, but
physical infrastructure, and attempts to trans- also to retain the loyalty of a working class which
form the culture of these districts, the latest might otherwise cast approving glances at Soviet-
thinking is that we must re-examine the part style communism in Central and Eastern Europe.
played by mobility in their problems. But we should also not forget that critiques of
pre-war social policy in the USA, UK and Europe
also dealt in issues of mobility and culture, as well as
If residents sustain a low quality of life, it is not so the shortcomings of unmodified capitalist develop-
much because of the absence of social capital as ment. The Chicago School’s analyses of crime and
the wrong kind of social capital; and the exit of poverty emphasized ‘interstitial districts’ in cities,
more resourceful residents is seen as a problem, which were inhabited by successive waves of new
rather than a remedy. The ‘well-being turn’ in immigrants (from the rural south and from abroad),
psychology and economics had led to a critique the most successful of whom moved quickly on to
of mobility and choice, as undermining commu- other neighbourhoods (Park et al., 1935).
nity, belonging and collective action. Its potential Gang culture and gang conflict were responses to
lies in its focus on mainstream social relations, its the anomie experienced by youth in such anony-
challenge to the hegemony of orthodox microeco- mous districts, with few reliable community bonds.
nomic analysis, and hence its invitation to other New social housing schemes attempted to create
social sciences to influence policies on poverty. a social environment of security and belonging, as
Each of these approaches to the spatial distribu- well as decent physical standards. This is evoca-
tion of, and environmental factors in poverty had tively recalled by Richard Sennett in his recent
a corresponding political economy–a set of inter- book, Respect, in which he describes in detail
linked ideas about economic development and gov- his childhood on just such a scheme in Chicago
ernment, which led to policies for housing and the (Sennett, 2003). These ideas were part of the theo-
wider physical infrastructure. Although it is beyond retical repertoire which informed post-war social
the scope of this article to deal in these policies in housing policies in the UK, and also the reconstruc-
detail, indications will be given of how theories tion programmes all over Europe, where it would
linking poverty to place influenced the broad out- have been fascism rather than crime which was seen
lines of the programmes adopted in each period. as a toxic by-product of the urban anomie spawned
by poverty-driven mobility.
The post-war period It is too simple to characterize the political econ-
It is not necessary to labour the point about the wel- omy of the post-war era as ‘Keynesian’. It built on
fare state’s assumption that the evils of poverty were an approach to public finance and the economics of
strongly reinforced by the physical environment of welfare that long pre-dated The General Theory of
the slum districts where poor people were concen- Employment, Interest and Money (Keynes, 1936).
trated. The assumption behind the new social hous- For instance, it is striking to come across the fol-
ing developments of that period was explicitly that lowing sentence:
these new, hygienic, well-appointed and potentially
convivial facilities would allow the flowering of the Provided that the dividend accruing to the poor is
kinds of democratic citizenship which social policy not diminished, increases in the aggregate na-
promoted, and pre-war conditions blocked. tional dividend of the community, unless they

116
The place of ‘place’ in theories of poverty

result from coercing people to work more than very generally, one might hazard the opinion that
they wish to do, carry with them increases in in Britain housing policy has been more deeply
economic welfare. embedded in the wrangles of party politics, that

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
housing legislation is more complicated, and the
These are not the words of Rawls, nor even of administration is more fussy and paternal than in
Keynes, but of A. C. Pigou (1920, ch. VII, secs most of the countries of continental Europe
1–4, summary). In Pigou’s work, there is already (Marshall, 1965, 153).
the combination of micro-analysis in terms of mar-
ginal product and cost, and macro-analysis, in A less explicit goal of this period of construction
which government uses various instruments of reg- was its direct contribution to economic growth.
ulation, redistribution and intervention (including Whereas expenditure on housing for the poor had
measures to establish a ‘national minimum standard hitherto been seen mainly in terms of redistribution
of real income’) to mediate between poverty and for the sake of social justice, both slum clearance
GDP (Pigou, 1920, ch. XIII). So, for example, in and house building programmes in the colonies of
the UK between 1924 and 1936, two-thirds of the affluent states began to be recognized as tools of
new houses built were constructed by local author- economic development. ‘The colonial powers, in-
ities (Hicks, 1947, 27); in the USA, the New Deal cluding Britain and France, had formed a fairly
spawned social housing projects of the kind de- clear idea about the economic significance of hous-
scribed by Sennett. ing by the 1950s’ (Arku and Harris, 2005, 910).
The role of government, both central and local, This view was deployed within a political econ-
was therefore to plan, and usually to supply, what- omy of government-led intervention in housing
ever public goods and services were required to supply as an aspect of reconciling the principles
achieve a Pareto-efficient distribution of resources, of the welfare states with economic growth.
under constitutional principles similar to those later These theoretical assumptions informing post-
adopted by Rawls (1972) in his account of social war social housing policy persisted right into the
justice (Mueller, 1979, ch. 1). The notion of a ‘na- late 1960s: for instance, Des Wilson’s book I Know
tional minimum standard’ for the poor was built it was the Place’s Fault (1970), used evidence of
into this model, and adopted in all affluent democ- poor housing conditions to explain the persistence
racies. In Europe and the UK, given the scale of war of concentrations of poverty.
damage, the first duty of government in relation
to the social environment was ‘to build houses as Culture as crucial, mobility as exit
fast as possible . . . with the resources available’
(Donnison and Chapman, 1965, 48), principally The culture of poverty
on the basis of social needs, and with local author- The post-war consensus started to crumble in the
ities as the prime movers. As T. H. Marshall put it: 1970s, and this was evidenced in the field of location-
based poverty by the rise of highly-politicized cultural
the ingredients of which housing policies were explanations of the persistence of poverty, and also of
compounded remained essentially the same as policies which promoted exit from poor communities
before the war—subsidies, cheap loans, tax rather than investment in their physical infra-
relief, rent restrictions and rent allowances. No- structures. The implication was that aspects of poor
body came to the rescue with any new ideas, people’s collective lives perpetuated poverty, so pub-
unless one were to count as such the British ini- lic money spent on the built environment would
tiative in the creation of New Towns. The differ- be wasted, and it was better to enable individuals to
ence between the various national policies were escape them.
[sic] caused, rather, by the different ways in The locus classicus for the culture of poverty liter-
which the old devices were employed. Speaking ature was Oscar Lewis’s two anthropological studies,

117
B. Jordan

La Vida (1969) and The Children of Sanchez (1964), (1965) analysis of exclusive clubs (as suppliers of
which documented the lives of Puerto Rican and collective goods to fee-paying members) and on the
Mexican immigrants in New York and other cities, supply of public goods (Buchanan, 1968), all of

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
identifying ways in which family, kinship and com- which pointed to the possibilities of ‘consumer sov-
munity reinforced practices which in turn perpetu- ereignty’ in what had been taken to be inescapably
ated poverty. In Lewis’s account, these included: government-led allocations.
These theorists were already reformulating the
the absence of childhood, as a specially pro- analysis of public finance, by applying a strict
longed and protected stage in the life cycle, early methodological individualism to fields in which
initiation into sex, free unions and consensual Pigou and Beveridge, as much as Keynes, had dealt
marriages, a relatively high incidence of the in ‘aggregates’ and collective interests. Instead of
abandonment of wives and children, a trend to- a duty of the sovereign state to supply optimum
wards female or mother-centred families and public goods (Hicks, 1947, 17–22), they substituted
consequently a much greater knowledge of the sovereignty of the citizen-consumer, shifting
maternal relatives (Lewis, 1969, 53). between a range of providers of collective infra-
structures and services. This was argued to enable
They also included individual feelings of margin- democratic consensus around the costs and condi-
ality and helplessness, ‘weak ego and poor impulse tions for such provision to members of these ‘clubs’
control’ and little ability to defer gratification. and jurisdictions, as well as economic efficiency in
This view of the culture of poverty became an supplying ‘local and particular’ goods to those who
official orthodoxy in the USA and the UK, pioneered opted to join them (Buchanan, 1967; Tullock, 1967;
by Sir Keith Joseph, Margaret Thatcher’s mentor, in Buchanan and Tullock, 1962; Musgrave, 1959).
the UK (Jordan, 1974). It was highly consistent with This new political economy promoted the major
a supply-side approach to problems of unemploy- restructuring of government, and especially local gov-
ment (improvements in character and human capital ernment, which took place in the Anglophone coun-
are necessary conditions for successful labour mar- tries from the mid-1970s onwards. The change which
ket policies). But it also meshed very snugly with accompanied the deregulation of labour markets, the
developments in theoretical economics. erosion of social protection and decline in manual
wages, involved a shift to entrepreneurial local leader-
Mobility and consumer sovereignty ship, competition between localities, fiscal austerity,
The revolution in the theory of public finance which privatization of public assets and the replacement of
took place in the 1980s was initiated by the article public monopoly local services by managerialist insti-
by Charles Tiebout in 1956, entitled ‘A pure theory tutions and contracting out to commercial organiza-
of local expenditures’, which showed that, under tions (Brenner and Theodore, 2002; Jessop, 2002;
a set of very demanding assumptions about full Corry and Stoker, 2002; Geddes, 2006).
information, costless mobility and lack of external- This produced the ‘neo-liberalization of urban
ities, households could sort themselves into the op- space’, or ‘neo-liberal localization’—a process of
timal memberships of jurisdictions for the efficient institutional deregulation and intensified inter-
supply of collective infrastructures and services spatial competition (Corry and Stoker, 2002, 18–23).
(Tiebout, 1956). In this environment, unskilled, sick, dis-
In other words, ‘voting with the feet’, by auton- abled and minority ethnic people were multiply
omous, mobile citizens, was a superior alternative disadvantaged—by their relative immobility, their
to the forms of social engineering under which local lack of access to owner occupation, their vulnera-
authorities had tried to supply public goods and bility to unemployment and poverty, and the decay
social services to their communities. This work of the physical environments in which they found
was, of course, backed up by J. M. Buchanan’s themselves concentrated. In an individualistic,

118
The place of ‘place’ in theories of poverty

competitive, economic environment, they could 24–25)—being of foreign origin was an even stron-
compensate for these disadvantages only through ger influence on the ability to live in a desirable
local (and often deviant) solidarities of resistance district than income (Maurin, 2004, 91). Meanwhile,

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
practices (Jordan, 1996, 2006a). The new political government policy imposed ‘segregation from
economy, which installed markets at the centre of above’ on poor and minority citizens through social
social and political life (Finlayson, 2003; Gilbert, housing schemes (Begag, 2004; Nicholls, 2006).
2004), ironically made poor people more reliant on
their local cultural resources (networks of kinship
and friendship) than they had been in the post-war Measuring and explaining the persistence of
era. Men especially were less likely to belong to poverty
formal organizations (Hall, 2002; Bynner and At the same time, the academic sociological
Parsons, 2003), but more likely to be involved in and social policy analysis of poverty in the USA
the informal (often illegal) economy. and the UK had moved away from the physical
All these tendencies were far more marked in the environment and housing as a major focus, and
UK, USA, New Zealand and Australia than in con- turned towards the definition and measurement of
tinental European countries. In the theoretical tra- poverty—the so-called ‘rediscovery of poverty’ by
dition within which poverty was analysed in Harrington (1962) in the USA and Townsend and
Germany and France, policies were more concerned Abel-Smith (1965) in the UK—and to the dynamics
with ‘the conservation and utilization of human of income maintenance programmes.
beings as valued resource of the state [so that] their After the heavy involvement of sociologists and
end is not the positive enhancement of life but the anthropologists in the Great Society Antipoverty Pro-
augmentation of the national estate’ (Dean, 1991, grammes in the US, and the Community Develop-
34)—a mercantilist tradition which was more en- ment projects in the UK (1965–70), the ideological
during than the Anglophone legacy of state welfar- backlash against the politicization of poverty (protests
ism in the twentieth century. and social movements) sought to take the whole issue
The scope for radicalism in applying new princi- off the streets, and entrust it to economists and Trea-
ples was greatest in the UK, where some 30% of the suries. At the same time, the more technical analysis
housing stock was owned by local authorities, and of poverty, embodied in the UK by the work of Peter
around 200,000 new homes a year were still being Townsend, and especially his Poverty in the United
built in this sector in 1970. Selling off council Kingdom (1979), paid less attention to the social and
houses to tenants was a flagship programme of political relations of poverty, and more to relative
Margaret Thatcher’s reforms. It enabled the trans- incomes. In continental Europe too, the study of
formation of urban spaces, and broke down the poverty shifted towards the dynamic between earn-
solidarities of local politics by allowing new differ- ings, taxes and benefits, and away from social and
entiations between social groups to develop. With environmental factors (Walker et al., 1984).
larger rented sectors, continental European coun- In the USA, looking back on the late 1960s and
tries had no such sudden policy shifts. the 1970s, Haveman (1987) wrote that ‘the War on
Even so, the exclusion of poor and minority eth- Poverty was conceived as an economic war: the
nic citizens from sought-after facilities (such as designs, debates, and the evaluations were all con-
schools) and desirable districts was identifiable, ducted by economists. Economics was the central
for instance in France, by the early 1990s (Paugam, discipline in both the notion and the research com-
1998). By the middle of the following decade, soci- ponents of the war’ (Haveman, 1987, 51–52). And it
ologists were commenting on ‘the extraordinary se- was economists who published papers on the dam-
lectivity of residential mobility, revealing the age to work incentives and family structures of the
almost infinitive anxiety of families and the almost income maintenance experiments conducted under
existential importance of place’ (Maurin, 2004, Nixon, themes taken up in the UK by the Institute

119
B. Jordan

for Economic Affairs, which became Margaret because of race discrimination, inequality in ac-
Thatcher’s intellectual engine room in the late 1970s. cess to exit has had some appalling consequen-
What is here being argued is that the two strands ces, such as the ‘‘ghettoization’’ and partial ruin

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
of social scientific thought which fed Thatcherism’s of our big cities’ (Hirschman, 1981, 252).
and Reaganism’s two-headed radicalism (their neo-
conservatism and neo-liberalism) were represented This insight gave rise to a whole stream of critical
respectively by the culturalists, who emphasized analysis of the impact of exit strategies on the social
cultures of poverty (which were often place-based); structures of poor districts, from Mike Davis’s City
and the public finance/public choice economists, of Quartz (1990) in Los Angeles to William Julius
whose ideas were highly compatible with those of Wilson’s When Work Disappears (1996) in Chicago.
Hayek (1960, 1978), Von Mises (1966) and the Obviously, as Wilson pointed out, the de-
anti-Keynesians (Friedman, 1975), who wanted industrialization processes accelerated by Thatcher-
a social order constructed by individuals in markets, ism–Reaganism reinforced the exit of bourgeois
not by governments. white and black families from the inner cities; not
These two combined to produce the new intellec- only was there a depopulation of 66% in the dis-
tual orthodoxy of the 1980s, which spilled over into tricts he studied between 1950 and 1990; male em-
the next decade. Just as it saw unemployment as ployment declined by 46%, as less-skilled manual
a supply-side issue of poor adaptation to the trans- jobs disappeared (Wilson, 1996, 44).
formation of labour markets, so it saw poverty as The growth of service work accelerated in those
a cultural collapse in a face of economic change, leafy suburbs to which more resourceful residents
leading to individual demoralization. Charles retreated. At the same time, other sociologists and
Murray (1980) and his British imitators, who de- social policy analysts were charting the fate of the
veloped notions of ‘underclass’ and ‘dependency outer city social housing schemes which had been
culture’ were the heirs of Oscar Lewis, while those built during the post-war period, and up to the
who led the privatization of social housing schemes 1970s—or far later in Continental Europe, and es-
and the collective facilities of poor districts, selling pecially in the state socialist countries of Central
off parks and school playing fields, were paying hom- Europe. Ann Power’s (1996) work drew attention
age to James Buchanan and Friedrich Von Hayek. to the exclusive effects of industrial decline and
As early as 1978, the great social and political social polarization all over Europe. Although social
theorist A. O. Hirschman identified the role of mo- insurance benefits could replace earnings fairly ad-
bility in generating the concentrations of poverty, equately in countries like Germany and Finland, the
and the social problems which were exacerbated isolation and loss of work-related social organiza-
by these phenomena. He pointed out that the en- tion in the lives of these residents was deeply dam-
couragement of exit options for more resourceful aging to their quality of life and their citizenship.
members of disadvantaged communities was apply- Theorists and researchers like Wilson, Power and
ing a market mechanism to the social order. It might Jordan (Jordan, 1996) ran the risk of seeming to
seem attractive as an alternative to the democratic confirm the underclass and demoralization rhetoric
mechanisms for collective decision-making— of Charles Murray and the IEA. To analyse the
‘‘‘more efficient’’ than the ‘‘cumbersome’’ politi- transformation of collective life in these districts
cal process for the redress of people’s grievances or (in other words, to present a sociological version
the fulfilment of their demands’ (as he put it). But: of what was depicted in films and TV series like
The Boys from the Blackstuff, Aufwiedersehen Pet,
Unfortunately, because of differences in income Brassed Off, Common as Muck and The Full
and wealth, the ability to vote with one’s feet is Monty) was to flirt with the culturalist account of
unequally distributed in modern society. In the the links between poverty and place—that collec-
United States, where the problem is compounded tive responses to unemployment and poverty,

120
The place of ‘place’ in theories of poverty

however understandably, consolidated their effects, in families and neighbourhoods (Driver and Martell,
and that exit was therefore the only viable option 1997). In so far as it had an economic rationale, it
from a self-reinforcing ghetto process. was one of investment in human capital (Becker,

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
Mobility is a systematic feature of markets, and 1964)—stimulating firms and disadvantaged peo-
the cultures of poor districts were seen as a kind of ple to invest in improving the economic potential
market failure. Policy might address either these of those previously excluded from mainstream cir-
cultural features, or the housing market, or both. cuits of production, through initiatives by a ‘Social
This was the challenge for the next shift in policy. Investment State’ (Reich, 1993; Giddens, 1998).
The policy instruments created to achieve these
goals were ‘partnerships’ between local authorities,
The Third Way firms and local populations (Innes, 1994; Lauria,
The Clinton and Blair Third Way administrations in 1997; Davies, 2001, 2002). The theory behind these
the USA and UK extended the policy repertoires innovations first developed in the USA by Elkin
of governments in relation to these districts, with (1987) and Stone (1989) in terms of ‘regimes’ and
their programmes for urban regeneration, social refined by Rhodes (1997), Davies (2001, 2002) and
inclusion and above all with workfare, the New Stokes (2000) in the UK in terms of ‘governance’—
Covenant, New Deals and tax credits. Refusing to ‘self-organising, inter-organisational networks’
return to European-style social insurance-based re- (Rhodes, 1997, 53). The goal in both countries
distributive measures, they relied instead on retrain- was to build long-term, stable relationships between
ing and resocializing workers for menial service city government and local private interests in
employment, buttressing their low wages with tax pursuit of mutual goals (Jones and Evans, 2006,
subsidies, and penalizing non-cooperative resisters. 1494), in tasks of urban regeneration, involving
But a major difficulty for the new politics of local residents.
welfare under Third Way regimes was that the Critics have argued that the power relations in
means of rule that had characterized the post-war these new institutions of governance, distanced from
institutions (for solidarity, redistribution, sharing local authorities, and attempting to include neigh-
facilities and sustaining balanced communities) bourhood organizations, have been complex and
had all been dissolved, and replaced by opportuni- opaque; case studies reveal wide differences between
ties for individuals and households to exercise patterns and outcomes (Jones and Evans, 2006,
choice through mobility between suppliers and 1506; Geddes, 2006, 92–93). Similar conclusions
jurisdictions. Because these governments were un- have been drawn from Danish and Irish experience
willing to reverse this shift, they focused instead on (Sorenson and Torfing 2004; Forde, 2006). Above
new ways to engage commercial interests and local all, the ‘invited spaces’ (Gaventa, 2004) created by
populations in the physical and social regeneration these initiatives disadvantage local residents in re-
of their districts, in order the improve the function- lation to organized business and government partic-
ing of education, health, social services, policing ipants; in France, the associational sector has failed
and housing agencies, and enhance the cultural to influence public policy in neighbourhoods, despite
resources of residents for solving their problems of a rhetoric of partnership (Nicholls, 2006, 1798).
crime, homelessness, drug and alcohol abuse, truancy In so far as these partnerships for regeneration
and family breakdown (Jordan with Jordan, 2000). have attempted to reverse the exclusion of residents
Unlike the neo-liberal transformation, with its of disadvantaged districts, to minimize the effects
theoretical basis in public choice and micro- of social polarization, and to deploy new means of
economics, this approach was grounded in a politi- rule in fragmented and disorganized communities,
cal theory of citizenship (Kymlicka and Norman, the emphasis on governance in Third Way theory
1994) and community (Etzioni, 1993). The goal represents a compromise between neo-liberal man-
was to stimulate the sense of mutual responsibility agerialism and attempts at achieving consensual,

121
B. Jordan

communitarian local activity—for example, in the focus on the improvement of the quality of life of
UK New Deal for Communities (Lawless, 2006). long-term residents of poor communities. In the
Taken in conjunction with the expansion of tax event, the exit of more resourceful individuals and

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
credits, subsidising the wages of low-earning work- households seems to have continued, despite
ing households and with the range of other meas- attempts at both strategies.
ures to enforce work and family responsibilities,
these initiatives have at least slowed down the cre-
ation of neighbourhoods with concentrations of Social capital and well-being
poverty in most parts of the USA (Cooke and To bring this story up to date, we seem now to be
Marchant, 2006), with the important exceptions of entering a new phase in the articulation between the
the Sunbelt cities, Los Angeles, California’s Cen- three elements in the theory of poverty and place.
tral Valley and the old industrial cities of the North- This stems from dissatisfaction with the limited
east (Jargowsky, 2003; Jargowsky and Yang, success of communitarian analyses and regenera-
2005). A similar mixed picture in the UK, against tion policies in relation to the collective life of de-
a background of Third Way interventions which prived districts; but it also arises from alarm at the
broadly mirrors that of the USA, must be set against levels of disorder, conflict and threat to security
the fact that both countries have enjoyed relatively attributed to members of some such neighbour-
rapid and stable growth of GDP during this period. hoods. Here again, the leading theoretical develop-
In continental Europe, the background condi- ments come from the Anglophone tradition, where
tions were very different—higher manual wages; these fears are strongest.
higher minimum wages; higher replacement rates As a background to the new thinking, it is impor-
of social insurance benefits, with better coverage; tant to recognize the extent to which methodological
but slower growth of GDP, higher social insurance individualism and the economic approach to human
contributions and higher unemployment, in most of interactions had come to dominate the social scien-
the old EU members states. ces, almost totally replacing the collectivist elements
An evaluation of the EU’s URBAN 1 Commu- in the interwar and post-war theorizing about pov-
nity Initiative (1994–1999) for area-based urban erty, reviewed in the first section of this article. For
regeneration found that it had introduced a trans- example, when the economist Gary Becker first
formed neighbourhood intervention in several framed his theories on poverty, low wages and the
states, identifying similar districts with deprivation, family in terms of individual underinvestment in
stigma, market and state failure in countries without human capital (Becker, 1964, 1976), his ideas were
previous initiatives of this kind, and involving regarded as outrageous in the other social sciences.
community participation and partnership. The pro- Now the ‘supply side’ approach to unemployment,
gramme influenced policy in 11 states, but the ac- lack of skills and low earning power underpins both
tual effects of interventions were again mixed. In theory and policy in these fields. But the interven-
10% of cases, the initiative actually increased spa- tions inspired by this approach have made little
tial inequalities, by displacing problems to other impact on the behaviour and lives of individuals
areas (Carpenter, 2006, 2158), e.g. by raising prop- living in intense concentrations of poverty.
erty prices and taxes. At the end of the period, all Although public choice theory dealt with the
the target districts were still absolutely and rela- economics of groups and collective action (Olson,
tively disadvantaged (ibid., 2159). 1965, 1983), the ideological thrust which informed
Part of the problem is that it is unclear whether it was anti-socialist; its advocates wanted to sub-
housing markets should enable more overall mobil- stitute commercial and quasi-commercial organiza-
ity, both in and out of poor districts, (and hence that tions for state agencies across a range of issues,
social housing might be a barrier to more mixed or including infrastructures and the built environment
balanced communities); or whether policy should (Foldvary, 1994; Davies, 1992). The model of

122
The place of ‘place’ in theories of poverty

a society—or more accurately a system of overlap- But subsequent critical analyses have pointed out
ping jurisdictions and economic ‘clubs’ (Casella that some of the defining features of social capital
and Frey, 1992)—which it promoted was one of (social norms of reciprocity and civil associations)

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
self-sorted groupings of highly mobile individuals, are poorly correlated with quality of governance
constantly shifting between options, and seeking to and subjective well-being (SWB); the remaining
avoid sharing with those who had costly needs component, generalized trust, is alone relevant for
(Cullis and Jones, 1994, 297–301). It gave far less these (Bjørnskov, 2006). Others have shown that
attention to such phenomena as loyalty (to family several definitions of social capital—‘bridging con-
members, neighbours, communities or country), or nections yielding functional utility’ (Coleman,
the bonds which sustained long-term relationships 1990, 302), ‘social networks and the norms of rec-
and affiliations. Communitarian accounts of ‘respon- iprocity and trustworthiness’ (Putnam, 2000, 19)
sible communities’ had proved too prescriptive and and ‘informal rules or norms shared among them’
vague to provide a basis for effective policies. (Fukuyama, 1997, 378)—ensure that social capital
The rapid rise of social capital theory to the status is always desirable since its presence is equated
of a ‘master idea’ in the social sciences (Bjørnskov, with beneficial consequences (Durlauf and
2006; Bowles and Gintis, 2002) can be traced to its Fafchamps, 2004, 3–5).
apparent capacity to link features of the collective The attraction of social capital theory is that it
life of neighbourhoods, regions or states to the might explain how some communities come to
functioning of both their economies and their polit- function in ways which make them prosperous,
ical institutions. well-organized and well-governed, whereas others
In this way, it seemed to connect spatial with become poor and fragmented, falling prey to many
social dimensions of social interactions and provide social problems. This implies that informal interac-
an analysis in terms of cultural and organizational tions, informal information sources and the func-
features of social units. The concept of social cap- tioning of local norms and institutions are all
ital denoted an all-purpose collective good, which alternatives, and perhaps even superior alternatives,
was both a bonding agent and a lubricant in inter- to geographical mobility, except for those trapped
actions of all kinds (Putnam, 2000, 20), but which in ‘disorganized’ neighbourhoods.
could also function as a private good for individual However, in relation to mobility, Putnam in
benefit (ibid., 22). The claims later made for social Bowling Alone (2000, 205) acknowledges that US
capital research were enormous—that there were: society has polarized into homogeneous districts,
on the basis of age, taste, income, class, race and
robust correlations in various countries between so on. The same phenomena have been well docu-
vibrant social networks and important social out- mented recently by geographers such as Danny
comes, such as lower crime rates, improved child Dorling in the UK (Dorling and Thomas, 2003).
welfare, better public health, more effective gov- But he also acknowledges that this homogenization
ernment administration, reduced political corrup- of residential districts is associated with lower lev-
tion, educational performance, etc. (Helliwell els of participation in civil society and civic life
and Putnam, 2005, 438) (Putnam, 2000, 209–210). He (and other social cap-
ital theorists) do not deal with mobility in any sys-
This seems to imply that social capital is a single tematic way as a factor in the dynamics of social
medium which facilitates communications of all capital building.
kinds, in interactions involving markets, political Faced with the phenomenon of poor districts with
systems and voluntary organizations, although concentration of social problems of all kinds, and
Putnam’s earlier work suggested—following de with the La Vida phenomenon of strong informal
Tocqueville (1836)—that the last of these were networks in some of these, and a kind of blood-
crucial to its generation (Putnam, 1993). and-guts code of loyalty, solidarity and resistance

123
B. Jordan

to authority in all of them, Putnam (2000, 22–23) disaffection (van Staveren, 2003). This is illustrated
offers a very vague distinction between ‘bonding’ by the collective responses of Muslim youth in the
social capital, built on links with others with social UK and Europe. In France, the street rioters of

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
characteristics like one’s own (a bit like ‘thick com- October–November, 2005, displayed Putnam’s
munity’), and ‘bridging’ social capital, in the form of bonding social capital. They united around the slo-
links with members of other groups (‘thin’ or liberal gan ‘France hates us, and we hate France’, and were
community). But he does not use this distinction at veritably ‘les exclus’, poor, unemployed, living in
all consistently in Bowling Alone, or his other work. the outer suburbs, in special social housing
If mobility polarizes and homogenizes residential schemes, sharing a common culture of resistance,
districts, it must contribute to the emergence of crime and loyalty.
bonds between people with very similar social pro- By contrast, the social profiles of the suicide
files, if it contributes to social capital at all. All the bombers on the London Transport system of 7 July
evidence is that a great many poor people in the UK 2005 seemed to demonstrate the hallmarks of
have dropped out of formal civil society organiza- integration on many dimensions. They were well-
tions since the early 1980s. educated, had good jobs or job prospects, lived in
In Bynner and Parsons’ (2003, tables 10.1–10.9) mainstream housing and were members of sports
in a comparison of survey evidence of three gener- clubs (the index of social capital holders). But this
ations since World War II in the UK, of those kind of ‘bridging’ social capital, through college,
Class V men born in 1946, 52% were members work and sport, was consistent with membership of
of organizations when surveyed aged around 30, a jihadi militant group.
and 45% were members of trade unions. Of Class In tight-knit local communities, ‘social capital’
V men born in 1970, and interviewed at around means little more than a way of doing things in-
age 30, 12% were of members of organizations, formally which are done through markets or formal
and 8% of trade unions. But 46% of them had been organizations elsewhere. This may be economically
arrested. more efficient for participants, but have costs for
All this suggests that such networks as do exist in others, and sometimes these arise from deliberate
poor districts are informal, and tend to reinforce predation, rather than simply from exclusion. In
a counterculture, including practices such as work- larger, more cosmopolitan and complex social
ing while claiming, petty crime, hustling, prostitu- units, where individuals have multiple affiliations,
tion, drug dealing and so on. Alternatively, as ‘social capital’ consists of many different relation-
Madeleine Leonard’s researchers on informal eco- ships, each giving rise to different cultural resources
nomic activity in Catholic West Belfast showed, it and restraints. It is impossible to specify in advance
can sustain a highly organized and brutally which ideological, national, ethnic or faith links
enforced loyalty to an armed resistance struggle will move members to take collective action at
against the mainstream (Leonard, 1993). Either any particular time.
way, as again Leonard showed, in her recent article So it seems that social capital theory gets us no
in Sociology (2004), it implies that ‘bonding’ social further than a culture of poverty theory. We there-
capital is very difficult stuff to handle. If you try to fore turn to the most recent new perspective on
replace it, as the Peace Process in Belfast has done, poverty and place, well-being theory. This of
by links into the mainstream economy and main- course stems from psychological research, but has
stream social service agencies, you may leave some been taken up by economists, notably Richard
individuals more poor, isolated and vulnerable than Layard (2005) and Avner Offer (2006), as a critique
before—more excluded, paradoxically, than when of their own discipline’s narrow assumptions.
they were living in a ghetto of armed resistance. The relationship between well-being theory and
Thus social capital theory has proved an unreli- social capital theory is ambiguous. On the one
able guide to policy in relation to disadvantage and hand, neither Layard (2005) nor Offer (2006) make

124
The place of ‘place’ in theories of poverty

any extensive or systematic use of the term social death (twice). Health (three times more), satisfying
capital in their analyses; on the other, Helliwell has work (two and a half) and participation in a social
written with Putnam to claim that ‘social capital is activity (about twice), along with trust in fellow

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
strongly linked to SWB through many independent citizens, are all very important (Helliwell, 2003).
channels and several different forms’ (Helliwell and Above all, average levels of SWB have ceased to
Putnam, 2005, 455). The main difference in the two rise in the affluent countries for the past 30 or
approaches is that well-being theory seeks to iden- 40 years (Frey and Stutzer, 2002, 8–9). Higher
tify the utility produced (Sugden, 2005; Jordan, incomes do not bring a better quality of life.
2006b) and exchanged (Offer, 2006, ch. 5) in per- All this focuses attention on mainstream culture,
sonal, group and community interactions, rather than rather than the culture of poverty. Instead of seeing
claiming the presence of a possibly tautologously- poor districts as displaying deficits of the qualities
defined beneficial collective good. which sustain the mainstream order, it poses the
But another important common ground between questions ‘What’s wrong with our collective life,
the two approaches is that they focus on aspects of our relationships, our institutions?’ It sees poor dis-
interactions in affluent societies which have been tricts as, at worst, distorting mirrors held up to the
neglected by methodological individualism and mainstream way of life. Richard Layard’s recent
micro-economic analysis. Bowles and Gintis high profile as an advocate of extended mental
(2002, F433) point out that these features, such health provision and ‘personal learning’ in schools
as ‘information-intensive team production . . ., has disguised the radicalism of his critique, which
difficult-to-measure services . . . [and] qualities implicitly portrays current political culture in the
rather than quantities’, which ‘cannot be regulated USA and the UK as the last gasp of the Thatcherite
by complete contracts or by external fiat’, hence revolution. He advocates:
resist both market and governmental solutions,
and rely on multi-lateral monitoring and risk- (i) higher taxation, reduction of competition and
sharing through face-to-face interactions. rivalry, less performance-related pay, espe-
This implies an approach to political economy cially in the public sectors;
which deals in informal, personal and communal (ii) more redistribution in favour of poor people,
improvements in a ‘second-best world’ of multiple in this country and abroad;
Pareto equilibria, rather than the ‘first-best’ single (iii) more resources for mental health services;
equilibrium criterion which governed both the (iv) improving family life, through family-
Pigou–Keynes–Beveridge welfare state model, friendly employment policies and better
and the Buchanan–Tiebout–Tullock public choice support services;
model (Durlauf and Fafchamps, 2004). (v) more resources for promoting active commu-
Well-being theory (Kahneman et al., 1999) starts nity participation;
from people’s self-assessed overall satisfaction with (vi) redistribution of work, in favour of the
their lives (which turns out to be surprisingly ro- unemployed;
bust, and comparable between cultures), and goes (vii) prohibition of commercial advertising for
on to consider the components which make up this children’s goods;
overall measure—those elements which add most (viii) better moral education (Layard, 2005, 232–
to levels of SWB, or subtract most if they are absent 234).
(Argyle, 1999; Myers, 1999; Diener and Suh,
1999). As part of his first proposal, he urges less mobility,
It appears to be the case that a loss of one-third of on the grounds that it increases crime and weakens
income is markedly less damaging than the loss of families and communities. In his critique of indi-
a partner through separation (four times more sig- vidualism as the basis for our social and political
nificant), divorce (more than twice as damaging) or culture, he deplores the consequences of mobility

125
B. Jordan

for family support systems and active communities. The main tension now lies between the continued
He chides economists for advocating mobility for commitment to mobility and choice as the bases for
the sake of higher productivity, but neglecting the a collective life of self-selected units, and the alter-

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
costs to well-being through loss of support and trust native claims of balanced communities, cohesion
(ibid., 233). and engagement. Public policies have, since the
Layard’s focus is on geographical mobility, 1980s, encouraged exit strategies over voice and
which is the most obvious influence on poverty loyalty (Hirschman, 1970); these now dominate
and place. But if he were to be consistent in his the search for ‘positional advantage’ (Hirsch,
critique of the 1980’s legacy of cultural resources 1977), even in continental Europe. The extent to
and social institutions, he should consider the which UK parents see mobility as crucial to their
whole edifice of exit-orientated systems—the reli- achievement of such advantage could be seen in the
ance on switching and shifting between suppliers in middle-class reaction to the decision by Brighton
education, health care, social care and the former Council to award school places by lottery (Guardian,
public utilities, as much as geographical mobility. 2007). The costs for children of living in highly
The rhetoric of choice, made by autonomous, competitive, unequal societies was evident from
independent, self-responsible and self-realizing the UK’s and USA’s bottom two places in a league
citizens, is at the heart of the Third Way project table of child well-being in 21 affluent countries
for reforming the public services and the public (Innocenti, 2007).
infrastructure. This tension has most clearly been highlighted in
The ‘well-being turn’ invites a kind of theorizing the UK in the Prime Minister’s speeches on order
about poverty and place which deals in both the and security. For example, in relation to ‘respect’ in
mobility of populations and its exclusionary effects, everyday social interactions, after setting the issue
and the kinds of cultural resources and social insti- in a context of political philosophy from Hobbes to
tutions which are generated to deal with these R. H. Tawney, Blair was at pains to emphasize that
effects. Layard crudely concludes that immigration the ‘vast majority’ of citizens were civil and con-
damages community cohesion. This should be the siderate; problems of disorder, drunkenness and de-
topic for detailed, qualitative research. How do in- linquency were confined to a small minority of
digenous and settled immigrants respond to new individuals to be dealt with by criminal justice
waves of immigration, and how do the new immi- interventions (Blair, 2006).
grants adapt? How do they interact? This conclusion justifies the individualism,
choice and mobility between options which are
central to public sector reform, but cuts across
attempts to improve cohesion and balance in
Conclusions ‘mixed’ communities. It also allows the increased
The recent analyses of social capital and well-being stigmatization and exclusion of a group of poor
theorists illustrate that welfarist, culturalist and mo- people, who cannot benefit from these processes
bility elements are all still present in theories of the (Harris, 2007).
place of ‘place’ in poverty. Layard’s (2005) empha- The place of ‘place’ in the theory of poverty
sis on inequality of income and the social costs of shows that the analysis of poverty is inadequate
mobility revive some of the themes of the post-war, unless it is part of the overall analysis of social
welfare state understanding of how poor districts relations. The advantage of the well-being turn is
reinforce social disadvantage. Social capital theory its focus on mainstream social relations. It also
endorses the importance of ‘community gover- challenges the hegemony of orthodox microeco-
nance’ (Bowles and Gintis, 2002) in achieving cul- nomic analysis, and offers an opportunity for the
tural and political participation which improves the rest of the social sciences to exert a stronger influ-
quality of life in such communities. ence on policy.

126
The place of ‘place’ in theories of poverty

References Davies H. Fighting Leviathan: Building Social Markets


that Work. London: Social Market Foundation, 1992.
Argyle M. Causes and Correlates of Happiness. In: Davies J. Partnerships and Regimes: The Politics of Ur-
Kahneman D et al. (eds). Well-being: The Foundations ban Regeneration in the UK. Aldershot: Ashgate, 2001.

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
of Hedonic Psychology. New York: Russell Sage Foun- Davies J. The governance of urban regeneration: a critique
dation, 1999, 353–372. of the governing without government thesis. Public
Arku G, Harris R. Housing as a tool of economic devel- Administration 2002; 80: 301–322.
opment since 1929. International Journal of Urban Davis M. City of Quartz: Excavating the Future of Los
and Regional Research 2005; 29: 895–915. Angeles. London: Vintage, 1990.
Becker GS. Human Capital. New York: Columbia Uni- Dean M. Towards a Theory of Liberal Governance.
versity Press, 1964. London: Routledge, 1991.
Becker GS. The Economic Approach to Human Behav- Diener E, Suh EM. National differences in subjective
iour. Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1976. well-being. In: Kahneman D et al. (eds). Well-being:
Begag A. L’Integration. Paris: Le Chevalier Bleu, 2004. The Foundations of Hedonic Psychology. New York:
Beveridge W. Social Insurance and Allied Services. Russell Sage Foundation, 1999, 434–52.
Cmd 6404. London: HMSO, 1942. Donnison D, Chapman V. Social Policy and Admin-
Bjørnskov C. The multiple facets of social capital. Euro- istration: Studies in the Development of Social Ser-
pean Journal of Political Economy 2006; 22: 22–40. vices at the local Level. London: Allen and Unwin,
Blair T. Speech on Respect, January 10th, 2006. 1965.
Bowles S, Gintis H. Social capital and community gov- Dorling D, Thomas B. People and Places: A 2001 Census
ernance. Economic Journal 2002; 112: F419–F436. Atlas of the UK, Bristol: Policy Press, 2003.
Brenner N, Theodore N. Spaces of Neo-Liberalism: Ur- Driver S, Martell L. New Labour’s communiatarianisms.
ban Restructuring in North America and Western Critical Social Policy 1997; 17: 27–46.
Europe. Oxford: Blackwell, 2002. Durlauf SN, Fafchamps M. Social Capital, Working
Bruni L, Porta P-L. Economics and Happiness: Framing Paper 10485. 2004. Available at www.nber.org/papers/
the Analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005. w10485
Buchanan JM, Tullock G. The Calculus of Consent: Log- Elkin S. City and Regime in the American Republic.
ical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1987.
Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 1962. Etzioni A. The Spirit of Community. New York: Touch-
Buchanan JM. Public Finance in a Democratic Process. stone, 1993.
Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press, Finlayson A. Making Sense of New Labour. London:
1967. Lawrence and Wishart, 2003.
Buchanan JM. The Demand and Supply of Public Goods. Foldvary F. Public Goods and Private Communities: The
New York: Rand McNally, 1968. Market Provision of Social Services. Aldershot:
Bynner J, Parsons S. Participation and crime. In: Ferri E, Edward Elgar, 1994.
Bynner J, Wadsworth N (eds). Changing Britain, Forde C. Invited Spaces for Participation: A Critical
Changing Lives: Three Generations at the Turn of Study of Local Social Partnership in Ireland, 2006.
the Century. London: Institute of Education, 2003. PhD Thesis, Dept of Applied Social Studies
Carpenter J. Addressing Europe’s urban challenges: The Frey B, Stutzer A. Happiness and Economics: How the
EU URBAN community initiative. Urban Studies Economy and Institutions Affect Well-being. Princeton:
2006; 43: 2145–2163. Princeton University Press, 2002.
Casella A, Frey B. Federalism and clubs: towards a theory Friedman M. Unemployment versus Inflation? An
of overlapping political jurisdictions. European Eco- Evaluation of the Phillips Curve, London: Institute of
nomic Review 1992; 36: 639–646. Economic Affairs, 1975.
Coleman JS. The Foundations of Social Theory, Cam- Fukuyama F. Social Capital, Turner Lecture on Human
bridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990. Values. 1997.
Cooke T, Marchant S. The changing intrametro- Gaventa J. Towards participatory governance: assessing
politan location of high-poverty neighbourhoods the transformation possibilities. In: Hickey S, Mohan G
in the US, 1990–2000. Urban Studies 2006; 43: (eds). Participation: From Tyranny to Transformation.
1971–1990. London: Zed Books, 2004.
Corry D, Stoker G. New Localism: Refashioning the Geddes M. Partnership and the limits of local governance
Centre-Local Relationship. London: New Local in England. International Journal of Urban and Re-
Government Network, 2002. gional Research 2006; 30: 76–97.
Cullis J, Jones P. Public Finance and Public Choice: Giddens A. The Third Way: The Renewal of Social
Analytical Perspectives. London: McGraw Hill, 1994. Democracy. Cambridge: Polity, 1998.

127
B. Jordan

Gilbert J. The second wave: the specificity of New Jones P, Evans J. Urban regeneration, governance and the
Labour. Soundings 2004; 26: 25–44 (deletion). state: exploring notions of distance and proximity. Ur-
Guardian. War over school boundaries divides Brighton: ban Studies 2006; 43: 1491–1510.
Council brings in lottery for sought-after places: Jordan B. Poor Parents: Social Policy and the ‘Cycle of

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
parents in old catchment area threaten court action’. Deprivation’. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul,
Guardian. March 1st, 2007, 10. 1974.
Hall PA. Great Britain: the role of government and the Jordan B. A Theory of Poverty and Social Exclusion.
distribution of social capital. In: Putnam RD (ed.). Cambridge: Polity, 1996.
Democracies in Flux. Oxford: Oxford University Press, Jordan B. Sex, Money and Power: The Transformation of
2002, 28–51. Collective Life. Cambridge: Polity, 2004.
Harrington M. The Other America. New York: Jordan B. Social Policy for the Twenty First Century:
Macmillan, 1962. New Perspectives, Big Issues. Cambridge: Polity, 2006a.
Harris J. So now we’ve finally got our own ‘White Jordan B. Rewarding Company, Enriching Life and the
Trash’. Guardian March 6th, 2007. Economics of Relationships and Well-being 2006b.
Haveman RH. Poverty, Policy and Poverty Research: Available at www.billjordan.co.uk.
The Great Society and the Social Sciences. Wisconsin: Jordan B, Jordan C. Social Work and the Third
University of Wisconsin Press, 1987. Way: Tough Love as Social Policy. London: Sage,
Hayek FA. Von. The Constitution of Liberty, London: 2000.
Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1960. Kahneman D et al. Well-being: The Foundations of He-
Hayek FA. Von. New Studies in Philosophy, Politics and donic Psychology. New York: Russell Sage Founda-
Economics, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1978. tion, 1999.
Helliwell J. How’s Life? combining individual and na- Keynes JM. The General Theory of Employment, Interest
tional variables in explaining subjective well-being. and Money, London, Macmillan, 1936.
Economic Modelling 2003; 20: 331–360. Kymlicka W, Norman R. Return of the citizen: a survey
Helliwell J, Putnam RD. Social capital and well- of recent work of citizenship theory. Ethics 1994; 103:
being. In: Huppert FA et al. (eds). The Science of 352–381.
Well-being. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Lauria M. (ed.). Reconstructing Urban Regime Theory:
2005, 435–56. Regulating Urban Policies in a Global Economy.
Hicks U. Public Finance. London: Nisbet/Cambridge Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage, 1997.
University Press, 1947. Lawless P. Area-based urban interventions: rationale
Hirsch F. Social Limits to Growth. London: Routledge and outcomes. Urban Studies 2006; 43: 1991–2012.
and Kegan Paul, 1977. Layard R. Happiness: Lessons from a New Science.
Hirschman AO. Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to London: Allen Lane, 2005.
Decline in Firms, Organisations and States. Cam- Leonard M. Informal Economic Activity in Belfast.
bridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1970. Aldershot: Avebury, 1993.
Hirschman AO. Exit, Voice and the State. In Hirschman Leonard M. Bridging and Bonding Social Capital:
AO (ed.). Essays in Trespassing: Economics to Politics A Report from Belfast. Sociology 2004; 38:
and Beyond. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 927–944.
1981, 246–65. Lewis O. The Children of Sanchez: The Autobiography of
Innes J. Planning Through Consensus-Building: A New a Mexican Family. London: Penguin, 1964.
View of the Consensus Planning Ideal. Berkeley, CA: Lewis O. La Vida. New York: Panther, 1969.
University of California Press, 1994. Marshall TH. Social Policy. London: Hutchinson,
Innocenti Report Card 7. Child Poverty In Perspective: 1965.
An Overview of Child Well-being in Rich Countries. Maurin E. Le Ghetto Francais: enquête sur le separa-
Florence: UNICEF. 2007. tisme social. Paris: Editions du Sueil, 2004.
Jargowsky PA. Stunning Progress, Hidden Problems: Mises L. Von. Human Action, Chicago: Contemporary
The Dramatic Decline of Concentrated Poverty in the Books. 1966
1990s. Washington DC: Brookings Institute, 2003. Mueller DC. Public Choice. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
Jargowsky PA, Yang R. The ‘Underclass’ Revisited: A versity Press, 1979.
Social Problem on the Decline. Washington, DC: Murray C. Losing Ground: American Social Policy Since
Brooking’s Institute, 2005. 1950. New York: Free Press, 1980.
Jessop B. Liberalism, neo-liberalism and urban gover- Musgrave RA. The Theory of Public Finance. New York:
nance: a state-theoretical perspective. In: Brenner N, McGraw Hill, 1959.
Theodore N (eds). Spaces of Neo-Liberalism. Oxford: Myers DL. Close relationships and quality of life. In:
Blackwell, 2002. Kahneman D et al. (eds). Well-being: The Foundations

128
The place of ‘place’ in theories of poverty

of Hedonic Psychology. New York: Russell Sage Foun- Sennett R. Respect in a world of inequality, New York,
dation, 1999. Norton 2003.
Nicholls WJ. Associationalism from above: explaining Sorenson E, Torfing J. (eds). Making Governance Net-
failure through France’s Politique de la Ville. Urban works Democratic. Roskilde: Centre for Democratic

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org at Shah Jalal University of Science and Technology on July 28, 2010
Studies 2006; 43: 1779–1802. Network Governance, 2004.
Offer A. The Challenge of Affluence: Self-Control and Stokes G. (ed.). The New Politics of British Local
Well-being in the United States and Britain Since Governance. Basingstoke: Macmillan, 2000.
1950. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006. Stone C. Regime Politics: Governing Atlanta, 1946–1988.
Olson M. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods Lawrence, KS: University Press of Kansas,
and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard 1989.
University Press, 1965. Sugden R. Correspondence of sentiments. In: Bruni L,
Olson M. The Rise and Decline of Notions: Economic Porta PL (eds). Economics and Happiness:
Growth Stagflation and Social Rigidities. New Haven, Framing the Analysis. Oxford: Oxford University
CT: Yale University Press, 1983. Press, 2005.
Park RE, Burgess EW, McKenzie RD. The City, Chicago. Tiebout C. A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal
Chicago University Press 1935; 1967: 374–91. of Political Economy 1956; 64: 416–424.
Paugam S. Poverty and social exclusion: a sociological Tocqueville A. de. Democracy in America. New York:
view. In: Rhodes M, Meny Y (eds). The Future of Basic Books, 1836.
European Welfare: A New Social Contract? Basing- Townsend P. Poverty in the United Kingdom. London:
stoke: Macmillan, 1998, 41–62. Penguin, 1979.
Pigou AC. The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmil- Townsend P, Abel-Smith B. The Poor and the Poorest.
lan, 1920. London: Bell, 1965.
Putnam RD. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions Tullock G. Towards a Mathematics of Politics.
in Modern Italy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Ann Arbor, MS: University of Michigan Press,
Press, 1993. 1967.
Putnam RD. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival Van Staveren I. Beyond social capital in poverty research.
of American Community. New York: Simon and Journal of Economic Issues 2003; 37: 415–423.
Schuster, 2000. Walker R, Lawson R, Townsend P. (eds). Responses to
Rawls J. A Theory of Justice. Oxford: Oxford University Poverty: Lessons from Europe. London: Heinemann,
Press, 1972. 1984.
Reich R. The Work of Nations: Preparing Ourselves for Wilson D. I Know it Was the Place’s Fault. London:
Twenty-First Century Capitalism. New York: Knopf, Oliphants, 1970.
1993. Wilson WJ. When Work Disappears: The World of the
Rhodes R. Understanding Governance: Policy Networks, New Urban Poor. London: Vintage, 1996.
Governance, Reflexibility and Accountability. Buck-
ingham: Open University Press, 1997. Received on March 12, 2007; accepted on August 21, 2007

129

You might also like