You are on page 1of 4

COMMENTARIES

Biomedical Patents and the Public’s Health


Is There a Role for Eminent Domain?
Aaron S. Kesselheim, MD, JD constructs designed to reward innovation. But under cer-
tain circumstances, the way manufacturers manage their pat-
Jerry Avorn, MD ents can also negatively impact public health and medical
care costs.

A
S A GOVERNMENT-SANCTIONED MONOPOLY, A DRUG
patent allows its owner to prevent others from mak- Health Care Patents and the Public Good
ing, using, or selling a given medication for a set
amount of time. Patents can help encourage and The United States has occasionally been faced with poten-
reward scientific innovation in the pharmaceutical indus- tial public health problems relating to restrictive manage-
try. But some drug companies have been criticized for re- ment of medication patents. During World War II, a fed-
stricting access to products in the face of actual or poten- eral appeals court strongly criticized the holder of patents
tial public health emergencies1 or distorting the patent system on a process to enrich foods with vitamin D for refusing to
in pursuit of higher revenues.2 allow that process to be used widely to fortify low-income
One example has been pharmaceutical manufacturers’ ag- Americans’ limited wartime diets.10 In 2002, as the nation
gressive management of patent rights for AIDS drugs, mak- struggled with the anthrax bioterrorism scare, Bayer ini-
ing them unaffordable in developing countries.3 Patents on tially declined to increase production of its ciprofloxacin
pharmaceutical products can also harm the public health (Cipro), the only Food and Drug Administration–
by limiting availability of drugs to treat, for example, tu- approved antibiotic to treat this infection, to required lev-
berculosis4 and cancer,5 although controversy exists over els.11 In both cases, the patent holders ultimately made
what factors provide the greatest barriers to access in some their products more widely available under governmental
settings.6 Recently, Roche came under pressure because its pressure.
oseltamivir phosphate (Tamiflu) may be useful in manag- Patents can also be used to inflate drug prices for con-
ing a potentially epidemic avian influenza virus. Roche ini- sumers. Abbott developed the human immunodeficiency vi-
tially endeavored to keep tight control of its ownership of rus protease inhibitor ritonavir (Norvir) in the 1990s with
the Tamiflu patent rather than allowing licenses to other considerable support from the National Institutes of Health
manufacturers.7 In October, the company cut back on its (NIH). Ritonavir was found to be more effective as an in-
shipments to the United States, arguing that it wanted to hibitor of the cytochrome P450 system; soon, it was being
prevent hoarding.8 prescribed primarily in combination with other protease in-
Controversy has also arisen concerning Pfizer’s torce- hibitors to increase their potency. In 2003, Abbott in-
trapib, which may prevent cardiovascular disease by in- creased US retail prices for ritonavir by 400%12 to prevent
creasing high-density lipoprotein cholesterol levels. The com- this use and to support sales of its own protease inhibitor
pany’s premarketing clinical trials will test torcetrapib only combination. The Bayh-Dole Act, which permitted private
in conjunction with its low-density lipoprotein–lowering corporations to own patents of discoveries made with fed-
product atorvastatin (Lipitor), paving the way for Pfizer to eral grants, allows the government to assume control of such
market torcetrapib as a fixed combination tablet with ator- patents if the product is not made available under “reason-
vastatin. In that situation, physicians could not prescribe able terms.”13 But NIH Director Elias Zerhouni declined to
torcetrapib individually or with lower-cost generic stat- use this power, arguing that federal law did not give the NIH
ins.9 This strategy would effectively extend the market ex- the right to do so in the case of ritonavir.12 In fact, the gov-
clusivity of atorvastatin; otherwise, its patent would expire ernment has never exercised its rights in this way.14
in about 5 years.
Author Affiliations: Division of Pharmacoepidemiology and Pharmacoeconom-
The issues surrounding AIDS drugs, oseltamivir, and torce- ics, Department of Medicine, Brigham and Women’s Hospital, Harvard Medical
trapib illustrate the thorny balance between protecting the School, Boston, Mass.
Corresponding Author: Aaron S. Kesselheim, MD, JD, Division of Pharmacoepi-
intellectual property rights of companies and the some- demiology and Pharmacoeconomics, 1620 Tremont St, Suite 3030, Boston, MA
times competing needs of patients. Patents are useful legal 02120 (akesselheim@partners.org).

434 JAMA, January 25, 2006—Vol 295, No. 4 (Reprinted) ©2006 American Medical Association. All rights reserved.
COMMENTARIES

Companies can also inflate drug prices by manipulating efit the companies developing the site. The Supreme Court
patents to prevent generic drugs from entering the market ruled 5-4 that the city had a right to take possession of the
even after expiration of their original patents.2 By patent- homes because of the “traditionally broad understanding of
ing peripheral aspects of drugs such as their coating or nor- public purpose” in eminent domain law.21
mal metabolites, a process known as “evergreening,” com- The federal government’s eminent domain power has long
panies can extend market exclusivity.15 The manufacturers included patents among the categories of private property
of loratidine (Claritin)16 and metformin (Glucophage)17 pe- that can be the subject of government takings, without seek-
titioned Congress for extended market exclusivity, and in ing a license or other permission; the right was codified in
the case of ranitidine (Zantac), a legal technicality gave the 1948.23 However, this authority has rarely been used in in-
manufacturer nearly 2 more years of patent protection.18 The tellectual property matters; only 8 of 2000 new eminent do-
Federal Trade Commission has also cited occasions where main cases filed in 2003-2004 concerned aggrieved owners
companies registered duplicative or otherwise inappropri- of patents or copyrights.24 The government considered us-
ate patents to prevent lower-cost generic alternatives from ing its eminent domain rights during the 2001 anthrax scare
being marketed.19 and briefly contemplated issuing compulsory licenses al-
Rising prescription drug costs have become a burden for lowing generic manufacturers to produce the needed amount
payers, individuals, and public insurance programs such as of ciprofloxacin.25 Ultimately, an agreement was reached to
Medicaid. Artificially elevated drug prices reduce adher- purchase the necessary amount from Bayer, the patent holder.
ence to medication regimens, especially for low-income pa- In the wake of the anthrax incidents, debate resumed over
tients,20 and mounting drug costs have forced states to cut when the government should take over drug patent rights
back covered services, increase co-pay requirements from and how much compensation would be due. Some argued
indigent patients, or limit eligibility criteria. that overriding patents in such instances would be im-
moral26; others argued that the US government should avoid
Eminent Domain and Private Property doing so to maintain consistency with its opposition to drug
In the face of growing concern over excesses in pharma- patent infringements in third world countries.27 Still oth-
ceutical patent protection, another legal instrument exists ers contended that the government should authorize pro-
that can protect the public health: eminent domain. The con- duction of needed medicines to protect patients and pre-
troversial Supreme Court decision of June 2005 in the case vent profiteering by pharmaceutical manufacturers.28 A bill
of Kelo v New London confirmed the government’s broad au- was introduced in Congress in 2001 to override drug pat-
thority to assume control of private property in the name ents during public health emergencies,29 but with resolu-
of a higher good. The court ruled that a municipality could tion of the potential ciprofloxacin shortage and the passing
take over individuals’ homes to facilitate construction of of- of the perceived anthrax threat, no legislation was enacted
fice space and more upscale residences because the pro- and public debate largely dissipated. With ongoing con-
posed development would be a “public good.”21 Viewed in cerns about the effect of patent abuses on drug availability
this light, eminent domain may be a tool to help address and prices, along with new concerns about access to prod-
situations in which manipulation of biomedical patents ucts to prevent or manage an avian influenza pandemic, the
threatens the public good even more directly. question remains as to when the government should in-
Eminent domain was originally designed to facilitate pub- voke its eminent domain rights over drug patents to pro-
lic works projects, such as building roads or schools. The tect patients and the health care system.
common law tradition, codified in the Fifth Amendment,
lets “private property be taken for public use” by the gov- Principled Government Use of Eminent Domain
ernment, as long as “just compensation” is provided. Early in the Health Care Market
interpretations held that any uses must be purely public. But Most instances in which the government has threatened to
by the mid-1900s, the Supreme Court began to apply a more invoke eminent domain have occurred in times of war, other
“broad and inclusive”22 definition allowing government to security crises, and public health emergencies. But even in
seize land for the benefit of private corporations whose ac- nonemergency situations, abuse of prescription drug pat-
tivities could eventually improve the public good or the sub- ents can have substantial impact on the health of the Ameri-
jective aesthetic quality of an area. can people and the stability of the health care system. If the
The Kelo v New London case affirmed this broader defi- manufacturer of an agent active against avian influenza
nition of eminent domain. The city argued that expropri- (whether a neuraminidase inhibitor or a vaccine) refused
ating homeowners’ property to allow a private company to to allow licensing agreements with other manufacturers to
develop the site would provide jobs, generate tax revenue, ensure adequate supply, or if excessive pricing of an inno-
and “build momentum for the revitalization of down- vative drug for cancer or AIDS makes the treatment un-
town.” Some affected homeowners sued the city, claiming available to poor patients, should this qualify as a threat to
it had overstepped its eminent domain rights and arguing the public health important enough to justify invoking emi-
that the government’s confiscation would primarily ben- nent domain to ensure access? If a company engages in patent
©2006 American Medical Association. All rights reserved. (Reprinted) JAMA, January 25, 2006—Vol 295, No. 4 435
COMMENTARIES

evergreening to add years to a drug’s market exclusivity and tive practices, as happened with ciprofloxacin and may be
prevent marketing of generic alternatives, should the gov- occurring with oseltamivir. Even if not applied, govern-
ernment invoke its eminent domain authority to assist be- mental willingness to use such power could help move the
leaguered public payers like Medicaid? country toward a more fairly balanced intellectual prop-
One way to approach these questions would be to de- erty policy by helping to prevent companies from exerting
velop a standard to define when the risk of damage to the their patent rights even to the detriment of the public’s health.
public’s health is substantial enough to take such a step. An- Now that the Supreme Court has reaffirmed that the state
other would be to organize a standing committee within the can override homeowners’ property rights to transform a
US Department of Health and Human Services to hear pe- neighborhood into office space “for the public good,” would
titions from state departments of health, patient groups, fed- it not be equally justifiable on rare occasions for the gov-
eral agencies, generic drug manufacturers, and other pay- ernment to use the same authority to limit the (intellec-
ers. This group could evaluate life-threatening shortages or tual) property rights of biomedical corporations to protect
perceived manipulations of patent rights that might justify the public welfare? The latter application would seem closer
use of eminent domain. In making its recommendation, the to the original public good intent of the constitutional emi-
committee would consider the magnitude of the effect on nent domain provision. The Kelo v New London decision
the public health, the availability of alternative solutions, could provide a relevant precedent with a touch of irony: a
and the potential for a decision to suppress future innova- major beneficiary of the “revitalization” of the affected area
tions in the field. There is precedent for such a committee of New London, and the owner of a large parcel of land ad-
in hearings that the NIH has organized on the few occa- jacent to the disputed site, is the world’s largest drug com-
sions it has considered patent ownership issues in the past.30 pany, Pfizer.33
Exercising such authority would require providing ap- Financial Disclosures: None reported.
propriate compensation to the owners of the intellectual
property rights. In cases of patent evergreening, such pe- REFERENCES
ripheral patents are usually for the purpose of maintaining 1. Schull M. Effect of drug patents in developing countries. BMJ. 2000;321:833-
market exclusivity, rather than to protect these “innova- 834.
tions.” Compensation for invoking eminent domain in these 2. Kesselheim AS, Fischer MA, Avorn J. The financial impact of current drug patent
policy on Medicaid drug spending. J Gen Intern Med. 2005;20(suppl 1):139.
circumstances would therefore be modest. By contrast, for 3. Pollack A. Defensive drug industry: fueling clash over patents. New York Times.
AIDS drugs or a treatment or vaccine for avian influenza, if April 20, 2001:A6.
4. Pecoul B, Chirac P, Trouiller P, Pinel J. Access to essential drugs in poor coun-
the patent holder refused to allow licensing at a reasonable tries: a lost battle? JAMA. 1999;281:361-367.
price to ensure adequate and affordable supply, the re- 5. Dash PR. Govt puts Novartis cancer drug on notice. India Times. February 15,
2005. Available at: http://timesofindia.indiatimes.com/articleshow/1022035
quired reimbursement to the corporations involved would .cms. Accessed September 19, 2005.
be substantially higher. Economists have tried to value this 6. Attaran A, Gillespie-White L. Do patents for antiretroviral drugs constrain ac-
proposition,31 which would entail estimating a reasonable cess to AIDS treatment in Africa? JAMA. 2001;286:1886-1892.
7. Bradsher K. Pressure rises on a producer of a flu drug. New York Times. Oc-
market price for the drug and considering the effective time tober 11, 2005:C1.
left on the patent. 8. Pollack A. Hoarding prompts halt in flu drug shipping. New York Times. Oc-
tober 27, 2005:A16.
9. Avorn J. Torcetrapib and atorvastatin—should marketing drive the research
Conclusion agenda? N Engl J Med. 2005;352:2573-2575.
10. Vitamin Technologists v Wisconsin Alumni Research Foundation, 146 F2d
For better or worse, most of current therapeutics is based 941 (9th Cir Ct App 1945).
on private ownership of pharmaceutical discoveries, even 11. Petersen L, Pear R. Anthrax fears send demand for drug far beyond output.
New York Times. October 16, 2001:A1.
if the origin of those therapies is based on publicly funded 12. Malakoff D. NIH declines to march in on pricing AIDS drug. Science. 2004;305:
university-based research.32 Advocates of such ownership 926.
argue that it is necessary for the public good of new drug 13. 35 USC §203 (2005).
14. Love J. NIH meeting on Norvir/Ritonavir march-in request. May 25, 2004.
development. In some circumstances, however, this own- Available at: http://www.essentialinventions.org/legal/norvir/may25nihjamie
ership may jeopardize another widely regarded public good, .pdf. Accessed December 8, 2005.
15. Kesselheim AS, Avorn J. University-based science and biotechnology prod-
namely the right of those who are ill to have access to life- ucts: defining the boundaries of intellectual property. JAMA. 2005;293:850-854.
saving medicine or other health care services. A stark choice 16. Riordan T. Claritin and six other drugs hope to get a little Congressional help
on further patent protection. New York Times. May 10, 1999:C13.
arises if these two public goods are irreconcilable: “When 17. Harris G, McGinley L. Industry splits over Bristol-Myers’s bid to protect top
free enterprise and the freedom to live clash, which free- drug from generic sales. Wall Street Journal. November 21, 2001:A16.
dom will we limit?”32 While the role of eminent domain in 18. McGrory M. Patently offensive. Washington Post. November 28, 1995:A2.
19. Federal Trade Commission. To Promote Innovation: The Proper Balance of
this context is a legal question, application of this author- Competition and Patent Law and Policy. Washington, DC: Federal Trade Com-
ity is an inherently political decision, as Kelo v New London mission, 2003. Available at: http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/10/innovationrpt.pdf.
Accessed September 22, 2004.
(and its contentious aftermath) make clear. 20. Mojtabai R, Olfson M. Medication costs, adherence, and health outcomes among
Faced with eminent domain assumption of their intel- Medicare beneficiaries. Health Aff (Millwood). 2003;22:220-229.
21. Kelo v New London, 125 S Ct 2655 (2005).
lectual property with market-value compensation, pharma- 22. Berman v Parker, 348 US 26 (Sup Ct 1954).
ceutical manufacturers may choose to curb anticompeti- 23. Judicial Code and Judiciary Act, Pub L No. 80-773 (1948); 28 USC §1948 (2005).

436 JAMA, January 25, 2006—Vol 295, No. 4 (Reprinted) ©2006 American Medical Association. All rights reserved.
COMMENTARIES

24. Judicial Business of the United States Courts US Court of Federal Claims: Cases Tommy Thompson. October 18, 2001. Available at: http://www.cptech.org/ip
Filed, Terminated, and Pending for the 12-Month Period Ending September 30, /health/cl/cipro/nadethom10182001.html. Accessed August 29, 2005.
2004. 2004. Available at: http://www.uscourts.gov/judbus2004/appendices/g2a 29. Public Health Emergency Medicines Act, HR 3235, 107th Cong (2001).
.pdf. Accessed August 29, 2005. 30. McGarey BM, Levey AC. Patents, products, and public health: an analysis of
25. Vedantan S, Chea T. Drug firm plays defense in anthrax scare. Washington the CellPro march-in petition. Berkeley Tech Law J. 1999;14:1095-1116.
Post. October 20, 2001:A4. 31. Guell RC. Haggling for a patent: what a government would have to pay for
26. Resnik DB, De Ville KA. Bioterrorism and patient rights: “compulsory licen- prescription drug patents. Health Econ. 1997;6:179-185.
sure” and the case of Cipro. Am J Bioeth. 2002;2:29-45. 32. Avorn J. Powerful Medicines: The Benefits, Risks, and Costs of Prescription
27. Dugger C. A catch-22 on drugs for the world’s poor. New York Times. No- Drugs. New York, NY: Alfred A. Knopf; 2004.
vember 16, 2001:W1. 33. Mann T. Pfizer’s fingerprints on Fort Trumbull plan. The Day [New London,
28. Nader R, Love J. Letter from Ralph Nader and James Love to DHHS Secretary Conn]. October 16, 2005:A1.

US Health Policy in the Aftermath


of Hurricane Katrina
Sara Rosenbaum, JD joining the terms “Hurricane Katrina” and “health care”
turned up 12.2 million hits. Devastating news accounts re-
garding the terrible health conditions endured by survi-

I
N A SEASON THAT EXPERIENCED AN ONSLAUGHT OF
vors, particularly the poor,5 have given way to more far-
major hurricanes, Hurricane Katrina nonetheless
reaching assessments regarding Katrina’s long-term
stands apart as a seminal social event. Katrina did not
implications for health care in the Gulf Coast region. The
merely lay waste to a geographic region; it also
consequences for low-income populations have been par-
exposed every public policy failure essential to community
ticularly severe. In the affected states, an estimated 106 fed-
and population health. Nicholas Lemann wrote that, “after
erally funded community health centers with 166 service
the levees broke, we watched every single system associ-
sites were destroyed, damaged, or overwhelmed by patient
ated with the life of a city fail: the electric grid, the water
surges, with surrounding states experiencing up to 100 000-
system, the sewer system, the transportation system, the
person patient surges.6 New Orleans’ Charity Hospital, a prin-
telephone system, the police force, the fire department, the
cipal source of health care and the only level I trauma cen-
hospitals, even the system for disposing of corpses.”1 The
ter for the entire Gulf Coast region,7 was left devastated and
US Department of Homeland Security reported that as of
dysfunctional, furloughing nearly 2600 employees as of No-
September 15, 2005, 90 000 square miles had been
vember 7, 2005.8
declared disaster areas, and over 122 000 persons were
To rebuild the region means rebuilding health care ser-
housed in shelters throughout the nation.2 Three months
vices, since accessible and affordable health care is essen-
later, in December 2005, more than a million people are
tial to basic population health and safety. However, the re-
still reported to be homeless.3
building task faces particularly great challenges; even if capital
Hurricane Katrina exposed a health care system inca-
can be found, the population is so pervasively uninsured
pable of withstanding the long-term impact of a major di-
that its ability to sustain reclaimed facilities is open to ques-
saster. Through destruction and permanent displacement,
tion. For decades the Gulf Coast population has lived daily
Katrina illuminated the fundamental weaknesses inherent
with the consequences of the nation’s gap-ridden approach
in the national approach to health care financing, as well as
to health care financing. The lack of coverage is unnerving:
the extent to which these weaknesses can threaten recov-
in 2004, only 47% of Louisiana’s nonelderly residents and
ery. Yet almost from the moment that health care emerged
48% of Mississippi residents had employer-sponsored ben-
as a major issue, a battle rapidly ensued over the appropri-
efits, and the nonelderly uninsured population in each state
ate scope of the response.4 Now, several months after this
stood at 21% and 20%, respectively.9 Only in Alabama did
disaster, prospects are increasingly dim that this cata-
the proportion of the population with employer coverage
strophic event will yield at least modest improvements in
exceed the national average,9 but privately insured resi-
the national policy arsenal for effectively responding to di-
dents were concentrated in the state’s industrial regions, not
sasters, manmade or national.
the towns that dot the coastline. All in all, the region’s de-
Viewing National Health Care Policy
Author Affiliation: Department of Health Policy, George Washington University
in the Context of Katrina School of Public Health and Health Services, Washington, DC.
Corresponding Author: Sara Rosenbaum, JD, Hirsch Health Law and Policy Pro-
Katrina has received extensive attention over its impact on gram, George Washington University School of Public Health, 2021 K St NW, #800,
health care; indeed, a mid-December 2005 Google search Washington, DC 20006 (sarar@gwu.edu).

©2006 American Medical Association. All rights reserved. (Reprinted) JAMA, January 25, 2006—Vol 295, No. 4 437

You might also like