You are on page 1of 14

Applied Economics, 2004, 36, 291–303

What determines the value and volume


of noncash transactions? Evidence from
a panel of European and North American
countries
§ A L E SS A N D R A G U A R I G L I A * and zY IIN G J I A LOK E
§School of Economics, University of Nottingham, Nottingham NG7 2RD,
UK and zSchool of Social Sciences, Universiti Sains Malaysia, 11800 Minden,
Penang, Malaysia

Using data from a panel of 15 countries over the period 1990–1998, the determinants
of the use of non cash payment instruments are analysed. The estimation results
highlight the importance of distinguishing between the determinants of the value and
volume of noncash transactions. It is found in fact that the volume of these transac-
tions is generally affected by changes in the determinants more strongly than their
value, and that variables such as the interest rate have a different impact on the
volume and the value of the transactions. The findings also suggest that past habits
play a dominant role in the intensity of use of noncash payment instruments.

I. INTRODUCTION and developments of noncash payment mechanisms at


retail level. As Hancock and Humphrey (1998) put it:
Owing to improved computer technology and to the dereg- ‘. . .although the popular press is full of references on the
ulation of banks, the past decade has been characterized potential use of new types of payment arrangements – from
by rapid financial innovation, which brought about the the effect of ATMs and smart cards on cash use to the
extended use of various payment instruments other than potential for electronic payments over the Internet to
cash, such as cheques, credit and debit cards, and direct replace cheques or credit cards for bill payments – little
debits.1 One aspect of the effects of financial innovation theoretical (and even less empirical) work has been done
that has been widely stressed in recent research includes in this area.’ (pp. 1574–5). More specifically, given the wide
the implications of the growth in the density of ATM disparities in the payment systems across developed coun-
(Automated Teller Machines) and EFTPOS (Electronic tries, it would be interesting to understand how tech-
Funds Transfer at Point-of-Sale) terminals,2 and of the nological and institutional factors affect these disparities
development of noncash payment instruments on cash use compared to macro-monetary determinants; the extent to
and its consequence on the demand for money (Trundle, which the respective determinants of the different payment
1992; Johnston, 1984; Boeschoten, 1992; Snellman et al., instruments can explain the variation in the payment trends
2000, 2001). across countries; and what the relationship among the
However, little attention has been given to understand- noncash payment instruments looks like in various coun-
ing the underlying factors that actually influence the trends tries. This paper aims to provide an understanding of these

*Corresponding author. E-mail: alessandra.guariglia@nottingham.ac.uk


1
A direct debit is an authority given to one’s bank or building society to make regular payments from a current account at the request of,
and to the account of, a specified organization. Direct debits are generally used to pay bills. They save the time and trouble of writing and
sending a cheque or paying in cash.
2
EFTPOS terminals are terminals that accept debit and credit cards.

Applied Economics ISSN 0003–6846 print/ISSN 1466–4283 online # 2004 Taylor & Francis Ltd 291
http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals
DOI: 10.1080/0003684041000167222
292 A. Guariglia and Y. J. Loke
issues, and more in general to give a clear idea of what the transactions, and then manipulate the relevant technologi-
determinants of various noncash payment instruments are cal, institutional, and macro-monetary variables necessary
in developed countries. to achieve this system.
Three recent studies have analysed the determinants of The second contribution of this paper is methodological:
noncash payment instruments. The first one, Humphery updated estimation techniques compared to those in
et al. (1996a), uses data for a panel of 14 developed countries previous literature are used. Humphrey et al. (1996a) and
over the period 1986–1993 to study the determinants of the Snellman et al. (2000, 2001) estimate in fact their panel
volume of transactions conducted in five noncash payment regressions applying either Ordinary Least Squares (OLS)
instruments, namely credit and debit cards, paper and elec- to their pooled panel data set or simple fixed effects tech-
tronic giros, and cheques. The second one, Snellman et al. niques. Applying OLS to panel data is however likely to
(2000, 2001), uses a panel of ten European countries over the lead to biased and inconsistent estimates, as it does not
period 1989–1996 to analyse the determinants of the value of take into account unobserved country heterogeneity.
card transactions. The third one, Humphrey (2002), focuses Similarly, using a fixed effects estimator is also likely to
on the determinants of the value of card transactions, using lead to biased and inconsistent estimates when the model
a time-series of US data for the period 1974–2000.3 to be estimated is dynamic and the time dimension of the
In this paper, the comprehensive payment statistics panel is small (Nickell, 1981). Furthermore, both estima-
data sets compiled by the European Monetary Institute tion techniques do not take into account the possible endo-
(EMI) and the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) geneity bias, which might affect some of the regressors. In
for selected EU and G10 countries from 1990 to 1998 are this paper, the dynamic equations for the demand of non-
exploited to provide a further analysis of the determinants cash payment instruments are estimated using the GMM
estimator, which allows both unobserved country hetero-
of noncash payment instruments. Within Groups and
geneity and the endogeneity bias to be taken into account.5
Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) estimators are
The remainder of the paper is laid out as follows. In the
used to regress the value and the volume of the per capita
next section, the data set is described. In Section III, the
transactions financed by each of three noncash payment
empirical specification is presented and the methodology
instruments, namely cards,4 direct debits, and cheques, on
used in estimation discussed. Section IV reports the econo-
selected explanatory variables such as interest rates, avail-
metric results of the estimation of the regressions for the
ability of ATM and EFTPOS terminals, past habits, cash
volume and value of the transactions conducted using three
holdings per capita, and private consumption per capita.
noncash payment instruments, namely credit and debit
Using panel data techniques allows particular attention
cards, direct debits, and cheques. Section V concludes the
to be paid to the country heterogeneity and the dynamic paper.
features of the model.
The principal contribution of this study is that, contrary
to the previous literature, which focused on the determi-
nants of either only the volume or only the value of trans- I I . DA T A A N D D E SC R I P T I V E S T A T I ST I C S
actions conducted in noncash payment instruments, it
considers both the volume and the value of transactions. The basic payment data set used in this paper draws from
This is important as it turns out that the explanatory the payment statistics complied by the European Monetary
variables used have very different effects on these two Institute and the Bank for International Settlements. The
types of transactions. Thus, if a country aimed at achieving latter is used for payment data on Canada, Switzerland, and
a specific payment system, it should first establish what the USA, while the data for Austria, Belgium, Denmark,
this system looks like in terms of volume or value of Finland, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal,

3
Note that the 2000 version of Snellman et al.’s work is a much longer version of their 2001 paper. Also note that the main focus of
Snellman et al. (2000, 2001) is on the effects of the development of cards and cheques as noncash POS payment instruments on cash use,
whereas the main objective of Humphrey (2002) is the implementation of a model aimed at determining the share of cash payments in the
USA in the last 25 years.
4
Contrary to Humphrey et al. (1996a), who estimate separate regressions for credit cards and debit cards, in this paper, credit and debit
cards are pooled together (see Snellman et al., 2000, 2001, for a similar approach). This is motivated by the fact that in the data set
disaggregated data for credit and debit cards were only available for the USA, Canada, and France.
5
It is also worth noting that this study is based on a time period and a sample of countries slightly different from those used by
Humphrey et al. (1996a) and Snellman et al. (2000, 2001). In particular, the analysis covers the payment trends over the period 1990–
1998, whereas Humphrey et al. (1996a) only focus on the period 1989–1993, and Snellman et al. (2000, 2001) consider the period 1988–
1996. In addition, the data set includes three EU countries namely Austria, Portugal, and Spain which are not included in Humphrey
et al. (1996a) and Snellman et al. (2000, 2001)’s samples, but it excludes Japan and Norway, which are part of Humphrey et al. (1996a)’s
sample. The latter two countries were excluded from the data set due to missing data on several payment instruments such as the volume
of cards and the value and volume of direct debits.
Determinants of the value and volume of noncash transactions 293
Table 1. Aggregate descriptive statistics for 15 selected EU and G10 countries over the period 1990–1998

Mean Std. deviation Min Max

Part I: Value and volume of transactions for each payment instrument (per year per person)

Real Value (US$)


Cards 1421.4 1037.16 54.5 4830
Direct debits 7879.607 9383.78 467 44 700
Cheques 84 523.99 150 795.70 230 714 000
Volume
Cards 23.346 20.922 0.283 86
Direct debits 15.401 15.067 0.822 65.7
Cheques 36.421 59.100 0.339 248

Part II: Macro-monetary variables

Interest rate (%) 5.132 2.818 0.69 14.8


Real cash holdings per person 1208.2 629.379 366 3340
Real private consumption per person 13 871.78 3726.188 6210 26 000
ATM terminals per person 0.000 392 1 0.000 1731 0.000 0545 0.009 62
EFTPOS terminals per person 0.004 935 2 0.003 9218 0.000 087 0.0184

Source: Bank for International Settlements, (1993, 1996, 2000), Statistics on Payment Systems in the Group of Ten Countries, Basle.
European Monetary Institute/European Central Bank, (1993, 1996, 2000), Payment Systems in the European Union, Frankfurt. Inter-
national Monetary Fund (2000), International Financial Statistics Yearbook 1999.
Spain, Sweden, and the UK are obtained from the European tively US$1412.4 and US$7897.6.7 The statistics also
Monetary Institute. The data coverage spans from 1990 to show that there exists a very strong contrast between the
1998.6 The data set consists therefore of 135 pooled obser- maximum value of cheque and card transactions per per-
vations accounting for 15 countries over nine years. son, while there is a smaller difference between the max-
All variables are annual end of year time series data. For imum volume of the two transactions. In particular, the
ease of international comparisons, where appropriate, pay- maximum value of cheque transactions is approximately
ment data are given in per capita terms and, where values 147 times higher than the maximum value of card transac-
are involved, they are deflated to adjust for inflation, and tions, while the maximum volume of cheque transactions is
converted to US dollars. only 2.88 times higher than the corresponding volume of
Table 1 presents the descriptive statistics relative to all card transactions. This corroborates the previous conclu-
the variables used in this study, obtained by pooling the sion that cheques are used for larger value transactions
data for all the selected EU and G10 countries over the than cards.
period 1990–1998. Part I of the Table refers to the value Second, according to Part II of Table 1, the wide disper-
and volume of per capita transactions undertaken using sion of interest rates between the maximum and minimum
cards, direct debits, and cheques. Part II refers to the value describes the downward trend in interest rates which
other variables that will be included in the regressions for characterized the period 1990–1998. The maximum value
the determinants of noncash payment instruments, namely (14.8) was found in 1991 in Portugal and the minimum
the interest rate, real cash holdings per capita, real private value (0.69) was registered in 1998 in Switzerland.
consumption per capita, and the number of ATM and Third, there is a wide gap between the maximum and
EFTPOS terminals per person. minimum values of the real cash holdings per person,
Several stylized trends can be observed from these sta- reflecting the differences in the intensity of the use of
tistics. First, it can be see from Part I of the Table that cash in the sample countries. The minimum real value of
there are only minor differences in the mean volume of cash holdings per person was recorded in Finland in 1993
transactions per person compared to the wide disparity in (US$366), whereas the maximum value was found in
the mean value of transactions between the noncash pay- Switzerland in 1995 (US$3340).
ment instruments. In value terms, cheques seem to be asso- Fourth, the large differences between the maximum and
ciated with much higher value transactions than cards or minimum values of the ATM terminals per person and
direct debits. The mean value of cheque transactions per the EFTPOS terminals per person illustrates the evolution
person is in fact US$84524.0, whereas the corresponding and the gaps in the stage of development in the payment
figures for card and direct debit transactions are respec- systems amongst the countries.
6
Data for 1999 were only available for eight countries. This is why the analysis is limited to the period 1990–1998.
7
These means represent the average per capita values of the relevant transactions per year over the period 1990–1998. The very wide
standard deviation characterizing the value of cheque transactions should also be noted. The smallest cheque transaction, 230 US$, was
recorded in the Netherlands in 1998, whereas the largest, 714 000 US$, was recorded in Canada in 1990.
294 A. Guariglia and Y. J. Loke
III. EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION AND which represents a time-specific component that pick up
E ST I M A T I O N M E T H O D O L O G Y business cycle effects; and "it, which represents an idiosyn-
cratic component. The time-specific component of the error
Main empirical specification term is taken into account by including time dummies in
all the specifications. A log-linear model is used in all the
Following Humphrey et al. (1996a), for each payment regressions. Hence, the coefficients can be interpreted as
instrument, dynamic reduced form regressions of the fol-
elasticities. Both dynamic specifications as in Equation
lowing type will be estimated:
(1) and static specifications not including the lagged depen-
Mj, it ¼  þ X 0it  þ Cj Mj, iðt1Þ þ i þ t þ "it ð1Þ dent variable are estimated.

where i indexes countries; t, time; and j, the noncash pay-


ment instrument considered (i.e. cards, direct debits, and Estimation methodology
cheques).8
The dependent variables M represent in turn the value Initially Equation 1 is estimated using a Within Groups
and the volume of transactions per person conducted in estimator, which transforms the equation to eliminate the
each of the selected noncash payment instruments. i component of the error term. The transformation con-
Mj,i(t1) includes the lagged dependent variable, as well as sists in expressing all variables as deviations from indi-
past values of the value or volume of competing payment vidual means. The model provides an estimate, reported as
instruments. These variables are included to measure the rho (), representing the proportion of the observed total
influence of past habits on the current use of selected pay- variance of the error term accounted for by unobserved
ment instruments. Following Humphrey et al. (1996a), the heterogeneity. On top of taking into account unobserved
remaining regressors (Xit) include macro-monetary vari- country heterogeneity, another advantage of the Within
ables, i.e. the interest rate,9 the real value of cash holdings Groups estimation technique is that it allows the potential
per person,10 and the real value of private consumption time-invariant measurement error in the regressors (which
per person; and technological support factors data, i.e. will be encompassed in i) to be dealt with. However, for
the number of ATM and EFTPOS terminals per person.11 panels where the number of time periods is relatively small,
The latter variable is used to represent the availability of the estimates obtained using this method are likely to be
credit and debit card equipment. The number of ATM biased and inconsistent, as the transformed lagged depen-
terminals per person is included because the more terminals dent variable and the transformed error term will be
there are, the easier it is to obtain cash, lowering therefore negatively correlated (Nickell, 1981).13
the relative user cost of cash.12 Equation 1 is also estimated using a Generalized-
The error term is made up of three components: i, Method-of-Moments (GMM) first-differenced estimator,
which denotes a country-specific unobservable effect; t, which allows to control for both the country-specific het-

8
Unlike Humphrey et al. (1996a), the determinants of paper and electronic giros are not considered. The latter noncash payment instru-
ments are in fact essentially used for large value transactions, and are therefore not directly comparable to cards, direct debits, and
cheques. Also note that Humphrey et al. (1996a) did not analyse the determinants of direct debits individually. However, direct debits are
included in their wider electronic giros category, which also includes direct deposits and other automated clearing house payments.
9
The interest rate is used as a proxy for the price of the single transactions undertaken using the noncash payment instruments. Note that
because, as documented in Humphrey et al. (1996a), in a number of countries, users typically do not pay a per transaction price, and even
if they do, this price is generally below cost, using the interest rate as a proxy for transaction prices is a reasonable simplification. For
general information on the estimated cost of using each type of noncash payment instruments such as credit cards, direct debits, and
cheques for retailers and consumers, see Drehmann et al. (2002, Part C of the Appendix). Snellmann et al. (2000, 2001) and Humphrey
(2002) also used the interest rate as an explanatory variable in their regressions for the value of card transactions.
10
Note that only the real value of cash holdings per person is included in the regressions. Ideally, the volume/value of cash transactions
should have been included, but these data do not exist.
11
Snellman et al. (2000, 2001) do not include EFTPOS as a direct determinant of the value of card transaction. They use it as a
determinant of the coefficient on their (currency þ cheques) regressor, which they allow to vary over time as a function of the number
of EFTPOS per person and of country-specific effects.
12
Like other existing studies on the role of ‘bad behaviour’ on the demand for currency (Rogoff, 1998; Drehmann and Goodhart, 2000;
and Drehmann et al., 2002), Humphrey et al. (1996a) have tried to evaluate the impact of crime on the use of the various noncash
payment instruments. Like Snellman et al. (2000, 2001), crime rates are not included in the set of explanatory variables in this empirical
analysis. Unlike Humphrey et al. (1996a) and like Snellman et al. (2000, 2001), a bank concentration variable is also not included. It is
not thought that not accounting for crime and bank concentration in the specifications can significantly bias the results, as these omitted
variables are likely to vary slowly over time, and can thus be considered to be included in the country-specific component of the error
term. Even Humphrey et al. (1996a) found in fact that these variables were largely insignificant in those specifications which included
country dummies and the lagged dependent variable.
13
Assuming that the other regressors are exogeneous, the Within Groups specification is appropriate when a static model, not including
the lagged dependent variable, is estimated. All the static specifications will therefore be estimated using a Within Groups estimator.
Determinants of the value and volume of noncash transactions 295
erogeneity and the endogeneity bias characterizing some of and Table 4 to cheque transactions. All Tables report the
the regressors, and in particular the lagged dependent vari- estimates obtained with the dynamic model in Equation 1
able. This estimator delivers consistent estimates of the estimated both with the Within Groups and the GMM
parameters. The GMM first-differenced specification esti- specifications, and those obtained with a static model,
mates the original specification expressed in first-differ- estimated with the Within Groups estimator.
ences, and uses ‘internal instruments’, i.e. instruments
that are based on lagged values of the endogenous expla-
natory variables.14 First-differencing allows to control for The determinants of card transactions
unobserved heterogeneity,15 and instrumenting the regres- Column 1 of Table 2 refers to the dynamic Within Groups
sors, to correct for the endogeneity bias. The chosen instru- model and shows that the main determinant of the value
ment set includes values of the dependent variable and of of card transactions is the lagged dependent variable. The
the other noncash payment instruments lagged three coefficient suggests that if the value of card transactions
times.16 Since the regressors included in Xit are assumed undertaken in the past had been higher by 10%, then the
to be exogenous, they are instrumented with current values value undertaken in the present would be higher by 6.6%.
of themselves.17 This can be seen as indication of a strong habit component.
In order to evaluate whether the model used is correctly Cash holdings per person, which are added in the regres-
specified and whether the instruments are valid, two cri- sion to measure the relationship between cash and noncash
teria are used: The Sargan/Hansen statistic and the test payment instruments, are also positively related with the
for second-order serial correlation of the residuals in the value of card transactions, suggesting a relationship of
differenced equation (m2). The former, also known as the complementarity between the two types of payment instru-
J statistic, is a test for overidentifying restrictions, which, ments. This complementarity might be due to the fact that
under the null of instrument validity, is asymptotically dis- in most countries, either there still exists a minimum value
tributed as a chi-square with degrees of freedom equal to for card transactions or an extra cost is imposed on card
the number of instruments less the number of parameters. transactions below a certain threshold. The coefficient on
If the model is correctly specified, the variables in the the number of EFTPOS terminals per person is positive
instrument set should be uncorrelated with the idiosyn- and precisely determined: it suggests that if the number
cratic component of the error term "it. The m2 test is of EFTPOS terminals per person increases by 10%, then
asymptotically distributed as a standard normal under the value of card transactions will rise by 1.1%. This effect
the null of no second-order serial correlation, and provides is not surprising as EFTPOS terminals increase the
a further check on the specification of the model and on the convenience of card use.
legitimacy of variables dated t  2 as instruments.18 The panel variance component, , which represents the
proportion of the observed total variance of the error term
accounted for by unobserved heterogeneity is precisely deter-
IV. ESTIMATION RESULTS mined and equal to 0.92. This suggests that it is important
to take unobserved country-specific characteristics into
The estimation results are reported in Tables 2–4. Table 2 account.
refers to the determinants of the value and volume of card Similar results hold when the GMM specification is used
transactions, Table 3 refers to direct debit transactions, (column 2). In the latter specification, the Sargan and m2

14
See Arellano and Bond (1991) on the application of the GMM approach to panel data. The program DPD by Arellano and Bond
(1998) has been used in estimation.
15
In fact, if one first-differences Equation 1, the country-specific component of the error term, i, drops out.
16
The idiosyncratic component of the error term in the first-differenced equation is ("it  "i(t1)). In order not to be correlated with this
component of the error term, the instruments relative to the first-differenced equation should therefore be lagged twice or more. The
instrument set that we use does not include variable lagged twice because when those variables were included, the m2 and/or Sargan/
Hansen tests rejected the validity of the instruments (see below for a description of the two tests). For similar reasons, other lags of the
instruments beyond the third one were also not included.
17
It could be claimed that the real value of cash holdings per person is endogenous. Similarly, the number of ATM and EFTPOS
terminals per person could be considered as endogenous variables. In fact, it is possible that the number of these terminals is determined
in response to changes in the demand for various noncash payment instruments. Therefore some specifications were estimated, in which
not only the lagged noncash payment instruments, but also cash holding per person, and the number of ATM and EFTPOS terminals per
person were instrumented. The results were not qualitatively different from those presented in the paper. They are not reported for
brevity, but are available from the authors upon request.
18
If the undifferenced error terms are i.i.d., then the differenced residuals should display first-order, but not second-order serial
correlation. In such case, variables lagged twice are valid instruments. Note, however, that, as pointed out in footnote 16, variables
lagged three times had to be used as instruments, as the variables lagged twice did not pass the m2 and/or Sargan/Hansen tests. Also note
that neither the Sargan/Hansen test nor the m2 test allow to discriminate between inappropriate instruments and model specification.
296 A. Guariglia and Y. J. Loke
Table 2. Determinants of the value and volume of card transactions per person

Value of card transactions per person Volume of card transactions per person
Within groups: First diff. Within groups: Within groups: First diff. Within groups:
dynamic GMM: dynamic static dynamic GMM: dynamic static
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Interest rate 0.723 1.138 3.724** 0.313 1.365 1.490
(0.65) (0.74) (1.98) (0.19) (1.02) (0.61)
ATM terminals per person 0.007 0.051 0.355** 0.053 0.138 0.269*
(0.09) (0.47) (3.06) (0.47) (1.05) (1.66)
EFTPOS terminal per 0.112*** 0.165** 0.291*** 0.157** 0.212** 0.363***
person (2.65) (2.01) (4.20) (2.53) (2.54) (4.13)
Real private consumption 0.085 0.056 0.235** 0.055 0.208 0.189
per person (1.35) (0.65) (2.21) (0.57) (0.90) (1.31)
Real cash holdings per 0.426** 0.660*** 0.552* 0.033 0.406 0.774**
person (2.52) (3.80) (1.90) (0.13) (0.76) (2.10)
Card transactions per 0.660*** 0.609*** – 0.759*** 0.813*** –
person (lagged once) (13.35) (7.74) (10.58) (9.69)
Direct debit transactions 0.036 0.028 0.107 0.09 0.366 0.134
per person (lagged once) (0.77) (0.20) (1.35) (1.02) (0.76) (0.97)
Cheque transactions per 0.087 0.123 0.397*** 0.011 0.144 0.111
person (lagged once) (1.24) (0.51) (3.47) (0.11) (1.27) (0.78)
R2-adjusted 0.979 – 0.939 0.977 – 0.948
 0.979 – 0.973 0.543 – 0.920
m2 – 0.433 – – 0.727 –
Sargan/Hansen – 2.094 – – 1.208 –
(d.f.) (15) (15)

Notes: T-statistics are reported in parentheses. Standard error and test statistics are asymptotically robust to heteroscedasticity. Time
dummies were included in all equations. Instruments used in columns (2) and (5): card, direct debit, and cheque transactions per person
lagged three periods. The other variables, i.e. EFTPOS terminals per person, ATM terminals per person, interest rates, real private
consumption per person, and real cash holdings per person are assumed to be exogenous and are used to instrument themselves. The time
dummies were always included in the instrument set. The sample size in columns 1, 3, 4, and 6 is 120 for the period 1991–1998. The
sample size in columns 2 and 5 is 90 for the period 1993–1998 due to the lags in the instruments used.  represents the proportion of the
total error variance accounted for by unobserved heterogeneity. m2 is a test for second-order serial correlation in the first difference
residuals, asymptotically distributed as N(0,1) under the null hypothesis of no serial correlation. The Sargan/Hansen statistic (J test)
provides a test of the overidentifying restrictions distributed as chi-square under the null hypothesis that instruments are valid. The
abbreviation ‘d.f.’ stands for degrees of freedom. *indicates significance at the 10% level. **indicates significance at the 5% level.
***indicates significance at the 1% level.

tests do not suggest the existence of any problems with the the more transactions are likely to be made in all forms.
specification of the model or the choice of the instruments. Finally, the availability of ATMs reduces average cash
In the static specification, cash holdings and the number balances, and since credit and debit cards can be used for
of EFTPOS terminals per person are once again positively cash withdrawals, ATMs increase the benefits of holding
associated with card transactions, together with the interest and using such cards.19
rate, private consumption, and the number of ATM term- The main determinants of the volume of card transac-
inals per person (column 3). These findings are in line with tions are the number of EFTPOS per person and the lagged
those in Snellman et al. (2000, 2001). It is not surprising dependent variable (columns 4–6). These results are com-
that the interest rate and card transactions are positively parable with the findings in Humphrey et al. (1996a) who
related: the interest rate can in fact be interpreted as the estimated separate equations for the volume of transac-
opportunity cost of holding money, so the higher the inter- tions conducted using credit and debit cards and found
est rate, the higher one would except the value and vol- that especially for credit cards, habits play an important
ume of noncash transactions to be. The positive association role. However, while they found that the number of
between private consumption and card transactions can EFTPOS terminals affects the volume of debit card transac-
be explained by the fact that the higher the consumption, tions positively, they also found a negative and significant

19
The coefficient on the ATM variable is in fact precisely determined (although only marginally), also in the static specification relative to
the volume of card transactions (column 6). See the Appendix for an analysis of the coefficients on the country-specific dummy variables
in the static specifications relative to cards, direct debits, and cheques.
Determinants of the value and volume of noncash transactions
Table 3. Determinants of the value and volume of direct debit transactions per person

Value of direct debit transactions per person Volume of direct debit transactions per person
Within groups: First diff. GMM: Within groups: Within groups: First diff. GMM: Within groups:
dynamic dynamic static dynamic dynamic static
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Interest rate 0.127 1.683 0.902 3.541* 5.122* 4.010**
(0.05) (0.47) (0.33) (1.93) (1.84) (2.17)
ATM terminals 0.038 0.467 0.201 0.0133 0.587 0.057
per person (0.24) (0.88) (1.17) (0.11) (1.13) (0.47)
EFTPOS terminal 0.008 0.002 0.015 0.114* 0.219** 0.113
per person (0.09) (0.01) (0.14) (1.66) (2.34) (1.62)
Real private 0.027 0.007 0.061 0.166 0.067 0.213**
consumption per person (0.20) (0.08) (0.39) (1.53) (0.89) (1.98)
Real cash 0.113 0.179 0.344 0.060 0.079 0.086
holdings per person (0.31) (0.37) (0.83) (0.21) (0.33) (0.30)
Card transactions 0.031 0.083 0.100 0.117 0.254* 0.123
per person (lagged once) (0.30) (0.52) (0.82) (1.48) (1.85) (1.53)
Direct debit transactions 0.566*** 0.278*** – 0.207** 0.495*** –
per person (lagged once) (5.68) (2.63) (2.01) (3.08)
Cheque transactions 0.111 0.287 0.160 0.039 0.195 0.023
per person (lagged once) (0.74) (0.93) (0.92) (0.36) (0.77) (0.21)
R2-adjusted 0.942 – 0.922 0.960 – 0.959
 0.804 – 0.938 0.936 – 0.958
m2 – 1.264 – – 1.268 –
Sargan/Hansen – 1.347 – – 2.385 –
(d.f.) (15) (15)

Note: See Notes to Table 2. *indicates significance at the 10% level. **indicates significance at the 5% level. ***indicates significance at the 1% level.

297
298
Table 4. Determinants of the value and volume of cheque transactions per person

Value of cheque transactions per person Volume of cheque transactions per person
Within groups: First diff. GMM: Within groups: Within groups: First diff. GMM: Within groups:
dynamic dynamic static dynamic dynamic static
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Interest rate 0.352 2.414 2.496* 0.718 0.393 0.818
(0.34) (1.36) (1.84) (0.58) (0.41) (0.34)
ATM terminals 0.284*** 0.065 0.509*** 0.033 0.026 0.636***
per person (4.20) (0.58) (6.10) (0.39) (0.35) (4.28)
EFTPOS terminals 0.052 0.055 0.097* 0.017 0.021 0.024
per person (1.30) (0.90) (1.83) (0.37) (0.56) (0.26)
Real private 0.046 0.030 0.115 0.039 0.071 0.160
consumption per person (0.77) (0.66) (1.47) (0.53) (1.32) (1.12)
Real cash 0.453*** 0.660** 0.812*** 0.195 0.04 0.064
holdings per person (2.85) (2.44) (3.98) (1.00) (0.27) (0.17)
Card transactions 0.175*** 0.107* 0.304*** 0.073 0.087* 0.176*
per person (lagged once) (3.77) (1.70) (5.21) (1.36) (1.89) (1.69)
Direct debit transactions 0.053 0.018 0.031 0.004 0.154 0.078
per person (lagged once) (1.21) (0.197) (0.54) (0.06) (1.08) (0.58)
Cheque transactions 0.563*** 0.842*** – 1.165*** 1.158*** –
per person (lagged once) (8.48) (6.81) (16.11) (10.01)
R2-adjusted 0.994 – 0.990 0.990 – 0.963
 0.984 – 0.994 0.624 – 0.969
m2 – 2.712 – – 2.295 –
Sargan/Hansen – 4.906 – – 0.013 –
(d.f.) (15) (15)

A. Guariglia and Y. J. Loke


Note: See Notes to Table 2. *indicates significance at the 10% level. **indicates significance at the 5% level. ***indicates significance at the 1% level.
Determinants of the value and volume of noncash transactions 299
association between this variable and the volume of credit static Within Groups specification, none of the regressors is
card transactions in their static specification.20 precisely determined. This can be explained by the fact that
The regressions in Table 2 show that both the effect of the value of direct debit transactions is largely driven by
the number of EFTPOS terminals and the habit compo- the value of similar transactions undertaken in the past. It
nent are larger in the volume regressions compared to the is also worth noting that direct debits are a relatively new
value regressions. The fact that the coefficient on the form of electronic payment that has only gained popularity
EFTPOS variable is larger in the volume compared to from the mid-1990s onwards.
the value regression suggests that the availability of Focusing on the volume regressions, it can be seen that
EFTPOS terminals essentially increases the convenience in all models, the EFTPOS variable is positively and sig-
of using cards, and therefore the frequency of their use. nificantly or marginally significantly associated with the
In the static specification (column 6), a negative relation- volume of direct debits (columns 4–6). In the GMM speci-
ship emerges between real cash holdings and the volume of fication (column 5), for instance, the coefficient associated
card transactions per person, indicating the substitutability with the EFTPOS variable suggests that if the number of
between the two payment methods.21 Thus, in the static EFTPOS terminals per person rises by 10%, then the
specification, cash and card transactions work as comple- volume of direct debit transactions will go up by 2.2%.
ments if the value of transactions is focused on, and as Although direct debits operate through an electronic system
substitutes if their volume is focused on. As pointed out which does not use the same infrastructure as EFTPOS, this
above, this may suggest that although cash and cards can result can be explained by the fact that the increased avail-
both be categorized as retail instruments, cards cannot ability of EFTPOS terminals makes people more favourable
completely substitute for cash in terms of the value of to electronic fund transfers in general. In the Within Groups
transactions because there exists a minimum threshold and GMM dynamic models, the lagged dependent variable
value for which a transaction can be undertaken by card.22 is also precisely determined and positive (columns 4 and 5).
It is also worth noting that in the volume regressions, the
The coefficient on the interest rate variable is negative and
coefficient on the interest rate variable is never statistically
statistically significant in all specifications (columns 4–6). In
significant, whereas it was precisely determined in the static
the GMM specification (column 5), a negative relationship
specification for the value of card transactions. This high-
emerges between current direct debit transactions and
lights the fact that the interest rate can be seen as a cost to
lagged card transactions. This suggests that the two pay-
the value rather than the volume of card transaction. This
ment instruments can be considered as substitutes.23
finding corroborates the importance of looking at the deter-
Finally, in the static specification, the coefficient on private
minants of the volume and value of transactions separately.
consumption is also positive and precisely determined.
In all the Within Groups specifications, the  coefficient
The determinants of direct debit transactions lies between 0.80 and 0.96, suggesting the importance of
taking the country-specific effects into account. In none of
In the dynamic Within Groups specification, lagged direct
the GMM specifications do the Sargan/Hansen and m2
debits are the main determinant of current direct debit
tests indicate problems with the instrument selection or
transactions (Table 3, column 1), indicating once more
the general specification of the model.
the importance of habits. Although smaller in magnitude,
this variable is also precisely determined in the GMM spe-
cification (column 2). It has to be noted that the specifi-
The determinants of cheque transactions
cations relative to the value of direct debit transactions
are less satisfactory than those for cards, as less variables The value of lagged cheque transactions is positively asso-
appear to be statistically significant. In particular, in the ciated with the value of current transactions both in the

20
It has to be noted that Humphrey et al. (1996a)’s static specification does not include the country-specific dummies and therefore boils
down to applying OLS to the pooled data set. Because this approach does not take unobserved heterogeneity into account, the estimated
coefficients are likely to be biased.
21
In their static specification, Humphrey et al. (1996a) also found a negative (although insignificant) relationship between the volume of
credit card transactions and real cash holdings, but they observed a positive and significant relationship between the volume of debit card
transactions and real cash holding. Contrary to the present findings, they also found a negative and significant relationship between
the volume of credit card transactions and the volume of lagged cheque transactions; and a positive and significant association
between the volume of debit card transactions and the volume of lagged cheque transactions.
22
In Table 1, it can be seen that the minimum value of card transaction is US$54.50. This is obviously higher than the usual value of cash
transaction that one typically makes.
23
In their static electronic giros specification, Humphrey et al. (1996a) found evidence that electronic giros and credit cards are sub-
stitutes, whereas electronic giros and debit cards are complements. As stated above, however, their electronic giros category is wider than
the direct debits category that we use.
300 A. Guariglia and Y. J. Loke
Within Groups and the GMM specifications (columns 1 nificant in the regressions relative to the volume of cheque
and 2 of Table 4). transactions, whereas it is positive and precisely determined
The coefficient on lagged card transactions is also nega- in the static regression for the value of cheque transactions.
tive and precisely determined in all specifications, indicat- This finding confirms that the interest rate can be seen as
ing that cheques and cards are used as substitutes. Cash a cost incentive factor for cash economization in value
holdings are positively associated with the value of cheque terms only, and stresses once again the importance of
transactions, indicating the existence of some sort of analysing the determinants of the volume and value of
completementarity between the two payment methods. transactions conducted using various noncash payment
In both Within Groups specifications (columns 1 and 3), instruments, separately.
the coefficient on the ATM variable is positive and signifi- In both the volume and value GMM specifications, the
cant, whereas that on the EFTPOS variable is negative and m2 test seems to indicate some problems with the instru-
precisely determined in the static model (column 3). Since ment selection and/or the general specification of the
EFTPOS terminals increase the convenience of card use, model. However, since the Sargan/Hansen statistic is satis-
the negative effect that they have on cheque use is not sur- factory in both cases, this is not thought to be a serious
prising. The positive sign of the coefficient on the ATM problem.
variable could be due to the fact that ATM machines
allow the transfer of money between saving and checking
accounts, making cheque transactions indirectly easier. In V. CONCLUSIONS
the static model, there is also a positive association between
the interest rate and the value of cheque transactions In this paper, the determinants of noncash payment instru-
(column 3). ments in 15 EU and G10 countries between 1990 and 1998
As for the volume of cheque transactions, its main deter- have been analysed. More specifically, the roles of selected
minant in the dynamic model is the lagged dependent vari- variables which include technological innovation factors,
able (columns 4 and 5), indicating once more a strong habit financial variables, and past habits have been explored.
component.24 Like in the case of cards, past habits seem to Moving one step further with respect to previous literature,
have a stronger hold on the volume of cheque transactions the focus has been both on the value and the volume of
than on their value. When the coefficient on the lagged noncash transactions, and a GMM estimation technique
volume of cheque transactions in the cheques’ regression has been applied.
is compared with the coefficient on the lagged volume of The main findings can be summarized as follows. First,
card transactions in the cards’ regressions, it is found that past habits play a dominant role in determining both the
the former is larger than the latter. The stronger hold that value and the volume (intensity of use) of all noncash pay-
past habits seem to have on the use of cheques relative to ment instruments, the latter effect being generally larger
cards might be due to the observed strong cheque payment than the former. Moreover, past habits affect the volume
habit (cheque base) which is found especially in USA and of cheque transactions more strongly than the volume of
Canada (Humphrey et al., 1996b; McAndrews, 1997; card transactions. This is likely to be due to the fact that
Hancock and Humphrey, 1998). the cheque payment base is relatively more established than
The coefficients on the lagged card transactions in the cards, as cheque use has begun much earlier than card use.
estimation relative to the volume of cheque transactions Second, technological innovation through EFTPOS
are negative and significant or marginally significant in terminals has a clear and positive influence on the use of
the dynamic GMM specification and in the static specifica- card payments both in terms of volume and value of trans-
tion (columns 5 and 6), confirming that the two methods of actions, as well as on the volume of direct debit transac-
payment can be considered as substitutes.25 These coeffi- tions. Third, the interest rate is positively related with the
cients are lower than the coefficients of cash transactions value of card and cheque transactions, but not with the
in the static regressions for the volume of card transaction, volume of these transactions, suggesting that it can be
suggesting that the use of cards is substituting for cash seen as a cost incentive factor for cash economization in
more than for cheque use. value terms only. Fourth, it has been shown that if the
Finally, unlike Humphrey et al. (1996a), in the static focus is on the volume of transactions, there is a negative
specification, it is found that ATM terminals per person relationship between cash and cards, whereas the two pay-
affect the volume of cheque transactions positively and ment instruments are positively related if the focus is on
significantly (column 6). Like in the case of cards, the coef- their value. This may suggest that although cash and cards
ficient on the interest rate variable is never statistically sig- can both be categorized as retail instruments, cards cannot

24
Also Humphrey et al. (1996a) found a strong habit component in their regression for cheques.
25
Humphrey et al. (1996a) only found a negative association between lagged credit card transactions and the volume of current cheque
transactions in their static specification.
Determinants of the value and volume of noncash transactions 301
completely substitute for cash in terms of the value of Drehmann, M. and Goodhart, C. (2000) Is cash becoming tech-
transactions because there exists a minimum threshold nologically outmoded? Or does it remain necessary to facil-
itate ‘bad behaviour’? An empirical investigation into the
value for which a transaction can be undertaken by card. determination of cash holdings, Financial Market Group
Fifth, a negative relationship was found between the value Discussion Paper No. 0358, London School of Economics.
of cheque transactions and that of card transactions, indi- Drehmann, M., Goodhart, C. and Krueger, M. (2002) The chal-
cating that the two payment instruments can be seen as lenges facing currency usage: will the traditional transactions
substitutes. A similar, but generally weaker relationship medium be able to resist competition from the new technol-
ogies?, Economic Policy, 17(34), 193–227.
was observed for the volume of the same transactions. European Central Bank/European Monetary Institute (1993,
Furthermore, focusing on the volume of transactions, 1996, 1999) Payment Systems in the European Union,
cards seem to substitute for cash more than for cheques. Frankfurt.
In summary, the estimation results generally showed a Hancock, D. and Humphrey, D. (1998) Payment transactions,
distinct difference in the nature of the determinants of the instruments and systems: a survey, Journal of Banking and
Finance, 21, 1573–624.
value and volume of transactions in various noncash pay- Humphrey, D. (2002) US cash and card payments over 25 years,
ment instruments, with cost factors being the main deter- presented in Research/Payment Cards Center Conference:
minants of the value of transactions, and past habits and Innovation in Financial Services and Payments, Federal
adequate infrastructures being important in terms of Reserve Bank of Philadephia, 16 May.
volume of transactions. Humphrey, D., Pulley, L. and Vesala, J. (1996a) Cash, paper and
electronic payments: a cross-country analysis, Journal of
These results are important because, by providing an Money, Credit and Banking, 28(4), 914–37.
indication of what the determinants of various noncash Humphrey, D., Pulley, L. and Vesala, J. (2000) The check’s in the
payment instruments are, they can give guidance for devel- mail: why the United States lags in the adoption of cost-
oping and emerging market economies on how to achieve a saving electronic payments, Journal of Financial Services
payment system compatible with the infrastructure neces- Research, 17(1), 17–39.
Humphrey, D., Sato, S., Tsurumi, M. and Vesala, J. (1996b) The
sary to achieve sustained growth (Humphrey et al., 1996b). evolution of payments in Europe, Japan, and the United
Because of the significant differences noted in the deter- States: lessons for emerging market economies, World Bank
minants of the value and volume of the transactions con- Policy Research Working Paper No. 1676.
ducted in various noncash payment instruments, these International Monetary Fund (2000) International Financial
countries will have to first establish what they think their Statistics Yearbook 1999.
Johnston, R. (1984) The demand for non-interest bearing money
‘optimal’ payment system is, either in terms of volume or in in the UK, Government Economic Services Working Paper
terms of value of transactions, and then to manipulate the No. 66 (Treasury Working Paper No. 28).
relevant technological, institutional, and macro-monetary McAndrews, J. (1997) Network issues and payments systems,
variables necessary to achieve this system. Defining the Business Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadephia,
‘optimal’ payment system for a country is, however, a December, 15–25.
Nickell, S. (1981) Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects,
difficult task, which is beyond the scope of this paper. Econometrica, 49, 1417–426.
Rogoff, K. (1998) Blessing or curse? Foreign and underground
demand for euro notes, Economic Policy, 13(26), 261–303.
A C K NO WL E D G E M E N T S Snellman, J., Vesala, J. and Humphrey, D. (2000) Substitution of
noncash payment instruments for cash in Europe, Bank of
We wish to thank P. Mizen and an anonymous referee for Finland Discussion Paper No. 1/2000.
useful comments and suggestions. Snellman, J., Vesala, J. and Humphrey, D. (2001) Substitution of
noncash payment instruments for cash in Europe, Journal of
Financial Services Research, 19(2), 131–45.
REFERENCES Trundle, J. (1982) Recent changes in the use of cash, Bank of
Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1991) Another look at the instrumen- England Quarterly Bulletin, December, 519–29.
tal variable estimation of error-component models, Journal
of Econometrics, 68, 29–51.
Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1998) Dynamic panel data estimation
APPENDIX
using DPD98 for Gauss: a guide for users, mimeo, Institute
for Fiscal Studies, London.
Bank for International Settlements (1993, 1996, 1999) Statistics on Table A1 presents the estimates of the coefficients of the
Payment Systems in the Group of Ten Countries, Basle. country dummies relative to the static specification for the
Boeschoten, W. (1992) Currency use and payment pattern, in volume and the value of each of the three noncash pay-
Financial and Monetary Policy Studies, Vol. 23, Kluwer
Academic Publishers, Norwell, MA. ment instruments that have been considered.26 The

26
Only static estimates undertaken using the Within Groups estimator are presented because the GMM specifications do not provide
estimates of the country-specific component of the error term, which gets cancelled out through the first-differencing process. The
estimates of the country-specific effects are not reported for the dynamic Within Groups specifications because, as explained above,
these specifications are likely to suffer from the Nickell (1981) bias. The estimates are however available from the authors upon request.
302 A. Guariglia and Y. J. Loke
Table A1. Country-specific effects in the use of noncash payment instrument

Card transactions per person Direct debit transactions per person Cheque transactions per person
Countries Value Volume Value Volume Value Volume
Canada 2.725*** 2.445*** 0.135 1.593*** 3.917*** 2.589***
(5.70) (4.43) (0.18) (3.75) (18.96) (5.07)
Switzerland 0.267 1.503** 3.487*** 3.127*** 2.442*** 1.085*
(0.58) (2.58) (6.40) (8.87) (9.59) (1.84)
USA 2.756*** 3.508*** 1.016* 2.303*** 2.799*** 4.122***
(9.57) (5.36) (1.94) (4.50) (17.31) (7.25)
Austria 0.369* 0.922*** 1.519*** 0.705*** 1.386*** 0.409*
(1.67) (4.32) (5.18) (4.34) (12.34) (1.78)
Belgium 0.952*** 1.826*** 1.408*** 1.603*** 0.983*** 1.176***
(4.30) (5.03) (4.83) (5.79) (6.11) (2.85)
Denmark 2.129*** 2.529*** 2.888*** 1.122*** 1.908*** 2.017***
(5.65) (5.57) (6.14) (2.91) (6.87) (4.12)
Spain 1.183*** 0.440 0.050 1.000*** 0.482*** 0.345
(5.74) (1.47) (0.15) (4.45) (2.95) (1.14)
Finland 1.936*** 1.227* 3.025*** 2.632*** 1.800*** 1.589**
(4.29) (1.86) (5.23) (6.10) (5.54) (2.50)
France 1.202*** 2.033*** 0.156 0.491 1.520*** 2.872***
(4.33) (4.15) (0.37) (1.19) (8.43) (7.24)
Italy 0.577*** 0.378 0.701*** 3.407*** 0.039 0.684
(3.18) (0.69) (2.70) (19.72) (0.28) (1.29)
Netherlands 1.206*** 1.792*** 1.358** 0.333 3.602*** 0.428
(2.79) (8.75) (2.10) (1.57) (30.45) (1.54)
Portugal 0.849** 1.131* 2.240*** 2.424*** 1.344*** 1.838***
(2.07) (1.78) (4.27) (6.21) (4.66) (3.10)
Sweden 0.597** 1.205*** 2.666*** 2.220*** 0.640*** 0.149
(1.96) (2.94) (9.11) (9.62) (3.04) (0.34)
UK 1.807*** 1.796*** 0.337 0.756* 2.144*** 2.361***
(4.61) (3.28) (0.57) (1.76) (8.70) (4.85)

Note: The coefficients reported in this Table are those associated with the country-specific dummies obtained by estimating the static
models for the value and volume of card, direct debit, and cheque transactions per person. The dummy variable relative to Germany was
omitted from all the specifications, so the coefficients in this table have to be interpreted relative to Germany. T-statistics are reported in
parentheses. *indicates significance at the 10% level. **indicates significance at the 5% level. ***indicates significance at the 1% level.

country-specific dummies absorb differences in the per The countries making a lower relative use of cards appear
person payment instrument use not accounted for by the to be the Netherlands and Spain in terms of transactions
other regressors, relative to Germany.27 In all specifica- value, and Austria, in terms of volume.
tions, it appears that most of the country-specific dummies Columns 3 and 4 refer to direct debits. In terms of value
are precisely determined. This confirms the importance of of transactions, Switzerland and Finland make the highest
taking unobserved country-specific heterogeneity into relative use of direct debits. In terms of volume of transac-
account. tions, the coefficients on most country-specific dummies are
Columns 1 and 2 of Table A1 refer to the value and negative, suggesting that most countries make a lower rela-
volume of per capita card transactions, respectively. It tive use of direct debits compared to Germany. It is inter-
can be seen that Canada and the USA make a very high esting to note that Switzerland ranked highest on the scale
relative use of cards, both in terms of value and in terms of for the value of direct debit transactions, whereas it ranks
volume. Although in the USA, only about 20% of noncash fairly low on the scale relative to the volume of transac-
transactions are electronic, the country still ranks very high tions. This suggests that relatively few high-value direct
in terms of value and volume of card transactions essen- debit transactions are made in this country. In general
tially because it is characterized by many more noncash terms, the strong differences in the coefficients of the coun-
transactions than other countries (see Humphrey et al., try dummies in columns 3 and 4 confirms once again the
1996b). Denmark also ranks high in terms of card transac- importance of looking at the two types of transactions
tions value, whereas France ranks high in terms of volume. separately.

27
The dummy relative to Germany is in fact omitted. Examples of differences in the per person payment instruments use not accounted
for by other regressors could be due to cultural factors, crime rates, banking concentration, etc.
Determinants of the value and volume of noncash transactions 303
Columns 5 and 6 refer to the value and volume of instance, costs by banks that are sunk in cheque proces-
cheque transactions. The USA and Canada rank high in sing arrangements, a highly unconcentrated banking sys-
both columns, suggesting that these two countries make a tem, and strong antitrust laws also explain why the USA
very high relative use of cheques.28 As explained in and Canada rely so much on cheques. In terms of the
Humphrey et al. (2000), in the USA, this is due, among value of cheque transactions, the Netherlands and
other things, to the lack of a strong price incentive to Switzerland appear to make a lower relative use of che-
demand and use lower-cost electronic payment instru- ques, whereas Switzerland and Finland seem to make a
ments and to the benefit of obtaining cheque float versus lower relative use of cheques if the volume of transactions
an immediate debit to a transaction account that occurs is focused on.29
with a debit card or a direct debit. Other factors, like for

28
Humphrey et al. (2000) document that in the USA, cheques account for 75% of all noncash payments.
29
Time dummies were also added to the regression and in most cases, the relevant coefficients did not suggest any significant difference
across the years analysed. However, there was a notable exception for the volume and value of cheque transactions, which showed a
significant downward trend. This is consistent with the gradual shift towards paperless processes and the substitution away from cheques
towards electronic payment instruments, which has been observed in the literature (see Humphrey et al., 1996a, 1996b). In line with this
conclusion, the analysis of the coefficients associated with the time dummies also suggested an increase in the volume of direct debits over
the period considered.

You might also like