You are on page 1of 22

Journal of Economic Literature

Vol. XXXIV (June 1996), pp. 647–668

Rogoff: The Purchasing Power


Journal of Economic Parity
Literature, Vol. XXXIVPuzzle
(June 1996)

The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle


KENNETH ROGOFF
Princeton University

I am grateful to Rudiger Dornbusch, Hali Edison, John Rogers, Susanne Trimbath, and to
three anonymous referees for constructive suggestions on an earlier draft, and to Brian Doyle
and Giovanni Olivei for excellent research assistance. The National Science Foundation and
the Bradley Foundation provided research support.

I. Introduction (nominal exchange rates adjusted for dif-


ferences in national price levels) tend to-

F IRST ARTICULATED by scholars of the


Salamanca school in sixteenth cen-
tury Spain,1 purchasing power parity
ward purchasing power parity in the very
long run. Consensus estimates suggest,
however, that the speed of convergence
(PPP) is the disarmingly simple empiri- to PPP is extremely slow; deviations ap-
cal proposition that, once converted to a pear to damp out at a rate of roughly 15
common currency, national price levels percent per year. Second, short-run de-
should be equal. The basic idea is that if viations from PPP are large and volatile.
goods market arbitrage enforces broad Indeed, the one-month conditional vola-
parity in prices across a sufficient range tility of real exchange rates (the volatility
of individual goods (the law of one of deviations from PPP) is of the same
price), then there should also be a high order of magnitude as the conditional
correlation in aggregate price levels. volatility of nominal exchange rates.
While few empirically literate econo- Price differential volatility is surprisingly
mists take PPP seriously as a short-term large even when one confines attention
proposition, most instinctively believe in to relatively homogenous classes of
some variant of purchasing power parity highly traded goods.
as an anchor for long-run real exchange The purchasing power parity puzzle
rates. Warm, fuzzy feelings about PPP then is this: How can one reconcile the
are not, of course, a substitute for hard enormous short-term volatility of real ex-
evidence. change rates with the extremely slow
There is today an enormous and ever- rate at which shocks appear to damp
growing empirical literature on PPP, one out? Most explanations of short-term ex-
that has arrived at a surprising degree of change rate volatility point to financial
consensus on a couple of basic facts. factors such as changes in portfolio pref-
First, at long last, a number of recent erences, short-term asset price bubbles,
studies have weighed in with fairly per- and monetary shocks (see, for example,
suasive evidence that real exchange rates Maurice Obstfeld and Rogoff forthcom-
1 See Lawrence H. Officer (1982, ch. 3) for an
ing). Such shocks can have substantial ef-
extensive discussion of the origins of PPP theory; fects on the real economy in the pres-
see also Dornbusch (1987). ence of sticky nominal wages and prices.
647
648 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV (June 1996)

Consensus estimates for the rate at countries relative to poor ones. I also
which PPP deviations damp, however, consider differentials in government
suggest a half-life of three to five years, spending and current account imbal-
seemingly far too long to be explained by ances as variables that affect medium- to
nominal rigidities. It is not difficult to long-term deviations from PPP. Section
rationalize slow adjustment if real 7 discusses some recent vector autore-
shocks—shocks to tastes and technol- gression work that aims to decompose
ogy—are predominant. But existing the shocks underlying real exchange rate
models based on real shocks cannot ac- changes.
count for short-term exchange rate vola- In the final, concluding, section, I ar-
tility. gue that it is difficult to explain the vola-
Section 2 gives a brief account of the tility and persistence of PPP deviations
purchasing power parity doctrine’s em- without recognizing that international
pirical origins. In Section 3, I consider goods markets are not yet nearly as
some of the various ways in which PPP highly integrated as domestic goods mar-
can be construed; the alternative ap- kets.
proaches to defining PPP bring out many
of the main issues and problems underly- 2. Gustav Cassel and the Birth of PPP
ing testing and implementation. Section as an Empirical Tool
4 looks at the startling empirical failure
of the law of one price, a central building The modern origins of purchasing
block of PPP that posits that similar power parity trace to the debate on how
goods should sell for similar prices across to restore the world financial system af-
countries. Most economists recognize ter its collapse during World War I.
that there are frequent violations of the Prior to war, most countries adhered to
law of one price, but those not familiar the gold standard, in which their curren-
with recent research will probably be cies were convertible to gold at fixed
stunned by the pervasiveness of the dis- parities. The exchange rate between two
parities. Indeed, some recent studies currencies then simply reflected their
have shown that price differentials across relative gold values. After the outbreak
countries for very similar consumer of World War I, however, maintaining
goods are typically more volatile than the gold standard became impossible as
price differentials within a country for speculators became justifiably concerned
very dissimilar goods. that countries would devalue their cur-
Section 5 looks at a spate of recent rencies in an effort to gain seignorage
studies that have finally relieved re- revenues; the gold standard was quickly
searchers of the embarrassment of not abandoned. When the war ended, coun-
being able to reject the random walk tries faced the very real problem of de-
model for real exchange rates. Section 6 ciding how to reset exchange rates with
looks at some modifications to purchas- minimal disruption to prices and govern-
ing power parity that are often used in ment finances. Simply returning to pre-
practice and asks under what circum- war exchange rates made no sense be-
stances they provide a better model of cause the various belligerents had such
the long-run real exchange rate. This vastly differing inflation experiences dur-
section includes evidence on Bela ing the war.
Balassa’s (1964) and Paul Samuelson’s In a series of influential articles, the
(1964) hypothesis that prices for non- Swedish economist Gustav Cassel (1921,
traded goods tend to be high in rich 1922) promoted the use of PPP as a
Rogoff: The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle 649

means for setting relative gold parities. law of one price states that for any
Basically, he proposed calculating cumu- good i:
lative CPI inflation rates from the begin-
ning of 1914 and using these inflation P i = EP∗i (1)
differentials to calculate the exchange
rate changes needed to maintain PPP. where Pi is the domestic-currency price
Though purchasing power parity had of good i, P∗i is the foreign currency
been discussed previously by classical price, and E is the exchange rate, de-
economists such as John Stuart Mill, Vis- fined as the home-currency price of for-
count Goschen, Alfred Marshall, and eign currency. Simply put, LOP states
Ludwig von Mises, Cassel was really the that once prices are converted to a com-
first to treat PPP as a practical empirical mon currency, the same good should sell
theory. Cassel’s writings were quite in- for the same price in different countries.
fluential and PPP calculations played an Needless to say, the law of one price
important role in the debate over Brit- holds mainly in the breach. Tariffs,
ain’s much-criticized decision to try to transportation costs, and nontariff barri-
restore its prewar mint parity with the ers drive a wedge between prices in dif-
dollar in 1925; see John Maynard Keynes ferent countries with the size of the
(1932) and Officer (1976a). wedge depending on the tradability of
Today, various versions of purchasing the good.
power parity are used in a wide range Consider, for example, McDonald’s
of applications: from choosing the right “Big Mac” Hamburgers, which clearly do
initial exchange rate for a newly in- not transport very well in their final
dependent country, to forecasting form. True, some components of Big
medium- and long-term real exchange Macs, such as the frozen beef patty and
rates, to trying to adjust for price differ- special sauce ingredients, are highly
entials in international comparisons of traded. On the other hand, restaurant
income. space and local labor inputs needed to
cook and serve the burgers are essen-
tially nontraded. As Table 1 illustrates,
3. Variants of PPP Big Mac prices are widely disparate
Before proceeding any further, it is
useful to review some of the alternative TABLE 1
RELATIVE PRICES OF BIG MACS
variations of PPP that are used in prac-
ACROSS SELECTED COUNTRIES
tice. Though the technical minutiae of
PPP definitions may seem mundane, Country Price of Big Mac (in Dollars)
they in fact are central to many of the
Switzerland 5.20
practical questions surrounding imple- Denmark 4.92
mentation of purchasing power parity. Japan 4.65
Ultimately, there is no “right” PPP mea- Belgium 3.84
sure; the appropriate variation of PPP Germany 3.48
depends on the application. United States 2.32
Canada 1.99
Russia 1.62
A. The Law of One Price Hong Kong 1.23
China 1.05
The basic building block for any vari-
ation of purchasing power parity is the Source: The Economist, Apr. 15, 1995
so-called “law of one price” (LOP). The
650 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV (June 1996)

TABLE 2
measure of international price differen-
THE LAW OF ONE PRICE FOR GOLD tials; purchasing power parity measures
are designed to provide this. Absolute
Dollar Price (CPI) purchasing power parity requires:
Country of One Troy Ounce
Hong Kong (late) 379.35 ΣP i = EΣP∗i (2)
London (late) 379.25
Paris (afternoon) 378.81 where the sums are taken over a con-
Frankfurt (fixing) 378.87 sumer price index. An obvious question
Zurich (late afternoon) 379.10 is which consumer price index: home or
New York 379.10 foreign? Purchasing power parity com-
parisons raise all the usual kinds of index
Source: The New York Times, Feb. 24, 1995 number problems one faces when mak-
ing comparisons across different coun-
tries. With time series data, the prob-
lems are exacerbated as one must worry
across countries, with prices ranging about how to handle the introduction of
from $5.20 in Switzerland at the high new goods, shifting consumption weights
end to $1.05 in China at the low end. within a country, etc.
There are, of course, a number of The biggest problem with trying to im-
other reasons for Big Mac price differen- plement absolute purchasing power par-
tials besides nontradable inputs. Some ity, however, is that very little data is
countries’ prices include value-added available for measuring it. First, govern-
taxes, whereas others do not. Profit mar- ments do not construct indices for an in-
gins may differ across locations depend- ternationally standardized basket of
ing on competition. Finally, cognoscenti goods. Although the U.S. and German
will know that there are subtle interna- consumer price index and producer price
tional differences in how Big Macs are index are conceptually quite similar, they
bundled. In the United States and Can- are still constructed somewhat differ-
ada, ketchup for the hamburger is free, ently and the basket weights are not the
but in Italy and Holland, it costs roughly same in any event. Second, government
fifty cents extra; the choice of milk shake price data comes in the form of indices
flavors to accompany the meal also dif- relative to a base year, say 1990 equals
fers regionally. 100. Because the indices give no indica-
For some highly traded commodities, tion of how large absolute PPP devia-
the law of one price does hold very well, tions were for the base year, one must
as Table 2 illustrates for the case of gold. either assume that absolute PPP held on
As we shall see later, however, commodi- average over some base period (as
ties where the deviations from the law of Cassel, 1921, recommended), or else
one price damp out very quickly are the limit attention to relative (CPI) PPP,
exception rather than the rule. which requires that:
B. Absolute and Relative Purchasing ΣPit /ΣPit−1 = (Et/Et−1)(ΣP ∗it /ΣP∗it−1 ) (3)
Power Parity
where t subscripts denote time. Relative
Big Mac price deviations and gold PPP requires only that the rate of growth
price arbitrage are interesting and enter- in the exchange rate offset the differen-
taining. Policy makers and practitioners tial between the rate of growth in home
typically, however, require a broader and foreign price indices. Interpreting
Rogoff: The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle 651
1.7

1.35
(log) real exhange rate

0.65
1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995
Figure 1. Mexican Peso/U.S.$ CPI real exchange rate, Jan. 1984–May 1995
Source: International Financial Statistics

deviations of relative PPP can be very Gilbert and Irving Kravis (1954), for ex-
difficult. For example, during the early ample, developed price level measures
1990s, Mexico’s real exchange rate ap- for common baskets of goods across the
preciated sharply, as illustrated in Figure U.S., U.K., France, Germany, and Italy;
1. Should investors and policy makers see also Gilbert and Associates (1958).
have concluded already by the early In recent years, the endeavor to develop
1990s that the peso was overvalued and absolute PPP measures has culminated
thus anticipated its end-1994 collapse? in the influential research of Robert
Not necessarily. During the debt crisis of Summers and Alan Heston (1991), who
the mid-1980s, the real value of the peso together with colleagues have con-
had plummeted. As one can see from the structed estimates covering a much
diagram, with only relative PPP mea- broader range of years and countries. We
sures, one’s assessment of the overvalu- will present some results from their “In-
ation of the peso is very sensitive to the ternational Comparison Programme”
base year chosen for comparison. (ICP) data set later on. Unfortunately,
available absolute PPP measures such as
C. Indices for Measuring Absolute PPP
the ICP data set still have a number of
Economists have long recognized the limitations that make it impossible for
problems with government price indices them to fully supplant standard govern-
in making purchasing power parity com- ment indices in empirical and policy re-
parisons, and since the early 1950s, there search. The main problem is that ICP
have been a number of attempts to con- data are gathered infrequently (bench-
struct measures of absolute PPP. Milton mark surveys are available only at five-
652 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV (June 1996)

year intervals beginning in 1970) and relatively sophisticated manufacturing


country coverage is limited (the number goods, but even in “commodity manufac-
of benchmark countries rose from 16 in tures” such as screws, nuts, and bolts.
1970 to 56 in 1985.) For non-benchmark Corroborating Isard’s and Richardson’s
years and countries, data is filled in results, he finds that LOP deviations are
largely by extrapolation. There is also a highly correlated with exchange rate
long lag between the time the data is movements.
gathered and the time it can be made Perhaps the most convincing evidence
widely available. Monthly government of this type is provided by Michael M.
price indices are, of course, generally Knetter (1989, 1993), who looks at 7-
available on a much more timely basis.2 digit export unit values from a single
source to multiple destinations. He
4. Empirical Evidence on the Law of finds, for example, large volatile differ-
One Price entials in the price of German beer
shipped to the United States as opposed
Study after study has found that devia-
to the United Kingdom.
tions from the law of one price are re-
markably volatile across a surprisingly A. International versus Intra-national
broad range of goods. Generally speak- Price Volatility
ing, relative nominal prices are far less
A skeptic might point out that one can
volatile than exchange rates. Among the
find price differentials for basic goods at
early studies to document the size and
neighboring supermarkets, or even at
volatility of LOP deviations across seem-
different stalls in the same market place.
ingly highly traded goods were Peter Is-
Maybe the large and volatile price differ-
ard (1977) and J. David Richardson
entials one observes across countries are
(1978). Isard examined disaggregated
no different than one would observe
data (including transactions price data)
across cities within the same country. A
on U.S., German, Canadian, and Japa-
recent study by Charles Engel and Ro-
nese exports for a range of highly traded
gers (1995), however, shows convincingly
goods, such as apparel, industrial chemi-
that this is not the case. 3 They examine
cals, paper, and glass products. He found
data on 14 categories of disaggregated
that deviations from the law of one price
consumer price indices for 23 cities in
are large, persistent, and to a significant
the United States and Canada. Within a
extent simply reflect nominal exchange
country, the relative price of the same
rate movements. Richardson, looking at
good across two cities does appear to be
4- and 7-digit SIC (standard industrial
a function of the distance between them.
classification) categories finds some evi-
But even after controlling for distance,
dence of commodity price arbitrage be-
there remains a dramatic difference in
tween the United States and Canada, but
relative price volatility when one com-
the arbitrage is far from perfect. Using
pares two cities on opposite sides of the
an even more disaggregated data set on
border versus two cities on the same side
transactions prices for the United States
of the border. The “border” effect on
and Japan, Alberto Giovannini (1988)
relative price volatility is equivalent to
finds sharp price differentials not only in
adding anywhere between 2,500 to
2 In principle, it should be possible to combine 23,000 miles between cities, depending
the use of absolute and relative PPP measures to
obtain more up-to-date measures of absolute PPP 3 For earlier work on comparisons of price dif-
deviations but this issue has not yet been exam- ferentials across cities and countries, see Commis-
ined systematically. sion of the European Communities (1990).
Rogoff: The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle 653

on the specification. Rogers and Michael must not rely too heavily on institutional
A. Jenkins (1995) find that not only are factors peculiar to the twentieth cen-
relative price differentials for similar tury.
goods more volatile across borders, they
C. Possible Frictions: Transportation
are also more persistent.
Costs, Tariffs, Nontariff Barriers,
Just how volatile are deviations from
Pricing to Market
the law of one price compared to the
general variability of relative prices How is it possible that goods market
within the economy? Engel (1993) offers arbitrage does not force closer conver-
a dramatic comparison. Looking at data gence of international prices? One small
for the U.S. and Canada, Engel con- part of the answer, of course, is that
structs one-month conditional variances transportation costs permit some wedge
for relative prices of a large number of between domestic and foreign prices.4
similar goods (such as apples, men’s A crude estimate of international ship-
clothing, fuel) across borders, and com- ping costs can be obtained by comparing
pares them with the volatility of relative the value of world exports exclusive of
prices of dissimilar goods within a coun- transportation and insurance costs (the
try’s border. (He separates anticipated “fob” value) with the value of world im-
from unanticipated price movements us- ports inclusive of transportation and in-
ing simple autoregressions to proxy price surance (the “cif” value). In the Interna-
expectations.) Strikingly, Engel finds tional Monetary Fund’s Direction of
that with few exceptions in over 2,000 Trade Statistics (Dec. 1994), this differ-
pairwise comparisons, the relative prices ence is estimated to be approximately 10
of very similar goods across the U.S. and percent with of, course, large variations
Canada are much more volatile than the across countries. A second factor is that
relative prices of very different goods many goods thought of as being highly
within either country. traded in fact contain significant non-
traded components. This is true particu-
B. The Volatility of Law of One Price
larly at the consumer price level. Ba-
Deviations in the 20th Century
nanas in the supermarket embody not
Versus Earlier Ones
only traded bananas, but also imputed
A historical perspective on the volatil- rent (on the building), local shipping
ity of international price deviations is of- costs, labor in the supermarket, taxes,
fered by Kenneth A. Froot, Michael and insurance. Even at the wholesale
Kim, and Rogoff (1995), who look at an- level, bananas delivered on the dock may
nual data on prices for grains and dairy contain a large labor and insurance com-
products in Holland and England over a ponent.
period spanning the fourteenth through Obviously, tariffs can create deviations
the twentieth centuries. We find that from PPP, though world tariff levels
the volatility of deviations from the law have been falling steadily over the last
of one price, even among highly traded several decades. In addition to tariff
goods such as grains, has been remark- wedges, one must also consider nontariff
ably stable over the centuries. This re- barriers. For example, some countries
sult appears to be quite robust to the impose strict inspection requirements on
choice of detrending methods and to
how one controls for the effects of 4 For a discussion of the effects of transporta-
plagues and wars. It would thus appear tion costs on trade, see Jeffrey A. Frankel, Ernesto
that any explanation of the PPP puzzle Stern, and Shang-Jin Wei (1995).
654 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV (June 1996)

food imports. These requirements can trage has only a limited effect on equat-
add large spoilage costs to fruit and ing international goods market prices.
vegetable shippers when they are forced
to spend days waiting for their goods to 5. Long-run Convergence to PPP
be inspected. Knetter (1994) has argued
that nontariff barriers are quite impor- Given the abject failure of the law of
tant empirically in explaining deviations one price in microeconomic data, it is lit-
from PPP. He presents evidence that tle wonder that tests based on aggregate
German exporters charge higher prices price indices overwhelmingly reject pur-
to Japan across a broad range of goods, chasing power parity as a short-run rela-
and argues that this is evidence that high tionship. Jacob A. Frenkel (1978) does
retail prices in Japan are due to high find some support for PPP on hyperinfla-
nontariff barriers rather than an ineffi- tion data, which is not surprising given
cient distribution system. With nontariff the overwhelming predominance of
barriers, exporters will charge higher monetary shocks in such environments.
prices on sales to Japan in order to cover But test after test has rejected purchas-
costs of surmounting the barriers, and to ing power parity for more stable mone-
gain some of the rents associated with tary environments; see, for example
limited supply. Frenkel (1981) or Krugman (1978).
There are also some classes of goods, Figure 2, which presents monthly
such as automobiles and many types of movements in the relative (log) CPI lev-
electronics, where international arbi- els of the U.S. and Germany together
trage is difficult or impossible. This may with the (log) DM/dollar exchange rate,
be due to differing national standards shows why. As the figure illustrates, the
(e.g., 220 volt lamps are not popular variance of floating nominal exchange
items in the U.S., and left-hand-side rates is an order of magnitude greater
drive cars are not popular in Japan.) than the variance of relative price indi-
Also, monopolistic firms can sometimes ces. (Very similar results obtain for pro-
limit international arbitrage of prices by ducer price indices.) Short-term nominal
refusing to provide warranty service in exchange rate movements are, of course,
one country for goods purchased in an- notoriously difficult to explain even ex
other. To the extent that prices cannot post; see for example, Richard Meese
be arbitraged, then of course producers and Rogoff (1983), and Frankel and An-
can price discriminate across the differ- drew Rose (1995a).
ent international markets. Paul Krugman The failure of short-run PPP can be
(1987) refers to such price discrimina- attributed in part to stickiness in nomi-
tion as “pricing to market.” Knetter nal prices; as financial and monetary
(1989, 1993), using German export data, shocks buffet the nominal exchange rate,
finds that pricing to market is important the real exchange rate also changes in
across a surprisingly large range of the short run. This is the essence of
goods; see also Kenneth Kasa (1992). Dornbush’s (1976) overshooting model
For surveys of the pricing to market lit- of nominal and real exchange rate vola-
erature, see Robert P. Feenstra (1995) tility. If this were the entire story, how-
and Froot and Rogoff (1995). ever, one would expect substantial con-
Overall, it is hard to read the empirical vergence to PPP over one to two years,
evidence without concluding that outside as wages and prices adjust to a shock. As
a fairly small range of various homoge- we shall see, the evidence suggests this is
nous goods, short-run international arbi- not the case.
Rogoff: The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle 655

1.1 In(CPIger/CPIu.s.)
exchange rates and price ratios

0.7

In(DM/U.S.$)

0.3
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
Figure 2. DM/U.S.$ exchange rate and ratio of German to U.S. CPIs, Jan. 1972–May 1995
Source: International Financial Statistics

A. The Embarrassing Resiliency run homogeneity between relative prices


of the Random Walk Model and exchange rates; see Janice Boucher
Breuer 1994.)
Indeed, for many years researchers
The difficulties researchers had in re-
found it difficult to reject the hypothesis
jecting a random walk model for PPP de-
that major-country real exchange rates
viations on modern floating rate data was
follow a random walk under floating ex-
something of an embarrassment. Every
change rate regimes. That is, they found
reasonable theoretical model suggests
it difficult to prove that there was any
that there should be at least some tem-
convergence toward PPP in the long
porary component to PPP deviations.
run.5 Early tests include Richard Roll
Even if there are short-term rigidities in
(1979), Michael Darby (1983), Michael
domestic nominal prices, for example,
Adler and Bruce Lehmann (1983), and
long-term monetary neutrality implies
Edison (1985). Later papers incorporat-
that any effects of money shocks on the
ing now standard unit root tests include
real exchange rate (the nominal ex-
John Huizinga (1987), and Meese and
change rate adjusted for price differen-
Rogoff (1988). Tests using cointegration
tials) should die out in the long run.6
methods on modern floating rate data
have also typically failed to reject the 6 Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995b) show that if
random walk hypothesis. (Cointegration monetary shocks have short-run real effects due to
methods relax the assumption of long- sticky prices, they may also lead to temporary cur-
rent account imbalances that have long-run effects
5 For a technical discussion of the literature on
on the real exchange rate. The long-run effects
testing long-run PPP, see Froot and Rogoff should, however, be smaller in magnitude than the
(1995). short-run effects.
656 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV (June 1996)

B. Tests Based on Long-horizon appeared, using a variety of different


Data Sets approaches (including variance ratios,
fractional integration, cointegration and
Frankel (1986, 1990) argued that the error-correction models). These long-
reason for failure to reject the random horizon data studies almost invariably
walk model of real exchange rates was a tend to find evidence of mean reversion
lack of power. He pointed out that if in real exchange rates. Niso Abuaf and
purchasing power parity deviations damp Phillipe Jorion (1990), for example, used
sufficiently slowly, then it may require 1901–1972 data for eight currencies, and
many decades of data for one to be able found strong rejections of the random
to reliably reject the existence of a unit walk model. Their estimates suggest a
root (a random walk component) in real half-life for PPP deviations of 3.3 years.
exchange rates. Therefore, Frankel con- Jack D. Glen (1992) finds similar results
cluded, one must look at longer data for nine bilateral rates over the years
sets. Employing annual data for the dol- 1900–1987. Further rejections of the
lar/pound exchange rate for the period random walk model include Francis X.
1869–1984, Frankel was able to reject Diebold, Steve Husted, and Mark Rush
the random walk hypothesis with stan- (1991), who looked at data from the gold
dard Dickey-Fuller tests (see David standard period, with data samples rang-
Dickey and Wayne Fuller 1979). His ing from 74 to 123 years. For exchange
point estimates yielded an estimated rate rates across the six countries in their
of decay for real exchange rate devia- sample, their findings suggest an average
tions of 14 percent per year, implying a half-life of 2.8 years. James R. Lothian
half-life for PPP deviations of 4.6 years. 7 and Mark P. Taylor tested the random
(That is, the expected number of years walk hypothesis on two centuries of data
for a PPP deviation to decay by 50 per- for the dollar-pound (1791–1990) and
cent is 4.6 years.) Edison (1987) looked the franc-pound (1803–1990) exchange
at dollar/pound data for the years 1890– rates. They find strong evidence of mean
1978 using an error-correction approach reversion in both rates with an estimated
and obtained slightly weaker rejections, half-life (for their full sample) of 4.7
possibly because her sample was slightly years for the dollar-pound and 2.5 years
shorter. Edison’s and Frankel’s papers, for the franc-pound rate. Another long-
which mixed fixed and floating rate data, horizon study is Yin-Wong Cheung and
corroborated earlier results on fixed rate Kon Lai (1994), who find evidence of
data given by Henry J. Galliot (1970), mean reversion for real (WPI) rates
Moon H. Lee (1976), and Milton Fried- across several countries for the period
man (1980). Galliot, for example, found 1900–1992.
evidence of convergence to PPP using The consensus among these studies on
data from eight countries across the the half-life of PPP deviations is remark-
years 1900–1967. These earlier papers, able (three to five years). Still, an obvi-
admittedly, did not incorporate modern ous caveat to the above results is that
unit root and error-correction methods they blend fixed and floating rate data.
for testing for random walks. As Michael Mussa (1986) forcefully dem-
During the 1990s, several more stud- onstrated, real exchange rates tend to be
ies of long-horizon PPP data sets have more volatile under floating than under
7 Frankel runs regressions of the form q t = ρ
fixed exchange rates, and the econo-
q t-1 + ε t where q is defined as the real exchange metric implications of mixing data from
rate. Thus his point estimate of annual data is .86. the two regimes is unclear. One interest-
Rogoff: The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle 657

ing response to this criticism is offered about four years, which is very much in
by Lothian and Taylor (forthcoming). line with estimates obtained in the long-
They show that if one uses a simple horizon data. Other recent studies that
Chow test on a first-order autoregressive obtain similar estimates of convergence
specification, one cannot reject the hy- include Robert P. Flood and Taylor
pothesis that rate of convergence to PPP (forthcoming) and Lothian (1994).
is the same before and after floating be- One possible criticism of these results
gan in 1973. Still, this is not ultimately as is that the findings of mean reversion
convincing as evidence from the floating tend to be much stronger when high in-
rate period itself.8 flation countries are included. Given the
predominance of monetary shocks in
C. Tests of Convergence to PPP based high inflation countries, the results may
on Cross-Country Data Sets exaggerate the extent of convergence to
PPP.
Aside from expanding the range of Wei and David C. Parsley (1995) ad-
years covered, the other way to enhance dress this problem by looking at post-
the power of unit root tests is to expand 1973 annual data for 14 OECD coun-
the range of countries being considered. tries. They focus, however, only on
An early example is Craig Hakkio (1984), “tradables.” Following Jose De Gregorio,
who jointly tests for a random walk in Giovannini, and Holger Wolf (1994),
four industrialized-country exchange they define a good as tradable if the ratio
rates against the dollar. Despite the en- of its exports to production, averaged
hanced power, Hakkio’s test still failed over all 14 countries, is at least 10 per-
to reject the random walk model. A spate cent. Wei and Parsely estimate half-lives
of recent work, however, has had more for deviations from PPP in the range of
success in finding mean reversion on 4.75 years for non-European Monetary
cross-section floating-rate data. Frankel System countries and 4.25 years for real
and Rose (1995b) examine a panel data exchange rates across EMS countries. In
set including annual data for the years addition, they find evidence of non-
1948–1992 for 150 countries. They are linearity in mean reversion: the rate of
able to reject the random walk model convergence to PPP is faster when initial
handily even using only post-1973 float- deviations are large.
ing data, provided a sufficiently broad Another potentially important problem
cross-section of the countries is in- with existing cross-sectional tests has
cluded. Interestingly, their results been raised by P. G. O’Connell (1996).
strongly suggest an estimated half-life O’Connell points out that the standard
for purchasing power parity deviations of practice of calculating all real rates
8 Froot and Rogoff (1995) raise the further ca- relative to the dollar can lead to cross-
veat that all the exchange rates used in the litera- sectional dependence in time series
ture are across pairs of countries which have had panel data. Adjusting for this problem
high incomes (relative to the rest of the world)
throughout the sample period. This raises the appears to make it more difficult to re-
question of whether PPP will hold across two ject the random walk null.
countries with sharply differing growth experi- Overall, while there are some limita-
ences; see the discussion of the Balassa-Samuelson
effect in Section 6 below. They present evidence tions to both the long-horizon and cross-
that the Argentine peso has fallen sharply in real section results on long-run convergence
terms against both the dollar and pound since the to PPP, the recent literature has reached
beginning of the twentieth century, and find that
one cannot reliably reject the random walk model a surprising degree of consensus: PPP
even over more than 70 years of data. deviations tend to damp out, but only at
658 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV (June 1996)

the slow rate of roughly 15 percent per than poor countries, but because rich
annum.9 In the next section, we try to countries are relatively more productive
reconcile this slow rate of convergence in the traded goods sector. Nontraded
with some alternative theories of the fac- goods tend to be more service intensive
tors driving exchange rate movements and there is thus less room for estab-
and governing long-run real exchange lishing technological superiority. Cer-
rates. tainly, if one looks at historical data
across most industrialized countries,
6. Modifications to PPP technological progress in service-inten-
sive goods (education, health, insurance,
It is clear from Figure 1 above that in etc.) has been slower than for manufac-
the short run, nominal exchange rate tures, which tend to be more traded; see,
movements lead to real exchange rate for example, William Baumol and Wil-
movements due to short-term nominal liam Bowen (1966).
price rigidities. Over the longer term, Consider how a rise in traded goods
however, deviations from purchasing productivity affects a small country’s
power parity must be accounted for by overall consumer price level. For the
real factors. In this section, I consider moment it is simplest to think of the case
three modifications to long-run PPP where the nominal exchange rate is
that have been advanced in the litera- fixed. The rise in productivity will have
ture. no effect on prices in the (assumed com-
petitive) traded goods sector, because
A. The Balassa-Samuelson Hypothesis the domestic price level is tied down by
The first and most important model of the world price level and the exchange
long-run deviations from PPP was ad- rate. Therefore, wages in the traded
vanced more than 30 years ago by goods sector must rise. But if there has
Balassa (1964) and Samuelson (1964). been no corresponding increase in pro-
They argued that empirically, when all ductivity in the nontraded sector then,
countries’ price levels are translated to to be able to match higher wages in
dollars at prevailing nominal exchange the production of tradables, nontraded
rates, rich countries tend to have higher goods producers must raise their prices.
price levels than poor countries. The rea- With one component of the CPI con-
son for this phenomenon, they conjec- stant and the other higher, the country’s
tured, is not simply that rich countries overall price level must rise. 10 Note that
have higher absolute productivity levels if the country were to experience an
equal rise in both traded and nontraded
9 In an entertaining paper, Robert Cumby
goods productivity, its wage rate would
(1993) tests for PPP convergence using 1987–1993
data on up to 25 countries for the Economist also rise but there would be no relative
magazine’s “Big Mac” index (therefore he is able price effect. Therefore, there would
to test for convergence to absolute PPP and not be no effect on the real exchange rate.
just relative PPP). Cumby not only rejects the
presence of unit roots, but he finds remarkably The reader can easily check that the
little persistence in the data, with only 30 percent same basic argument holds, for real vari-
of hamburger price deviations persisting from one ables, under flexible as well as fixed
year to the next. One possible factor is that
Cumby’s data includes some hyperinflation coun- rates.
tries (where PPP works best) and another is that
“peso” problems (infrequent discrete devalu- 10 See Rogoff (1992) for a theoretical exposition
ations) may lead to understated standard errors of the Balassa-Samuelson effect within the context
given the relatively short time span of the data set of a dynamic model; see also Obstfeld and Rogoff
(see Karen Lewis 1995). (forthcoming, ch. 4).
Rogoff: The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle 659

TABLE 3
ICP MEASURES OF ABSOLUTE PURCHASING POWER PARITY VERSUS
PER CAPITA GDP

Per Capita GDP Relative Price Level Relative


Country to the United States to the United States
United States 100 100
Canada 95.9 103.9
Germany 84.0 132.3
Japan 82.5 133.9
France 77.3 126.5
United Kingdom 71.3 110.5
Italy 69.8 125.6
Spain 54.0 108.2
Taiwan 47.1 74.9
Venezuala 30.2 37.5
Mexico 29.3 43.7
Brazil 21.3 68.6
Poland 21.0 36.8
Turkey 20.4 43.9
Thailand 19.3 34.4
Argentina 19.0 79.8
Columbia 17.3 34.0
South Africa 17.2 76.0
Algeria 13.0 74.7
China 12.5 11.9
Peru 11.2 70.0
Morocco 11.1 41.9
Indonesia 10.3 27.0
Philippines 9.6 34.3
Egypt 9.4 33.5
Pakistan 7.4 22.4
Bangladesh 6.5 15.4
India 5.8 26.7
Sudan 5.2 30.1
Kenya 5.0 33.6
Nigeria 3.9 36.7

Source: Penn World Tables, Mark 5.6; see Summers and Heston (1991) for a de-
scription of the data.

A related theory that also predicts that a higher capital-labor ratio, rich coun-
rich countries will have higher exchange- tries will have higher wage rates, pro-
rate adjusted price levels than poor vided initial endowment disparities are
countries is due to Kravis and Robert sufficiently large that factor price equal-
Lipsey (1983), and Jagdish Bhagwati ization does not obtain. Assuming then
(1984). Their theory depends on the as- that labor is relatively cheap in poor
sumption that capital-labor ratios are countries and that nontradables are labor
higher in rich countries (because of im- intensive, we again arrive at the result
perfect capital mobility) rather than the that when measured in a common cur-
assumption that rich countries are rela- rency, price levels will be higher in
tively more productive in tradables. With richer countries.
660 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV (June 1996)

1.8

Switzerland
1.6 Finland
Norway Sweden
Iceland Denmark
Gabon
1.4
Austria Japan Germany
Italy France Luxembourg
1.2 Ireland Netherlands Belgium
Price Level (U.S.=1)

Israel U.K.
Spain Canada
1 Australia
Singapore U.S.A.
Greece Cyprus
New Zealand
0.8
Taiwan
Portugal Hong Kong
0.6
Uruguay
Hungary
Trinidad and Tobago
0.4
Czechoslovakia

0.2 Syria

0
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
(GDP/Pop)j /(GDP/Pop)u.s.
Figure 3. Price Level versus GDP per capita (U.S. = 1) 1990 log(Pj /Pu.s.) = 0.035 + 0.366 log(Yj /Yu.s.)
(0.090) (0.042)
Source: The Penn World Table, Aug. 1994

B. The Mixed Evidence where P j/P U.S. is the price level of coun-
on the Balassa-Samuelson Effect try j relative to the United States, and
Yj/Y U.S. is country j’s relative income
How well does the Balassa-Samuelson level; standard errors are in parentheses.
model hold up empirically? In Table 3, Inspection of the figure also indicates
we list real incomes and price levels for that whereas the relationship between
selected countries from the ICP data set, income and prices is quite striking over
discussed in Section 3 above. Figure 3 the full data set, it is far less impressive
draws on the same data set. Each point when one looks either at the rich (in-
in the figure represents an individual dustrialized) countries as a group, or at
country’s real GDP and real price level developing countries as a group. Regres-
relative to the United States for the year sion evidence confirms this observa-
1990. It is clear from the figure that tion.11
there is a positive relationship between A related prediction of the Balassa-
country income and prices. A simple Samuelson model is that fast-growing
logarithmic regression over the 100 ob- countries will tend to see their real
servations yields exchange rates appreciate and vice
versa for slow-growing countries. Again,
log P j /P U.S. = 0.035
the logic is based on the assumption
(0.090)
11 For a more detailed test of the Balassa-Sa-
+ 0.366 logY j/YU.S. + uj; R 2 = 0.42 muelson model on the ICP data set, see Heston,
(0.042) Daniel A. Nuxoll, and Summers (1994).
Rogoff: The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle 661

–4.4

Yen/U.S.$ CPI based real exchange rate

–4.8

–5.2

–5.6

Yen/U.S.$ WPI based real exchange rate

–6
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
Figure 4. Yen/U.S.$ CPI and WPI based real exchange rates: Jan. 1960–Apr. 1995
Source: International Financial Statistics

that, empirically, the traded goods sec- and both CPIs exclude food costs.) Two
tor is the main locus for productivity further pieces of evidence support the
improvements in fast-growing coun- view that the appreciation of the real yen
tries.12 is due to an exceptionally large differen-
The canonical time series example of tial between productivity growth in the
the Balassa-Samuelson effect is Japan, traded and nontraded goods sectors. One
which has experienced the fastest overall is the divergence between the real CPI
per capita income growth of any major yen-dollar rate and the real WPI yen-
country since World War II. Figure 4 dollar rate. Ronald I. McKinnon (1970)
documents the sustained appreciation in argued that because WPIs contain a
Japan’s real exchange rate against the much higher proportion of traded goods
dollar, which holds whether one uses than CPIs (as also noted by Keynes
CPIs or WPIs. (For the U.S., the closely 1932), one would expect the Balassa-
related PPI is used in place of the WPI, Samuelson effect to be much more no-
ticeable when real exchange rates are
12 Officer (1976b) questions the basic empirical measured by CPIs rather than WPIs. As
premise that fast-growing countries generally ex- Figure 4 illustrates, this is indeed the
perience extra-rapid productivity growth in the
traded-goods sector. One might also ask whether case. Even more direct evidence is pro-
the effect, even if it has existed in the past, might vided by Richard C. Marston (1987),
be mitigated during the coming century, as tech- who calibrates a model of the real yen-
nological advances sharply improve productivity in
many service sectors such as banking and insur- dollar rate using disaggregated OECD
ance. data. He finds that sectoral productivity
662 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV (June 1996)

differentials can quantitatively explain disequilibrium dynamics but does not ex-
the trend rise in the yen. plicitly incorporate adjustment costs. Re-
Unfortunately, whereas the Balassa- solving the differences across these vari-
Samuelson effect seems to work quite ous recent studies will require further
well for the yen-dollar rate, it does not research.
appear to work as convincingly for other Finally, De Gregorio and Wolf (1994)
industrialized-country exchange rates. 13 attempt to decompose short-term real
Froot and Rogoff (1991), for example, do exchange rate movements into the com-
not find any significant effect for traded ponent caused by changes in the relative
growth differentials across EMS coun- price of nontraded goods (the Balassa-
tries for the years 1979–1990. Similar Samuelson effect), and changes in the
findings are obtained by Patrick Asea relative price of traded goods (changes
and Enrique Mendoza (1994), who apply in the terms of trade). They find that
a general equilibrium model to disaggre- terms of trade shifts account for a very
gated sectoral data for 14 OECD coun- substantial component of real exchange
tries over the years 1975–1990. Their rate movements, suggesting that if the
model incorporates adjustment costs to Balassa-Samuelson effect is important, it
moving factors across sectors. They find is only over longer-term horizons.
that the sectoral differences in produc- Overall, there is substantial empirical
tivity growth help explain the trend rise support for the Balassa-Samuelson hy-
in service prices within OECD countries, pothesis, especially in comparisons be-
but have much less power in explaining tween very poor and very rich countries,
the relative price of nontraded (versus and in time series data for a select num-
traded) goods across countries. ber of countries, including especially Ja-
However, in an interesting recent pa- pan. 14 Whether traded goods product-
per based on the same disaggregated ivity bias is of broader importance in
OECD data, De Gregorio, Giovannini, explaining real exchange rates across in-
and Wolf (1994) obtain results more sup- dustrialized countries remains a matter
portive of the Balassa-Samuelson effect of some debate. We have already seen
(see also De Gregorio, Giovannini, and that a substantial body of evidence sug-
Thomas Krueger 1994). They regress the gests that across industrialized countries
real exchange rate on productivity differ- there is long-run convergence to PPP,
entials across the traded and nontraded the Balassa-Samuelson effect notwith-
goods sectors, using a specification care- standing. Perhaps this is because over
fully derived from a small-country model long enough horizons technology dif-
with open capital markets and perfect fuses across borders.
factor mobility. Their model allows for
C. Cumulated Current Account Deficits
13 David Hsieh (1982) does find some evidence and Long-run Real Exchange Rate
in favor of the Balassa-Samuelson model using Depreciation
time series data for both Germany and Japan, as
does Obstfeld (1993). Hsieh’s results may be
somewhat sensitive to his inclusion of the real
Another popular empirical theory of
wage differential, which is closely correlated with the real exchange rate holds that sus-
the real exchange rate, as a right-hand-side vari-
14 Adjusting for the Balassa-Samuelson effect
able. For Norway and the United Kingdom,
Edison and Jan T. Klovland (1987) look at data for can lead to dramatic changes in real income rank-
the years 1874 to 1971 and find that output growth ings among countries, especially when one is com-
rates and terms of trade shocks (which they treat paring high per capita and low per capita income
as shocks to traded-goods productivity) are signifi- countries. See Summers and Heston (1991), for
cant factors in explaining deviations from PPP. example.
Rogoff: The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle 663

tained current account deficits are asso- dents are likely to exhibit very differ-
ciated with long-run real exchange rate ent spending patterns. Ultimately, the
depreciation. Empirically, there does ap- correlation between the current ac-
pear to be some correlation between count and exchange rate is an empirical
these two endogenous variables over five matter, one that remains a subject of
to ten year horizons. 15 Obstfeld and debate.
Rogoff (1995a), for example, show that
the simple correlation between trade- D. Government Spending and
weighted real exchange rate changes and the Real Exchange Rate
changes in net foreign asset positions
(including imputed capital gains and A third consideration that is some-
losses) is quite large and significant times emphasized in making adjustments
across 15 OECD countries for the years to purchasing power parity is the level of
1981–1990. Obviously, correlation does government spending. Froot and Rogoff
not imply causation. Using simulations of (1991) find that among EMS countries,
the IMF’s multi-country model (“MUL- government spending is a significant de-
TIMOD”), Tamim Bayoumi et al. (1994), terminant of the real exchange rate; De
find that the real exchange rate/current Gregorio, Giovannini, and Wolf (1994)
account correlation can be quite sensi- find similar results. Froot and Rogoff
tive to whether the driving factor is a fis- reason that this effect is observed be-
cal or monetary policy change. cause relative to private spending, gov-
Indeed, from a theoretical perspec- ernment spending tends to fall more
tive, virtually any correlation between heavily on nontraded goods. Therefore a
the current account and the real ex- rise in government spending leads to an
change rate can be easily rationalized. increase in the real exchange rate. As
For example, a temporary productivity Rogoff (1992) emphasizes, however, any
shock can easily improve a country’s cur- such effect must be transitory because
rent account (saving rises as current in- demand shocks can affect the real ex-
come exceeds permanent income) while change rate in a small country only to
causing a deterioration in a country’s the extent that capital and labor are not
terms of trade (by raising current supply perfectly mobile across sectors. Over the
of the home good). Moreover, there are long run, with complete factor mobility
many forces driving current account across sectors and with open capital
deficits besides real exchange rate markets, the real exchange rate is tied
changes; theoretically, it is possible to down by productivity and other supply
have significant borrowing and lending factors. Demand matters only for the
across countries even in a one-good quantities of goods produced. Alberto
world. Alesina and Roberto Perotti (1995) ob-
Recognizing this ambiguity, Krugman serve, however, that it is possible for fis-
(1990) nevertheless argues that current cal policy to have long-run real effects in
accounts are likely to induce significant a model where distortionary taxes are
real exchange rate changes because used to finance government spending
they lead to transfers of wealth across programs.
countries, and home and foreign resi- Overall, the three modifications to
PPP discussed thus far in this section are
15 An early example is Peter Hooper and John
useful in some circumstances but are not
Morton (1982), who posit that countries with sus-
tained current account deficits will see their ex- nearly robust or universal enough to fully
change rates depreciate. supplant purchasing power parity as a
664 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV (June 1996)

theory of the long-run real exchange account for roughly 45 percent of the
rate.16 forecast error variance for the dollar-DM
real rate over the modern floating rate
7. Estimates of Convergence Based on era, and 34 percent for the yen-dollar
Multivariate Vector Autoregression rate. Rogers, using 130 years of data
Models from the U.S. and the U.K., finds that
real shocks account for roughly half the
We have seen that PPP does not hold one-year forecast error in real rates.
in the short run and that convergence to This research is promising but still
PPP is extremely slow. This raises a puz- at an early stage. Clarida and Gali’s
zle as to the nature of the shocks driving finding of a unit root in the real ex-
real exchange rate changes. Most expla- change rate is not inconsistent with uni-
nations of short-term exchange rate vola- variate studies that look at post-1973
tility (e.g., the literature following Dorn- data for only one country. It is not clear
busch 1976) suggest a large role for that one would find unit roots using simi-
monetary and financial shocks. Real lar methods on longer-term data. Also, it
shocks to productivity and preferences, is difficult to justify identifying as a de-
the conventional thinking goes, cannot mand shift any shock with only a transi-
possibly be volatile enough to explain the tory effect on the real exchange rate,
immense short-term volatility of ex- especially if the effect is highly persis-
change rates. But if a significant fraction tent. Finally, both studies are based on
of total exchange rate volatility is caused the somewhat anachronistic Mundell-
by monetary and financial shocks, then Fleming-Dornbucsh IS-LM framework,
one would expect deviations to PPP to rather than a modern sticky-price in-
die out at a rate faster than 15 percent tertemporal model.
per year, because monetary shocks can
only have first-order real effects over a 8. Conclusions
time frame in which nominal wages and
prices are sticky. One approach to try to One can restate the purchasing power
addressing this puzzle (the PPP puzzle) parity puzzle as follows: How is it possi-
is to examine the results of multivariate ble to reconcile the extremely high
models containing the real exchange rate short-term volatility of real exchange
and other macro variables. Richard rates with the glacial rate (15 percent
Clarida and Jordi Gali (1994), and Rog- per year) at which deviations from PPP
ers (1995), both attempt to put bounds seem to die out? It would seem hard to
on the fraction of total real exchange explain the short-term volatility without
rate volatility that can be accounted for a dominant role for shocks to money and
monetary shocks. The key identifying as- financial markets. But given that such
sumption is that any effects monetary shocks should be largely neutral in the
variables may have on real exchange medium run, it is hard to see how this
rates must be purely temporary. Clarida explanation is consistent with a half-life
and Gali find that monetary shocks alone for PPP deviations of three to five years.
16 Feenstra and Jon P. Kendall (1994) argue
It is possible that a different picture of
that pricing to market factors may also be impor- the persistence of PPP deviations will
tant in governing long-run deviations from PPP. emerge from multivariate VAR models,
Because pricing to market is possible only when but thus far such models also suggest
goods market arbitrage is blocked, it seems more
likely to be an important factor in the short-to-me- very slow convergence.
dium run than in the long run. One is left with a conclusion that
Rogoff: The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle 665

would certainly make the godfather of CASSEL , GUSTAV . The world’s money problems.
New York: E.P. Dutton and Co., 1921.
purchasing power parity, Gustav Cassel, ———. Money and foreign exchange after 1914:
roll over in his grave. It is simply this: New York: MacMillan, 1922.
International goods markets, though be- CHEUNG , Y IN -WONG AND LAI , KON S. “Mean Re-
version in Real Exchange Rates,” Econ. Letters,
coming more integrated all the time, re- 1994, 46(3), pp. 251–56.
main quite segmented, with large trading CLARIDA , R ICHARD AND GALI , JORDI . “Sources
frictions across a broad range of goods. of Real Exchange-Rate Fluctuations: How Im-
portant Are Nominal Shocks?” Carnegie Roch-
These frictions may be due to transporta- ester Conf. Ser. Public Pol., Dec. 1994, 41, pp.
tion costs, threatened or actual tariffs, 1–56.
nontariff barriers, information costs, or COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES .
One Market, One Money, European Economy.
lack of labor mobility. As a consequence Special issue. Brussels: European Commission,
of various adjustment costs, there is a 1990.
large buffer within which nominal ex- CUMBY, R OBERT . “Forecasting Exchange Rates on
the Hamburger Standard: What You See is
change rates can move without produc- What You Get with McParity.” Mimeo. Stern
ing an immediate proportional response School of Business, 1993.
in relative domestic prices. International CUMBY, R OBERT AND H UIZINGA , J OHN . “The
Predictability of Real Exchange Rate Changes
goods markets are highly integrated, but in the Short and Long Run.” Nat. Bureau Econ.
not yet nearly as integrated as domestic Res. Working paper 3468, Oct. 1990.
goods markets. This is not an entirely D ARBY, M ICHAEL R. “Movements in Purchasing
Power Parity: The Short and Long Runs,” in
comfortable conclusion, but for now The international transmission of inflation.
there is no really satisfactory alternative Eds.: M ICHAEL R. DARBY AND J AMES R.
explanation to the purchasing power par- LOTHIAN ET AL . Chicago: U. of Chicago Press,
Chicago, 1983, pp. 462–77.
ity puzzle. DE GREGORIO , J OSE ; GIOVANNINI , ALBERTO
AND K RUEGER , T HOMAS H. “The Behavior of
REFERENCES
Nontradable Goods Prices in Europe: Evidence
ABUAF , N ISO AND JORION , PHILLIPE . “Purchasing and Interpretation,” Rev. Int. Econ., Oct. 1994,
Power Parity in the Long Run,” J. Finance, 2(3), pp. 284–305.
Mar. 1990, 45(1 ), pp. 157–74. D E GREGORIO , J OSE ; GIOVANNINI , ALBERTO
ADLER , M ICHAEL AND LEHMAN , B RUCE. “Devia- AND W OLF , H OLGER C. “International Evi-
tions from Purchasing Power Parity in the dence on Tradables and Nontradables Infla-
Long Run,” J. Finance, Dec. 1983, 38(5), pp. tion,” Europ. Econ. Rev., June 1994, 38(6),
147–87. 1225–44.
ALESINA , ALBERTO AND PEROTTI , R OBERTO . D E G REGORIO , J OSE AND WOLF , H OLGER .
“Taxation and Redistribution in an Open Econ- “Terms of Trade, Productivity, and the Real Ex-
omy,” Europ. Econ. Rev., May 1995, 39(5), pp. change Rate,” Nat. Bureau Econ. Res. Working
961–79. Paper No. 4807, July 1994.
ASEA , PATRICK K. AND M ENDOZA , ENRIQUE G. DICKEY , DAVID A. AND FULLER , WAYNE . “Distri-
“The Balassa-Samuelson Model: A General- bution of the Estimators for Autoregressive
Equilibrium Appraisal,” Rev. Int. Econ., Oct. Time Series with a Unit Root,” J. Amer. Statist.
1994, 2(3), pp. 244–67. Assoc., June 1979, 74(366), pp. 427–31.
BALASSA , B ELA . “The Purchasing Power Parity D IEBOLD , FRANCIS X.; HUSTED , S TEVE AND
Doctrine: A Reappraisal,” J. Polit. Econ., Dec. R USH , M ARK . “Real Exchange Rates under the
1964, 72(6), pp. 584–96. Gold Standard,” J. Polit. Econ., Dec. 1991,
BAUMOL , WILLIAM J. AND B OWEN , WILLIAM G. 99(6), 1252–71.
Performing arts: The economic dilemma. New D ORNBUSCH , R UDIGER. “Expectations and Ex-
York: The Twentieth Century Fund, 1966. change Rate Dynamics,” J. Polit. Econ., Dec.
BAYOUMI , T AMIM ET AL . “The Robustness of 1976, 84(6), pp. 1161–76.
Equilibrium Exchange Rate Calculations to Al- ———. “Purchasing Power Parity,” in: The new
ternative Assumptions and Methodologies,” in Palgrave: A dictionary of economics. Eds.:
J OHN WILLIAMSON , ed. 1994, pp. 19–59. J OHN EATWELL , M URRAY M ILGATE , AND PE-
BHAGWATI , J AGDISH . “Why Are Services Cheaper TER N EWMAN . London: MacMillan; New York:
in Poor Countries?” Econ. J., June 1984, Stockton Press, 1987, pp. 1075–85.
94(374), pp. 279–86. EDISON, HALI J. “Purchasing Power Parity: A
BREUER , JANICE BOUCHER . “An Assessment of Quantitative Reassessment of the 1920s Experi-
the Evidence on Purchasing Power Parity,” in ence,” J. Int. Money Finance, Sept. 1985, 4(3),
J OHN WILLIAMSON , ed. 1994, pp. 245–77. pp. 361–72.
666 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV (June 1996)
———. “Purchasing Power Parity in the Long FRIEDMAN, M ILTON. “Prices of Money and Goods
Run: A Test of the Dollar/Pound Exchange Across Frontiers: The Pound and the Dollar
Rate (1890–1978),” J. Money, Credit, Banking, over a Century,” The World Economy, Feb.
Aug. 1987, 19(3), pp. 376–87. 1980, 2(4), pp. 497–511.
EDISON, HALI J. AND KLOVLAND , JAN T. “A FROOT , KENNETH A. AND R OGOFF , KENNETH .
Quantitative Reassessment of the Purchasing “The EMS, the EMU, and the Transition to a
Power Parity Hypothesis: Evidence from Nor- Common Currency,” in National bureau of eco-
way and the United Kingdom,” J. Appl. Econo- nomic research macroeconomics annual. Eds.:
metrics, Oct. 1987, 2(4), pp. 309–33. S TANLEY FISCHER AND O LIVIER B LANCHARD .
ELLIOT , GRAHAM ; R OTHENBERG, T HOMAS AND Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1991, pp. 269–317.
S TOCK , JAMES . “Efficient Tests for an Autore- ———. “Perspectives on PPP and Long-Run Real
gressive Root,” Econometrica, forthcoming. Exchange Rates,” in GENE GROSSMAN AND
ENGEL , CHARLES . “Real Exchange Rates and KENNETH R OGOFF , eds. 1995.
Relative Prices? An Empirical Investigation,” J. FROOT , KENNETH A.; KIM , M ICHAEL AND R O-
Monet. Econ., Aug. 1993, 32(1), pp. 35–50. GOFF , K ENNETH . “The Law of One Price Over
ENGEL , CHARLES AND R OGERS , J OHN . “How 700 Years.” Nat. Bureau Econ. Res. Working
Wide is the Border?” Nat. Bureau Econ. Res. Paper 5132, May 1995.
Working Paper No. 4829, 1995. GAILLIOT , H ENRY J. “Purchasing Power Parity as
FEENSTRA , R OBERT C. “Estimating the Effects of an Explanation of Long-Term Changes in Ex-
Trade Policy,” in GENE GROSSMAN AND KEN- change Rates,” J. Money, Credit, Banking, Aug.
NETH R OGOFF , eds. 1995. 1970, 2(3), pp. 348–57.
FEENSTRA , R OBERT C. AND KENDALL , J ON P. G ILBERT , M ILTON AND KRAVIS, I RVING B. An in-
“Pass-Through of Exchange Rates and Purchas- ternational comparison of national products
ing Power Parity,” Nat. Bureau Econ. Res. and the purchasing power of currencies: A
Working Paper No. 4842, Aug. 1994. study of the United States, the United Kingdom,
FLOOD , R OBERT P. AND T AYLOR , M ARK P. “Ex- France, Germany, and Italy. Paris: Organiza-
change Rate Economics: What’s Wrong with tion for European Economic Cooperation,
the Conventional Approach?” in The micro- 1954.
structure of foreign exchange markets. Eds.: GILBERT , M ILTON AND ASSOCIATES. Compara-
J EFFREY FRANKEL , GIAMPAOLO GALLI , AND tive national products and price levels: A study
ALBERTO GIOVANNINI . Chicago: U. of Chicago of Western Europe and the United States. Paris:
Press, forthcoming. Organization for European Economic Coopera-
FRANKEL , JEFFREY A. “International Capital Mo- tion, 1958.
bility and Crowding-out in the U.S. Economy: GIOVANNINI , ALBERTO. “Exchange rates and
Imperfect Integration of Financial Markets or Traded Goods Prices,” J. Int. Econ., Feb. 1988,
Goods Markets?” in How open is the U.S. econ- 24(1/2), pp. 45–68.
omy? Ed.: R IK W. HAFER . Lexington: Lex- GLEN , JACK D. “Real Exchange Rates in the
ington Books, 1986, pp. 33–67. Short, Medium, and Long Run,” J. Int. Econ.,
———. “Zen and the Art of Modern Macro- Aug. 1992, 33(1/2), pp. 147–66.
economics: A Commentary,” in: Monetary pol- GROSSMAN, GENE AND R OGOFF , KENNETH , eds.
icy for a volatile global economy. Eds.: WIL- The handbook of international economics. Vol.
LIAM S. H ARAF AND T HOMAS D. W ILLETT . 3. Amsterdam: Elsevier Press, 1995.
Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute HAKKIO, CRAIG . “A Re-examination of Purchasing
for Public Policy Research, 1990, pp. 117–23. Power Parity,” J. Int. Econ., Nov. 1984, 17(3/4),
FRANKEL , J EFFREY A. AND R OSE , ANDREW K. pp. 265–77.
“Empirical Research on Nominal Exchange H ESTON , ALAN; N UXOLL , DANIEL A. AND S UM-
Rates,” 1995a in GENE GROSSMAN AND KEN- MERS , R OBERT . “The Differential-Productivity
NETH R OGOFF , eds. 1995. Hypothesis and Purchasing-Power Parities:
———. “A Panel Project on Purchasing Power Some New Evidence,” Rev. Int. Econ., Oct.
Parity: Mean Reversion Within and Between 1994, 2(3), pp. 227–43.
Countries.” Nat. Bureau Econ. Res. Working H OOPER , PETER AND M ORTON, J OHN . “Fluctua-
paper 5006, Feb. 1995b. tions in the Dollar: A Model of Nominal and
FRANKEL , JEFFREY A.; STERN, ERNESTO AND Real Exchange Rate Determination,” J. Int.
WEI , S HANG -JIN . “Trading Blocs and the Money Finance, Apr. 1982, 1(1), pp. 39–56.
Americas: The Natural, the Unnatural and the HSIEH , DAVID A. “The Determination of the Real
Supernatural,” J. Devel. Econ., June 1995, Exchange Rate: The Productivity Approach,” J.
47(1), pp. 61–95. Int. Econ., May 1982, 12(3/4), pp. 355–62.
FRENKEL , J ACOB A. “Purchasing Power Parity: H UIZINGA , J OHN . “An Empirical Investigation of
Doctrinal Perspective and Evidence from the the Long-run Behavior of Real Exchange
1920s,” J. Int. Econ., May 1978, 8(2), pp. 169– Rates,” in Carnegie-Rochester Conf. Ser. Public
91. Policy, Autumn 1987, 27, pp. 149–215.
———. “The Collapse of Purchasing Power Pari- I NTERNATIONAL M ONETARY FUND . Direction of
ties During the 1970’s,” Europ. Econ. Rev., May trade. Statistics yearbook. Washington, DC:
1981, 16(1), pp. 145–65. IMF, Dec. 1994.
Rogoff: The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle 667
———. International financial statistics. Washing- enties: Do They Fit Out of Sample?” J. Int.
ton, DC: IMF, 1995. Econ., Feb. 1983, 14(1/2), pp. 3–24.
I SARD , PETER . “How Far Can We Push the Law ———. “Was It Real? The Exchange-Rate Inter-
of One Price?” Amer. Econ. Rev., Dec. 1977, est Differential Relation over the Modern
67(5), pp. 942–48. Floating-Rate Period,” J. Finance, Sept. 1988,
KASA , KEN. “Adjustment Costs and Pricing to 43(4), pp. 933–48.
Market: Theory and Evidence,” J. Int. Econ., M USSA , M ICHAEL . “Nominal Exchange Rate Re-
Feb. 1992, 32(1/2), pp. 1–30. gimes and the Behavior of Real Exchange
KEYNES, J OHN M AYNARD . Essays in persuasion. Rates: Evidence and Implications,” Carnegie-
New York: Harcourt Brace, 1932. Rochester Ser. Public Policy, Autumn 1986, 25,
KNETTER , M ICHAEL M. “Price Discrimination by pp. 117–213.
U.S. and German Exporters,” Amer. Econ. Rev., OBSTFELD , M AURICE , “Model Trending Real Ex-
Mar. 1989, 79(1), pp. 198–210. change Rates.” U.C. Berkeley CIDER working
———. “International Comparisons of Price-to- paper C93–011, 1993.
Market Behavior,” Amer. Econ. Rev., June OBSTFELD , M AURICE AND R OGOFF , KENNETH .
1993, 83(3), pp. 473–86. “The Intertemporal Approach to the Current
———. “Why are Retail Prices in Japan so High? Account,” 1995a in G ENE GROSSMAN AND
Evidence from German Export Prices.” Nat. KENNETH R OGOFF , eds., 1995, pp. 1731–99.
Bureau Econ. Res. Working paper 4894, Dec. ———. “Exchange Rate Dynamics Redux,” J.
1994. Polit. Econ., June 1995b, 103(3), pp. 624–60.
KRAVIS, I RVING B. AND LIPSEY , R OBERT E. To- ———. Foundations of international macro-
ward an explanation of national price levels. economics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, forth-
Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. coming.
52. Princeton, NJ: International Finance Sec- O’CONNELL , PAUL G. J. “The Overvaluation of
tion, Dept. of Economics, Princeton U., 1983. Purchasing Power Parity.” Mimeo. Harvard U.,
KRUGMAN , PAUL R. “Purchasing Power Parity and 1996.
Exchange Rates: Another Look at the Evi- OFFICER , LAWRENCE H. “The Purchasing-Power-
dence,” J. Int. Econ., Aug. 1978, 8(3), pp. 397– Parity Theory of Exchange Rates: A Review Ar-
407. ticle,” Int. Monet. Fund Staff Pap., Mar. 1976a,
———. “Pricing to Market When the Exchange 23(1) , pp. 1–60.
Rate Changes,” in Real-financial linkages ———. “The Productivity Bias in Purchasing
among open economies. Eds.: SVEN W. ARNDT Power Parity: An Econometric Investigation,”
AND J. D AVID R ICHARDSON . Cambridge, MA: Int. Monet. Fund Staff Pap., Nov.1976b, 23(3),
MIT Press, 1987, pp. 49–70. pp. 545–79.
———. “Equilibrium Exchange Rates,” in Inter- ———. Purchasing power parity and exchange
national monetary policy coordination and ex- rates: Theory, evidence and relevance. Green-
change rate fluctuations. Eds.: WILLIAM H. wich, CT: JAI Press, 1982.
B RANSON , J ACOB A. FRENKEL , AND M ORRIS R ICHARDSON , J. DAVID . “Some Empirical Evi-
GOLDSTEIN. Chicago: U. of Chicago Press, dence on Commodity Arbitrage and the Law of
1990, pp. 159–87. One Price,” J. Int. Econ., May 1978, 8(2), pp.
LEE , M OON H. Purchasing power parity. New 341–51.
York: Marcel Dekker, 1976. R OGERS , J OHN H. “Real Shocks and Real Ex-
LEWIS, KAREN. “Puzzles in International Finan- changes in Really Long-Term Data.” Mimeo.
cial Markets,” in GENE GROSSMAN AND KEN- Federal Reserve Board, 1995.
NETH R OGOFF , eds. 1995. R OGERS , J OHN . H. AND JENKINS , M ICHAEL A.
LOTHIAN , JAMES R. “Multi-Country Evidence on “Haircuts or Hysteresis? Sources of Movements
the Behavior of Purchasing Power Parity under in Real Exchange Rates,” J. Int. Econ., May
the Recent Float.” Mimeo. Fordham U., 1994. 1995, 38(3/4), pp. 339–60.
LOTHIAN , J AMES R. AND T AYLOR , M ARK P. “Real R OGOFF , KENNETH . “Traded Goods Consumption
Exchange Rate Behavior: The Recent Float Smoothing and the Random Walk Behavior of
from the Perspective of the Past Two Centu- the Real Exchange Rate,” Bank of Japan Mone-
ries,” J. Polit. Econ., forthcoming. tary and Econ. Stud., Nov. 1992, 10(2), pp. 1–
M ARSTON, R ICHARD C. “Real Exchange Rates and 29.
Productivity Growth in the United States and R OLL , R ICHARD . “Violations of Purchasing Power
Japan,” in Real-financial linkages among open Parity and Their Implications for Efficient In-
economies. Eds.: S VEN W. ARNDT AND J. ternational Commodity Markets,” in Interna-
D AVID R ICHARDSON. Cambridge, MA: MIT tional finance and trade. Eds.: M ARSHALL S AR-
Press, 1987, 71–96. NAT AND G IORGIO P. S ZEGÖ . Cambridge, MA:
M C KINNON, R ONALD I. Monetary theory and Ballinger, 1979, pp. 133–76.
controlled flexibility in the foreign exchanges. SAMUELSON, PAUL A. “Theoretical Notes on
Princeton, NJ: International Finance Section, Trade Problems,” Rev. Econ. Statist., May 1964,
Princeton U., 1971. 46(2), pp. 145–54.
M EESE , R ICHARD A. AND R OGOFF , KENNETH S. SUMMERS , R OBERT AND HESTON , ALAN . “The
“Empirical Exchange Rate Models of the Sev- Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set
668 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXIV (June 1996)
of International Comparisons, 1950–1988,” chasing Power Disparity during the Floating
Quart. J. Econ., May 1991, 106(2), pp. 327–68. Rate Period: Exchange Rate Volatility, Trade
T AYLOR , M ARK P. “An Empirical Examination of Barriers and other Culprits.” Nat. Bureau Econ.
Long-Run Purchasing Power Parity using Coin- Res. Working paper 5032, Feb. 1995.
tegration Techniques,” Applied Econ., Oct. WILLIAMSON , J OHN , ed. Estimating equilibrium
1988, 20(10), pp. 1369–81. exchange rates. Washington, DC: Institute for
WEI , SHANG-J IN AND PARSLEY, DAVID C. “Pur- International Economics, 1994.

You might also like