You are on page 1of 15

George M.

Guess
Open Society Institute

Comparative Decentralization Lessons from


Pakistan, Indonesia, and the Philippines

This article provides an analytic framework to guide regimes that are designing or implementing
decentralization programs. It is based on a comparison of three Asian cases of fast-track decen-
tralization. The framework suggests that regimes contemplating devolution must face fundamental
issues of (1) background support, (2) culture and institutions, and (3) technical design and se-
quencing. It can be used by regimes to compare the relative difficulty of fundamental challenges to
decentralization with their own capacity and potential for effective response. The three regimes
responded similarly to the first two issues and differed in how they performed technical activities to
implement the decentralization programs. Within this technical sequence, the regimes varied widely
in performance. In that the Philippine program has attained better performance so far, the differ-
ent responses of that regime are significant. More research is required to explain differences in
technical performance in the Philippines and other similar programs and to attribute measures of
decentralization success to these differences.

Introduction
Regimes that are contemplating decentralization pro- experiences of Pakistan, Indonesia, and the Philippines,
grams are often reluctant to take the political risk of un- predicts that regimes will face both general background
known technical consequences in design and implementa- challenges (top support, decision capacity, and political
tion. Regimes know that policies are often based on myth, culture) and specific technical design issues. They need to
and decisions on imperfect information. Policy makers respond to intense criticism that neither the regime nor the
would like to eliminate myths and reduce uncertainty be- country can meet these decentralization challenges. The
fore proceeding with programs such as decentralization. framework provides preliminary answers to these critics.
In 1996, policy makers at the Albanian Ministry of Inte-
rior asked me to provide comparative regional informa-
tion on how to prevent fiscal transfers from acting as a
To Decentralize or Not to Decentralize?
disincentive to local revenue mobilization. Without this Regimes are advised that decentralization is an efficient
information, which was unavailable at the time, the min- program that can improve performance. Efficiency is a very
istry’s state secretary for local government was reluctant broad category in the literature (Guess, Loehr, and Vazquez
to push for devolution. Other regimes have also found them- 1997, 10–26) that includes activities ranging from political
selves at this point, and they need an empirically based representation to service results. The notion of an efficient
guide or framework for the successful design and imple- local government is that it can provide more responsive and
mentation of decentralization. Considerable advice has innovative services and, in turn, can be held more account-
been provided by international donors, consultants, and able for operations by local voters than nationally provided
university personnel on decentralization. But at this stage,
regimes need more than technical advice on single issues Dr. George M. Guess is director of research, Open Society Institute, Local
Government and Public Service Reform Initiative, Budapest, Hungary. Previ-
such as fiscal transfers or tax policies. ously, he was public budgeting specialist for the Pakistan Fiscal Decentrali-
This article provides a preliminary but empirically zation project, financed by the Asian Development Bank (2001–02), and
technical backstop for the Indonesia Local Government Financial Framework
grounded framework for regimes that are contemplating project (2001–02), financed by the U.S. Agency for International Develop-
decentralization. This framework, which is based on the ment. E-mail: gguess@osieurope.org.

Comparative Decentralization Lessons 217


operations. Regimes design and implement programs to typically held in place by small groups of backers who
decentralize authority and power to locally autonomous units keep them in power (Bueno de Mesquita and Root 2002,
(as opposed to a deconcentration of central government ser- 31); this increases their longevity, but risks popular dis-
vices locally or administrative decentralization) for a vari- content and the opposition of international donors. Decen-
ety of reasons. The most common are related to policy or tralizing power to the lower tiers of government has been a
technical concerns: to generate local pressure for national means of enlisting new supporters, which partly explains
or provincial state modernization; to provide the public with the recent devolution program in Pakistan.1
cheaper, better-quality, and greater service coverage; to Six major performance indicators are commonly used to
achieve budget savings by cutting the central provision of measure program success or failure. Table 1 employs these
local services; to widen political support for and increase and other well-known measures to evaluate three cases of
the level of trust in the central regime; to increase local par- devolution implementation. First, local governments should
ticipation in planning and budgeting to produce service mixes increase their own-source revenues. Dependence on central
consistent with local preferences; to produce fewer white transfers should decrease and the local proportion of budget
elephant or incomplete capital or development projects; to financing should increase after decentralization. This mea-
hold the country together; to permit regional or local ex- sures the sufficiency of local revenues to finance budgets.
perimentation in program design; and to prevent the disin- Second, with combined formula-based transfers and new
tegration of the central government (Burki 2001; Richburg local sources of revenues, local governments should increase
1998). their funding stability. The basis for allocating central trans-
A related rationale for decentralization is economic and fers is often opaque and negotiated. Coupled with central
fiscal: Decentralized decision making is crucial for effec- revenue shortfalls, the budget system produces sudden fund-
tive organization in that it promotes internal competition ing cutoffs that negatively affect local services. Third, local
and entrepreneurial talent (North 1990, 81). Fiscal decen- government budget autonomy should increase. In contrast
tralization allows local governments to finance capital in- to central controls and extensive earmarks of local funding,
vestments on their own through responsible long-term bor- decentralization should give local officials increased author-
rowing in private markets. This strengthens the autonomy ity to shift funds to improve service delivery. Fourth, decen-
of local governments and the fiscal condition of central tralization should be associated with improved service de-
governments by reducing the need for grants from the state livery. Services such as health, education, and water supply
budget or loans from international financial institutions should be of higher quality and delivered at lower costs to
backed by sovereign guarantees (USAID 2002, 1). In ad- more citizens, that is, technical and allocative efficiency, re-
dition, resolving vertical fiscal imbalances in intergovern- spectively. Fifth, the performance of services and the de-
mental systems by devolving authority allows a closer cor- centralization process itself should be monitored and evalu-
respondence between revenue means and expenditure needs ated by citizen groups through surveys and social audits.
(Shah 1994, 40). A slightly different rationale focuses on This should lead to greater accountability and responsive-
the macropolitical benefits for democratic stability and ness of elected and appointed officials to local citizens. Fi-
responsiveness, that is, expansion of the governing coali- nally, decentralization should lead to greater local authority
tion to increase the inclusiveness of the central regime. to hire and fire appointed officials, meaning greater respon-
Governing coalitions may want to increase their legitimacy siveness of local governments to citizen needs. Officials
by expanding their base of support and by reducing con- would no longer be appointed from the center and paid for
straints on their policy freedom. Autocratic regimes are by the local governments (Winkler and Hatfield 2002).

Table 1 Comparative Decentralization Performance


Share of subnational SNG sets tax SNG authority to SNG mayor/ SNG can design/ Dedicated and Improved
own-revenues in total base and rate set budget council elected implement org- rule-based fiscal service
revenues** (percent) priorities staffing for transfer/tax outcomes
service reqs
Philippines 42.8 Yes Yes, but central Yes Yes Yes NA
government
still earmarks
Pakistan 5.0 Yes Yes Nazim by No Yes NA
council
Indonesia 25.4 No No Mayor by No No NA
council
**Source: Government Finance Statistics Yearbook 2001 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund). With the exception of Pakistan for which local statistics have not yet
been reported, the measures of local revenue sufficiency were obtained by dividing total revenues and grants by revenues from other levels of national government and
subtracting this amount from 100 percent.
SNG = Subnational government.

218 Public Administration Review • March/April 2005, Vol. 65, No. 2


Regimes are regularly provided these arguments and tonomy and authority through decentralization programs.
multiple measures for decentralization. They know it is Despite recent terrorist-control problems and internal
efficient to decentralize, but major inefficiencies can re- criticism from a vibrant local press, the Pakistani regime
sult from poorly designed and implemented programs. For continues to govern through civil service and military in-
instance, they could lose their elected or appointed jobs, stitutions, with reasonable success. Recent changes and
and the country could descend into (perhaps greater) chaos. security threats since September 11 have kept President
What should they do? Musharraf’s regime in power and have increased support
for devolution. Fear of regional fragmentation in light of
growing poverty and inequality—partly attributable to poor
Comparative Methodology local services—has been high among all three regimes.
To provide applied lessons to policy makers who are Pakistan’s program abandoned deconcentrated subnational
deciding whether or how to engage in decentralization, governance consisting of provinces, divisions, and districts
comparative field lessons are needed from similar cases. and created three new levels of countrywide elected gov-
The matched-case method of comparison that Xavier ernment: districts (96), tehsils, or towns (337), and union
(1998) uses to compare Malaysian and Australian budget councils (6,022). The program implements the intent of
reforms is useful for this purpose. That method was used the May 2000 local government plan. The operating prin-
in this research to select countries with similar intergov- ciple is to transfer power downward to citizen groups and
ernmental structures that have instituted similar reform district-level governments to provide and finance needed
programs under similar regional conditions. Classification basic services that were not being provided by either the
of the similarities allows one to hold constant the key fac- provinces or the central government (NRB 2000, 9). An
tors expected to influence reform, reducing the problem of impetus for the devolution program is that the central gov-
multiple causation, which otherwise besets comparative ernment—the National Reconstruction Bureau—rightly
analysis. By picking decentralization cases with similar feared that popular dissatisfaction with its performance was
key variables, this study focused on the measures, condi- growing and that this threatened the state’s legitimacy to
tions, and variables that are different. Focusing on the dif- hold the nation, four large and dissimilar provinces, to-
ferences of matched cases allows for a more rigorous ex- gether. Power was formally transferred to the new district
amination of factors that may account for variation in tier of government in August of 2001. In 2002, it was esti-
decentralization program results.2 mated the districts generated an average of 5.0 percent of
their own revenues (table 1). That is, 95 percent of their
funds were still provided from transfers and shared rev-
Background and Context on Matched enue sources.3
Program Cases The Philippine decentralization program has been de-
The three programs are similar in that they are “fast track.” scribed as one of the most far reaching in the developing
None of them was donor driven, and international donors world. A long tradition of political–administrative cen-
such as the Asian Development Bank and the U.S. Agency tralism existed in the Philippines that was initially chal-
for International Development continue to play critical sup- lenged by the concept of local autonomy, enshrined in the
porting roles. For the purposes of matching cases, these are Constitution of 1987 and later in the Local Government
similar regional examples of once-centralized states that have Code of 1991 (Republic Act 7160). This was the fifth at-
evolved into federal governance systems. Through this evo- tempt since 1946 to empower the four levels of local gov-
lution, all three countries have maintained relative stability. ernment with political and administrative authority (Yap
All three have enforced macroeconomic discipline, which and Sator 2001, 1).
tends to ensure political stability by stabilizing prices, em- The program began with the implementation of the Lo-
ployment, and budget deficits (Guess, Loehr, and Vazquez cal Government Code in 1991 (Galang 2001, i) and ex-
1997, 39). Stability can be used as a resource by central panded the responsibilities and authority of the 76 prov-
regimes to reallocate “policy latitude or “agency autonomy” inces, 1,540 municipalities, 66 cities, and 42,000 barangays
to its counterparts in lower-tier governments (Peters 1978, (precincts or wards). The major change was the expansion
168). In political and economic stability, the Philippines was of city, municipality, and barangay jurisdiction over the
ranked tenth most stable and Indonesia eighteenth by Eurasia/ planning and provision of hospitals, social welfare, envi-
Lehman Brothers (Economist 2003, 100). Economic growth ronmental protection, public infrastructure, and zoning. The
remains strong in both countries, with gross domestic prod- center would henceforth support or supervise rather than
uct increases of 5.8 percent and 3.9 percent, respectively, dictate or control local activities in these areas (Miller 1999,
from the same quarter in 2002. In the context of relative 15). An internal revenue allotment formula transfer based
stability, all three regimes have attempted to reallocate au- local financing on population (50 percent), equalization

Comparative Decentralization Lessons 219


(25 percent), and land area (25 percent) (Miller 1999, 15– weakened by increasing local partisanship and intrusions
16). In 1999, the allotment actually exceeded the costs of from the central bureaucracy (Shah 2003). This suggests
devolved functions and other mandates. Reflecting high that Pakistan had a local government tradition that was short
levels of regime support for the reform, this led to a decen- circuited and is now being reconnected. Thus, the differ-
tralization rarity—a centrally funded surplus for local gov- ence between Pakistan and the Philippines is narrower still.
ernments. Second, while the Philippine reform focused largely on
The Indonesian “big bang” devolution program com- fiscal devolution and not on political decentralization, an
menced in January of 2001, implementing two laws signed all-at-once sequence was followed in Pakistan and Indo-
in 1999 (Alm, Aten, and Bahl 2001). It has been described nesia—fiscal and political decentralization. Third, higher-
as “one of the fastest and most comprehensive decentrali- tier administrators deployed to local units are to be tempo-
zation initiatives ever attempted by any country” (USAID rary in Pakistan and have been permanent in the Philippines.
2002, 1). The program transferred power over core local Major deployments are still to be made in Indonesia. Nev-
services primarily to the 268 districts and, to a lesser ex- ertheless, the programs are substantially similar for com-
tent, the 31 provinces and roughly 350,000 villages. The parative purposes.
program broadly expanded local authority over new ser-
vice facilities and sectors. To ensure that local units actu-
ally perform core functions consistent with minimum ser- Challenges to Decentralization Design
vice standards, Law 25/2000 provided technical criteria and Implementation
for local service quality, sufficiency, and cost. This ser- The proposed policy framework suggests that regimes
vice-monitoring system now has to be tested and imple- face three types of constraints in the implementation of
mented. The Indonesian government and international do- decentralization : (1) background support and local tech-
nors continue to support the program, with positive results. nical capacity, (2) cultural-institutional issues, and (3) tech-
The Pakistani and Indonesian programs are similar in that nical design and sequencing issues (figure 1). Each con-
both devolved authority to local governments, largely by- straint should be recognized by policy makers as a trigger
passing the provinces and shifting large groups of civil point for review, course corrections, or possibly halting
servants to the districts to provide them with technical decentralization programs. The three regimes studied re-
capability. sponded effectively and similarly to the first two sets of
To summarize program similarities, all three countries constraints. Their performances differed in how they re-
devolved authority for programs that were formerly the sponded to the third set of constraints: technical design
responsibility of higher-tier governments. The three re- and sequencing of activities. Regime responses allowed
gimes (Philippines, Pakistan, and Indonesia) decided to go comparison of similar cases responding differently to tech-
full speed ahead on reforms by (1) devolving major func- nical sequencing challenges. With impact data (which we
tions, (2) assigning revenue authority and block grant fi- do not have), one could attribute devolution program re-
nancing, (3) transferring cadres of central and provincial sults to differences in regime abilities to respond to cul-
officials and positions to administer the decentralization, tural challenges and to design effective technical sequences.
and (4) organizing local elections for councils and mayors Using the proposed framework to compare the three devo-
to hold local administrations accountable. All are financ- lution programs facing common constraints, one can con-
ing the devolution and new responsibilities with entitle- firm or reject the importance of the constraints and focus
ment shares of higher-tier revenues (Pakistan’s “divisible on the successes and failures in response to these constraints
fund/local fund”). All transferred substantial numbers of and measure their effects on program results.
administrators and their positions from higher-tier govern-
ments to provide the technical resources for implementa- Background Conditions
tion (70,283 in the Philippines, two million in Indonesia, Opponents often argue these conditions must be imme-
and about 700,000 in Pakistan). diately present for decentralization to succeed. Without top-
Of course, the paths were not completely similar, and
there were minor differences in implementation. First, the Figure 1 Challenges and Constraints to
legal basis for local governments existed in the Philippines Decentralization Implementation
prior to the reform. This meant that Indonesian and Paki-
1. Background 2. Cultural/ 3. Technical
stani policy makers had a bigger job ahead. On the other institutional
support design/
hand, during the 1947–58 period, Pakistani local govern- (Regime support/ (Political culture/ sequencing
ments operating under administrative decentralization fi- local technical civil society/ (Similarities/
capacity) institutional differences)
nanced 95 percent of their needs with own-source revenues. rules)
Following this postpartition period, local governments were

220 Public Administration Review • March/April 2005, Vol. 65, No. 2


level support and local technical capacity, it is argued, de- sensus in Pakistan that without the required skills, sys-
centralization programs must fail. In fact, background con- tems, and resources (within the local institutions) the coun-
ditions are variables rather than constants, and they can be trywide decentralization and devolution program will re-
met with supporting public statements by the regime and main largely unimplementable (Khan 2002, 4). Manor
effective legal action (for instance, the authorization of laws (1999) suggests that countries devolving after initially
and regulations). deconcentrating services (that is, administrative decentrali-
zation) have an advantage in that this provides a technical
Top-Level Regime Support foundation for autonomous decision making. Consistent
For successful implementation, regime support4 should with this conclusion, the three country programs used three
exist in three forms: (1) the authorization of legal and regu- similar mechanisms to reduce the absorptive-capacity
latory frameworks, (2) the provision of adequate local fi- problem.
nancing, and (3) the authorization of oversight and control First, based on newly assigned tasks, skills and systems
structures. While sustained regime support exists in all three have been or are being transferred from higher-tier gov-
cases, problems remain. ernments to local governments. About two million central
First, as indicated, organic laws have been promulgated staff will be transferred in Indonesia and more than 70,000
in all three countries and supported by the respective re- have been transferred in the Philippines. Positions, people,
gimes. Possibly the strongest support has been provided equipment, and operating norms have all been transferred
by President Musharraf, who made the devolution the cen- to enable local units to perform their assigned tasks more
terpiece of his governance reforms, widening regime sup- effectively. Second, reporting and control systems had to
port in the face of major national security threats and a be shifted from central to local accountability. Departmental
long legacy of corrupt and poorly delivered local services. structures, routine approval processes for licenses and per-
Second, regime support is typically measurable in finan- mits, and budget and accounting reports all had to be re-
cial support provided to local units. One of the greatest routed to serve local needs rather than the control and com-
threats to devolution and local government reform is the pliance rules of the central government. In Pakistan, for
failure to provide sufficient resources to meet needs and instance, the Northwest Frontier Province restructured 26
local aspirations (Cochrane 1983, 6). In Pakistan, local departments, downsizing and refocusing them according
governments have been given new statutory sources of to a new distribution of functions. This enables provinces
revenue. They now have the independence to decide on to monitor, regulate, and supervise local district operations
tax rates and fee levies. By contrast, the Indonesian or- without controlling their affairs (World Bank 2002a, 10).
ganic laws (22 and 25/1999) did not assign new revenue Third, initial resistance to decentralization was strong
powers or borrowing authority to local governments. This in all three countries, based on the argument that locals
jeopardizes the link between costs incurred and services were not to be trusted with central funds and should be
demanded by local citizens (Alm, Aten, and Bahl 2001, monitored closely. Pakistan has initiated at least four re-
7). Third, central authorities (regimes) demonstrate sup- forms in the name of empowering local governments since
port for devolution by emphasizing supervision and over- the 1950s. All were incomplete reforms and were largely
sight of the programs over bureaucratic tendencies to in- reversed by later regimes, which argued for a lack of local
terfere and control. In all three cases, major opposition technical and political capacities. In Indonesia, similar ar-
from central (in the Philippines) and provincial (in Paki- guments have been raised about the local capacity to ab-
stan and Indonesia) authorities had to be overcome. Even sorb fiscal and technical resources. Several international
after overcoming opposition long enough to promulgate evaluations concluded there was little advance preparation
organic laws, transitory leadership with vacillating sup- for decentralization and that local governments were largely
port threatened the program in the Philippines. The Phil- unprepared for their new tasks (Alm, Aten, and Bahl 2001,
ippine Department of Health had eight changes of leader- 5). Coupled with the tradition of “waiting for the central
ship during 1991–2001, which held views ranging from government to act” (Alm, Aten, and Bahl, 2001, 9), top-
recentralization to continuing support for the reform level support was needed to overcome the perception that
(Razon-Abad 2001, 7–8). capacity problems were so severe as to jeopardize the en-
tire rationale for the program.
Local Technical Capacity
The most immediate issue is whether the newly em- Cultural-Institutional Issues
powered tier of local government can absorb its new rev- Opponents of decentralization often argue that (1) cen-
enue-raising and expenditure assignments. Opponents of tralist cultures value centrally directed nepotism and pa-
decentralization often focus on the lack of local capacity tronage more than issue-based local politics; (2) the lack
to oppose or derail the program. There is widespread con- of intermediary organizations for exercising citizens’ voices

Comparative Decentralization Lessons 221


will prevent local accountability; and (3) weak institutional the development of intermediary civil society organizations,
systems will reject universal norms and rules that are irrel- such as the media, unions, citizen associations, and politi-
evant to local cultural practices in such obvious areas as cal parties. Opponents of decentralization argue that if the
tax assessment and auditing. Such cultural and institutional goal is democratic decentralization and the clusters of in-
issues constitute a second set of challenges to which re- terests are missing or of the wrong kind, it is difficult to
gimes contemplating decentralization must respond. develop representative political parties in any but the nar-
rowest sense, that is, corporatist parties representing the
Political Culture state and industry. Without sustaining organizations to fa-
In developing countries, political culture is often viewed cilitate governance, devolution programs are likely to de-
as a threat or constraint rather than as an opportunity to teriorate into chaos and revert to centralism.
build on the achievements of decentralization. Political In developing societies, neither autonomous local gov-
culture consists of those shared values and attitudes that ernments nor powerful civic organizations exist. Never-
affect institutional and policy decision making (Inglehart theless, repressed local and civic traditions may exist, as
1988). It is what determines how people behave when they in Pakistan, which the decentralization program can reac-
are not being watched. It can also be recognized as “the tivate or energize. Conditions of repressed civil society or
way things are done around here” (Economist 2002, 53). “nascent social capital”—norms, trust, and networks fa-
Opponents of decentralization argue that culturally rein- cilitating coordinated action (Putnam 1993, 167)—can
forced systems are not easily changeable in the short run. serve as the foundation for successful institutional changes
The common cultural feature is centralist decision making required by a decentralization program. Manor found that
and popular distrust of frequently corrupt governments. even under conditions of repressed civil society—for in-
The trick is to distinguish those elements of the politi- stance, in Cote d’Ivoire during the 1980s—the psycho-
cal culture that genuinely deter program results and can logical impact of decentralization programs can catalyze
only be changed in the medium term from those that are greater participation and associational activity at lower
distinctive but can be modified or built upon to facilitate levels (1999, 57). In his view, decentralization programs
program results in the short run. Some cultural practices can make entirely adequate achievements in the absence
do not really affect the course of decentralization and can of lively civil society and can make up for them in the
be changed only in the long term, such as rote educational short term. The absence of full civil society need not be
practices, nepotism in civil service hiring, and staff loyal- an obstacle to program implementation.6 Decentralization
ties to groups and families over formal organizations. These programs need to identify these useful cultural practices
are important and distinctive—but they may not be impor- and build on them, rather than relying on systems imposed
tant to program implementation. More important for de- from the outside, often from a combination of poorly de-
centralization are practices that directly affect central or signed donor programs and imported consultants. Even
local government systems and are changeable in the short in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union, where
term. For example, distrust of government (revenue col- civil society did not formally exist, local party organiza-
lections), family and tribal loyalties (budgeting for devel- tions provided leadership skills to members that are now
opment projects), and peremptory or arbitrary power over being put to use in the development of civic institutions in
underlings (auditing) would affect decentralization imple- that region (Jacobsen 2000). Based on these conclusions,
mentation. Persistent administrative practices such as the the Pakistani regime included civil society creation as part
generation of statistical reports (budget reports that are often of its devolution program.
unread) and centralized expenditure controls (to preserve
hierarchical power within ministries) can be changed by Institutional Systems and Practices
modifying internal incentives. For example, statistical re- Institutions are the formal and informal rules, the sys-
porting can be converted into useful analysis for budget- tems (personnel, budgeting, procurement) and incentive
ing and auditing; passive line management can be turned structures (tax codes, assignments of intergovernmental
into active program implementation by giving them tar- functions), that shape the behavior of organizations and
gets and enforcing expenditure controls that already exist. individuals (North 1990; Burki and Perry 1998, 11). Many
Culture may be turned from a static obstacle to the dy- of these practices seem immutable and run counter to the
namic foundation on which a decentralization program can Western values that are central to devolution: transparency,
be built. 5 accountability, due process, and majority participation in
public decisions. Local parties and elite groups often op-
Civil Society pose modern institutional values as “imperialistic” and “im-
Cultural and civil society issues are related in that re- posed outsider” values to those that prevail locally. Never-
gimes governing in centralized cultures generally repress theless, obstructionist institutional practices can be

222 Public Administration Review • March/April 2005, Vol. 65, No. 2


modified with the right incentives. In Uganda, enforcing ficulty with the comparison is that, in most programs, more
readiness criteria through performance agreements has im- than one step is being implemented at each stage and, within
proved the reporting of health and education expenditures each step, differences exist in the scope and intensity of
at the local level and has produced a 60 percent increase in activities. This affects results and, to provide fully reliable
social expenditures reaching clients. Incremental changes policy lessons, requires more precise data than are avail-
in core reporting-system rules have produced sustained able at this point.
modification of institutional practices (Brooke 2002). Para-
doxically, Cochrane (1983, 5) found that some of the most Similarities
authoritarian regimes, which guarded power jealously, also From the program comparison, it was found the three
promoted local government reform (such as Nigeria and countries followed an approximate sequence of eight major
Pakistan). The current Pakistani devolution program was activities. First, all three countries began to consider devo-
initiated by a military government. That regime, now partly lution after they had achieved relative macroeconomic sta-
legitimated by election results, has been attempting to set bility. This is widely considered a prerequisite of decentrali-
up incentives to channel local values and practices into a zation, and International Monetary Fund program conditions
workable system that will produce service results and the focus on the establishment and maintenance of stabilization
popular trust required for effective governance. (Guess, Loehr, and Vazquez 1997, 33). Pakistan began its
The background conditions discussed previously reflect treasury control efforts in earnest in 1999, and the current
deeper institutional practices that can impede the progress regime’s intent is to integrate local fiscal and treasury op-
of any devolution program. They have been presented by erations into a single central bank account. Efforts are being
cautious supporters and opponents of decentralization alike made to strengthen internal controls and audit systems at
as deeper systemic problems of values and attitudes. While the district level to ensure proper spending controls. To pre-
they cannot be ignored in program design, they can be con- vent threats to macroeconomic control, local units have not
verted to shorter-term issues. For a large number of decen- yet been given short-term cash management or long-term
tralization programs, including the three cases examined capital borrowing authority. The Philippine Department of
here, neither institutional history nor deeper cultural traits Finance has been working since 1992 on the supervision of
need be viewed as constraints to devolution. Those fea- local treasury officers and the improvement of internal con-
tures of local political culture and institutions, such as the trol and accounting guidelines. Interest is growing in more
Pakistani administrative tradition of local governance, need sophisticated cost-accounting systems as well, with a pilot
to be built upon to support resource and technology trans- program initiated in 2001. Indonesia has shown more inter-
fers that are consistent with an appropriate sequencing of est in local borrowing and financing of infrastructure and
the decentralization program. Instead, many believe the development than in macroeconomic control. There is still
larger constraints to successful decentralization are poor no system of fiscal-transfer monitoring. Of the three cases,
planning and lack of financing (Cochrane 1983, 6). These Indonesia seems to have stressed macroeconomic control
constitute a third set of challenges to which regimes must over local finances the least, which could lead to unsustain-
respond (figure 1). able local financing problems later in the form of arrears
and fiscal deficits.
Technical Design and Sequencing It was found that in the second step, regimes focused on
The literature on the design of institutions indicates the the establishment of legal and regulatory frameworks. This
importance of getting incentives right and taking into ac- task refers to the promulgation of an organic law and the
count cultural values (North 1990, 137–38). But very little drafting of bylaws and operating regulations. While laws
has been written on options for getting the technical se- can be in flux for years and subject to revision and repeal,
quence right for the actual installation of institutions. Suc- an important indicator of results is whether intergovern-
cessful decentralization requires creating new institutions mental roles and responsibilities have been assigned ac-
and building on existing practices, with support from re- cording to sensible economic and political proximity cri-
gimes and intermediary organizations. The implementa- teria. Often they are not. In Pakistan, intralocal government
tion experiences, or the decisions and activities pertaining relations are still not clear between the tehsil, union, and
to the three programs, suggest that research should focus district levels, and no mechanism exists to deal with con-
on the technical design and sequencing stage (figure 1). flicts of law. The “economic constitution” step also requires
The questions raised by the analytic framework are: (1) the establishment of a primary institutional coordination
How have the three programs been sequenced, and (2) what and control mechanism at the central level (often at the
difference has the sequence made to results? The matched- ministry of finance) that can plan, manage, and implement
case approach allows one to review the similarities and the devolution program. Regulatory relationships between
attempt to link the differences to program results. One dif- provinces and districts are also unclear. One motive for

Comparative Decentralization Lessons 223


the Pakistani devolution was to circumvent the corrupt and and the absence of any real civil society or independent
ineffective provincial governments and to give power and professional sector in Pakistan. The Local Government
funding to the new local tier. Ordinance (SBNP 2001) established citizen community
Nevertheless, the overall approach of the National Re- boards with entitlements to 25 percent of local develop-
construction Bureau has been top-down planning, with an ment budgets. This institutional mechanism was an attempt
emphasis on rules, laws, and regulations from the bureau to break the lock on local politics by traditional elites and
and the provincial levels. Very little emphasis has been parties and to create a nascent civil society organization
given to the needed local management flexibility to de- responsible for development projects. Civil society has
liver the needed services. By contrast, the Philippine legal been repressed and is still weak in Pakistan. Pakistan held
and regulatory approach has been more facilitative and less local elections (for nazims, or mayors and councils) early
command and control. Conflicts of law have been recog- in the program (2000 and 2001), and this generated ex-
nized and an institutional mechanism proposed to remedy cessive local demands that threatened the capacity of new
the problem. Indonesian laws have not assigned clear ex- districts to respond.
penditure and revenue roles for local governments. The By contrast, the Philippines had a large civil society
laws also excluded the provinces from the devolution of structure to draw upon; the government of the Philippines
authority. Of the three cases, the Philippines have given developed a broad supervisory group that included repre-
most attention to the development of the legal and regula- sentatives from civil society and professional groups. The
tory framework. supervisory group included the Department of Interior and
The third set of regime activities focuses on the resolu- Local Government, Department of Budget and Manage-
tion of local capacity weaknesses. Regimes contemplating ment, Department of Finance, Civil Service Commission,
decentralization have to deal with this twice: initially as a the Economic and Development Authority, and the Com-
background issue, and later as an operational issue to be mission on Audit. Associations included the Association
remedied by technical assistance, training, and improved of Local Budget Officers. Indonesia relied on several local
incentives. All three regimes dealt with this issue by cor- government associations, including APPSI-provincial,
rectly defining it as a short-term issue that could be rem- APEKSI-local and district, and APKASI-mayors. These
edied by a promise of support and by deploying higher- have been important supporters, but they have not served
tier staff to local units. The Philippines and Indonesia as devolution program advocates so far. Part of this may
required local units to pay for salaries out of fiscal trans- occur in the shakeout period which, unlike Pakistan and
fers. None of the programs required local civil services, Indonesia, the Philippines has already experienced.
which created tension with central and provincial levels. In the fifth step, regimes focused on the establishment
Only the Philippines has made significant strides in mod- of a monitoring system to track progress and to make course
ern performance-based capacity building. Pakistan’s ca- corrections during implementation. In fact, only one coun-
pacity building is largely in-house and derived from ar- try did this; the other two made largely symbolic moves to
chaic colonial-era institutions and practices. The create monitoring and evaluation systems. The National
Philippines has given the most attention to this issue from Reconstruction Bureau in Pakistan planned a full-scale
initiation of the program in 1992. For example, it exempted implementation without pilot programs. It made no effort
20 percent of the local development fund from central ear- to establish any monitoring system, perhaps out of the ex-
marks. While Indonesia deployed about two million staff cessive hubris that it could simply dictate program effec-
to local units, the government of Indonesia did not provide tiveness. By contrast, in 1992 the Philippines established
them with any incentives for capacity building or the ap- the Rapid Field Appraisal system to generate needs assess-
plication of skills to new local systems. ments and to provide feedback on implementation progress.
It was found that the fourth step followed by the re- This was also consistent with its demand-driven, capacity-
gimes was to establish facilitation networks to support and building approach, which attempted to avoid failed sup-
sustain the reform. Without local support groups and citi- ply-driven training approaches. Indonesia made no major
zen participation, decentralization reform typically re- efforts in this area, other than the 1994–95 District Au-
mains unimplemented legislation. In Pakistan, a military tonomy Pilot Program, which was used to assess local ca-
government with an initially short operating life initiated pacity to execute newly devolved tasks prior to the pro-
the reform. It was directed by the National Reconstruc- gram. Negative conclusions generated by this program were
tion Bureau with little or no civil society or associational not utilized by the government of Indonesia in program
backing. This was due to the rapid planning requirement, planning or implementation.
the knowledge that the provinces would attempt to derail In the sixth activity, all three regimes recognized the
the reform, the recognition that most districts were tech- need to provide stable financing if local autonomy was to
nically deficient and could not make sound evaluations, become a reality. All three attempted to deal with the fi-

224 Public Administration Review • March/April 2005, Vol. 65, No. 2


nancing issue, but varied widely in success. For current gram. Indonesia has not forcefully attempted to restruc-
services, Pakistan’s National Reconstruction Bureau and ture local offices consistent with decentralization require-
Ministry of Finance agreed to pay the wage costs of the ments. Thus, the Philippines began early to improve local
devolution for the interim period—otherwise, local gov- government unit performance and has achieved the most
ernments could not pay the salaries of deployed staff or in this area. All three regimes recognize that local institu-
their own. Salaries now account for about 85 percent of tional reform will require a medium- to long-term effort.
district budgets (World Bank 2002a, 4). There are also in- The eighth and final step consists of efforts to shift plan-
novative block grants from federal ministries (such as edu- ning and budgeting for public-sector activities from inputs
cation) to ensure funding for primary and secondary edu- to outputs and outcomes. This is somewhat surprising be-
cation needs at the local level. But there is still no agreement cause one would expect results budgeting to be first, as
on the provision of stable annual amounts of funding or its core systems such as transfers and development projects
basis (that is, a performance formula) from the National depend on their information. Instead, all regimes calcu-
Finance Commission through the provincial finance com- lated that existing information could be used for results
missions. For fiscal year 2003, the central government purposes, for instance, line items to control operations and
transferred 2.5 percent of total general sales tax receipts to maintenance expenditures and to gauge sufficiency for pres-
the provinces (Abbasi 2002). But because of retained shares ervation of capital stocks. As results-oriented budgeting
and forecasting errors, this percentage does not indicate requires improvements in analytical skills and the genera-
the actual yield for local governments. tion of performance reporting information, it is more of a
Indonesian central transfers provide 25 percent of local medium-term activity, and hence last on the list of regime
revenues. No other major revenue sources are assigned and, priorities. In its short program history, Pakistan has done
given the absence of any real tax base in most areas, local much in this area at the provincial level, and this serves as
own-source revenues are relatively high for the coverage a model for local reform. At the local level, efforts sup-
of local needs (25.4 percent, see table 1). The assignment ported by the Asian Development Bank to develop perfor-
of revenues has not been based on the local cost of ser- mance systems have been constrained by the need to en-
vices estimates (that is, a target level of expenditures), sure consistency with past forms, accounting practices,
which should have been done first. This means the center manuals, and administrative practices. There are no local
retains control of revenues. In the Philippines, the early professional pressure groups advocating changes here (the
internal revenue allotment, required by the 1987 Constitu- civil society constraint). The lead agency for reform, the
tion, provided funds to local government units but excluded National Reconstruction Bureau, is hampered by inexpe-
the costs of the devolution. This deficiency was remedied rience in this area, together with a mostly consultant staff
by the 1994 “cost of devolved functions” mechanism in and top-down chain of command. The Philippine program
health (World Bank 1994). Work remains to be done in all utilized the Association of Local Budget Officers and other
three countries on improving the stability and performance professional associations to change local practices and to
basis of funding for local governments. The long gestation upgrade analytical skills. The Philippine central govern-
period in the Philippines suggests that fiscal stability is a ment had substantial experience at the central level in per-
medium-term issue requiring a longer shakeout period. formance and program budgeting. Despite an emphasis on
The seventh activity is restructuring and streamlining local borrowing (considered sophisticated by most), Indo-
local offices to prepare them for the performance of their nesia has not yet focused on performance reporting and
newly devolved tasks. The National Reconstruction Bu- budgeting.
reau has given considerable thought to this in Pakistan,
and efforts have been made at the provincial level to stream- Differences
line operations. Efforts at the district, tehsil, and union lev- Several conclusions can be drawn from the differences in
els have been more intermittent, which could impede ser- program implementation. The differences appeared less in
vice delivery. The bureau has not provided methodological the sequence of activities than in their actual performance.
options for functional review or reorganization, nor have As indicated in table 2, seven differences can be noted in the
regulatory relationships between provincial departments performance of technical activities at the organizational
and corresponding local group offices (such as public framework and implementation strategy levels.
works) been worked out clearly. In the Philippines, local First, the supervisory structure for decentralization var-
government units were authorized in 1991 to establish their ied among the three cases. The Philippines began with a
own structures consistent with local service delivery needs; broad-based structure that included multiple representa-
in 1992 the Civil Service Commission recommended a local tive interests. This extended to the use of civil society in-
government unit structure, and the Department of Interior stitutions for feedback and guidance on the progress of
and Local Government established an anti-red-tape pro- the reform. By contrast, the supervisory structure of the

Comparative Decentralization Lessons 225


Table 2 Differences in Decentralization Implementation cluded few international examples and did not solicit
Component Pakistan Philippines Indonesia international experience—despite the intent of the
Organizational Asian Development Bank’s Fiscal Decentralization
framework Technical Assistance project (2001–02). Pakistan as-
Supervisory structure/ Top-down Broad-based Less narrow
civil society feedback and narrow
signed roles to districts but ignored lower-tier inter-
Legal/regulatory Few comparative Comparative Comparative governmental relations, and it is still uncertain how
framework inputs inputs inputs to proceed with provincial–local relations. Both the
Capacity-building Some emphasis Strong emphasis Strong emphasis
Philippines and Indonesia have relied heavily on in-
Monitoring and No Yes No
evaluation system ternational and comparative local legal experience to
Implementation draft and modify their legal frameworks. As a result,
Local revenue Weak Strong-use of Weak the institutional base of the latter two programs is
sufficiency fiscal incentives
Restructure local Marginal efforts Some efforts Marginal efforts stronger than in Pakistan.
offices Third, regimes that wish to sustain their decen-
Performance Superficial Strong emphasis Some interest tralization reforms concentrate heavily on capacity
management interest
and budgeting building. The Philippines began early to provide train-
ing through a variety of institutions, including uni-
Pakistan reform has been limited to the military regime’s versities, nongovernmental organizations, and private
client institution, the National Reconstruction Bureau, firms. Indonesia also stresses capacity building and is
which represents few interests and is staffed by many con- strongly supported in this by funds from the U.S. Agency
sultants in a loose accountability structure. Pakistan has a for International Development. However, Indonesia trans-
weak civil society network; the reform was intended to ferred about two million staff without prior capacity-build-
circumvent existing political parties and provincial authori- ing support. Pakistan has responded more slowly, restrict-
ties, which the military viewed as opponents of the re- ing training to the existing colonial-based institutions,
form. As noted, the Local Government Ordinance autho- which are known more for their legal focus than for man-
rized a new set of civil society institutions for development agement innovation and technical analysis. The Philippine
projects, called citizen community boards. There is still government is transferring people and positions to districts
fear these boards may entrench local moneyed interests but with little prior training other than from their provin-
rather than empower the poor, because it is the rich who cial offices. The Asian Development Bank will provide
will have time to develop the technical expertise to attract support for training and capacity building. But it appears
district council funds (World Bank 2002b, 23). As ex- that much of this support will be locally driven and may
pected, citizen community boards have not yet become not be consistent with international best practices.
operational and are experiencing problems in competition The final key element of the organizational framework
with other locally powerful groups. The scope of the In- for decentralization is monitoring and evaluation. This is
donesian supervisory structure falls between the other two the fourth area of major difference in technical performance
programs—some representation at the top (the Office of among the three programs. The central supervisory insti-
Decentralized Local Government), but more is needed tution (or responsibility center) needs to establish a func-
from civil society organizations such as the professional tioning monitoring and evaluation system to provide feed-
municipal organizations APEKSI and APKASI. It is clear back on the performance and progress of the reform. This
that, after the establishment of macroeconomic control, information should be used to make course corrections in
all three regimes made efforts to establish supervisory in- the program and for capacity building to develop local abili-
stitutions, but each varied in its emphasis on representa- ties for institutional and policy analysis. To date, Pakistan
tion and the need for societal feedback. has not established a monitoring and evaluation system,
Second, as indicated in table 2, decisions of supervisory nor has the Indonesian government. The Asia Foundation
institutions must be guided by sensible laws relating to tax, supported a three-year effort that began in 2002 called the
budget, debt, participation in governance, and the assign- Indonesia Rapid Decentralization Appraisal, but this ap-
ment of functional roles. Decentralization laws must be in- praisal is external and not linked to the Center for Local
formed by a full understanding of what can go wrong in Government Innovation. Only the Philippines has recog-
public and municipal administration, as well as how to pro- nized the importance of this dynamic learning element to
vide speedy remedies for conflicts with other laws and regu- the success of the devolution.
lations. Many laws have been written by generalists from a Important performance differences were also noted at
top-down planning perspective that contain few insights the implementation level. Devolution of authority under
on the need to deliver local services. In the development of any circumstances requires fiscal support to achieve local
the Local Government Ordinance, the Pakistani regime in- autonomy. This is both a framework and an implementa-

226 Public Administration Review • March/April 2005, Vol. 65, No. 2


tion issue. Funding must be provided for both current ser- fied and institutionalized. Procedures for citizen inputs and
vices and for capital and development projects. Funding access to permits, licenses, and other documents need to
normally takes the form of transfers and can include per- be transparent and efficient to prevent delays and corrup-
formance conditions in exchange for local program dis- tion opportunities. All three countries recognized early on
cretion (block grants). It may also take the form of author- that capacity and structure problems existed at the local
ity to collect and use fees and taxes—broadening local tax levels, which could derail devolution. In Pakistan, efforts
bases. All three countries have recognized the importance have been made through the provincial local government
of providing not only funds, but also authority to mobilize departments to reorganize and restructure operations and
local revenue sources to reduce dependence on central to transfer those models to districts, tehsils, and unions
transfers. Local funding also needs to be linked to the ac- through technical assistance.
tual costs of services rather than simple tallies of previous On the other hand, there has been little recognition of
budget expenditures unrelated to service requirements. the complexity of this process or the need for a formal
Pakistan has attempted to provide revenues, but has had to methodology (such as an organizational efficiency review
deal with provincial reluctance to part with revenue au- or process reengineering) other than political logic. Re-
thority over districts. The provincial finance award still has sults so far have been variable. In Indonesia, the central
not been approved, jeopardizing local fiscal stability. The government is implementing civil service reform and
government of the Philippines supports local fiscal au- slowly transferring reforms to local governments. The
tonomy through local salary coverage and block sectoral Philippines has adopted anti-red-tape measures and taken
grants. This leaves the problem of covering local services steps to reform local governments. The difference is that
with very weak local tax bases (except in larger cities). the latter has permitted local units to reform themselves
As noted, Pakistan developed citizen community boards consistent with Civil Service Commission guidelines.
with access to dedicated funds for spending on local works Pakistan and Indonesia have been more insistent on a
and generation of wider political interest in proposing cookie-cutter approach, that is, a common model provided
needed projects. The citizen community board mechanism by provincial or central government planners. The Phil-
has not been fully implemented. Pakistan has also consid- ippine approach has been more innovative and seems
ered methodologies for estimation of service costs, but likely to produce successes that can be replicated in other
these have not been implemented either at the local level. local governments.
Thus, the bulk of local funds are still derived from central Finally, effective devolution requires measurement and
transfers (National Finance Commission awards) based analysis of results. Funds should be allocated on the basis
on population, and financing is largely unrelated to ser- of performance signals provided by the budgeting and fi-
vice requirements. nancial management system. Information on progress in
The Philippines initially made a mistake in not cover- capacity building, local financing, service results, devel-
ing local salaries and devolution costs through the internal opment projects, and the overall devolution reform itself
revenue allotment. This caused a major political backlash is required for management and policy making. Perfor-
against the reform. Since 1994, a new grant–loan link mance-monitoring systems and the analytical skills to op-
framework has provided strong fiscal support for local erate them are required. The most common means of inte-
governments. The Philippines also provides fiscal incen- grating management and fiscal performance information
tives in the form of a 20 percent addition to the develop- is through a performance-based budgeting system. This
ment fund for good performance. Indonesia earmarks 25 should be consistent with the national chart of accounts,
percent of central transfers for local units, but it is still but based on a flexible system to measure outputs and out-
unrelated to local needs or costs of services. The relation- comes. As is known, many budget formats and service
ship between loans and grants is not coordinated, with per- measures are available, as are means to achieve overall
verse results such as poor cities borrowing and rich cities objectives. While the legal basis for program and perfor-
relying on grants. Fiscal sufficiency is critical and takes a mance budgeting is included in Pakistan’s Local Govern-
long time to work out institutionally and politically. The ment Ordinance, its implementation has been impeded by
Philippines required four to five years to do this. an emphasis on prior legal constraints and systems. Suc-
Decentralization is also a matter of local governance. cessful models in Punjab province have not yet been fol-
The quality of governance will be affected by internal or- lowed elsewhere. Indonesia has shown less interest in per-
ganizational efficiency. Structures and systems need to exist formance-oriented budgeting than in the establishment of
that develop policies implemented by managers with suf- borrowing systems to finance local infrastructure. By con-
ficient resources and authority. Political and administra- trast, the Philippines has a long history with all forms of
tive relationships, especially between elected or appointed performance or results budgeting (zero-based, performance,
mayors, councils, and city departments need to be clari- and program budgeting) and continues to strengthen these

Comparative Decentralization Lessons 227


systems at the central and local levels through associations stitutions. It did not do so initially, but learned from expe-
such as the Association of Local Budget Officers. rience. The other two countries did not follow the Philip-
pine example despite its importance. All three countries
recognized the importance of international and compara-
Findings and Policy Lessons
tive inputs into local government ordinance development.
Two findings are useful for regimes that are contem- But only Indonesia and the Philippines included this in
plating devolution or find themselves in the midst of imple- practice, and the latter more so than the former. It is criti-
mentation. First, regimes should follow the framework cal that regimes review and absorb lessons learned from
summarized in figure 1, and realistically assess the levels regionally similar programs. To proceed on the premise
of background support and technical capacity and cultural- that program conditions are culturally and politically dis-
institutional constraint. On the basis of these assessments, tinct is a high-risk strategy. This research revealed many
regimes should decide whether to proceed with plans or similarities and differences in only three regional programs,
modify ongoing devolution programs. Regimes can respond and regimes ignore such conclusions at their peril.
to perceived gaps in background support and technical ca- As part of the organizational framework for devolution,
pacity in the short run if they believe they can allocate re- all three regimes recognized the importance of capacity
sources to them quickly and effectively (for instance, building. Pakistan has had a harder time severing its links
through the transfer of central or provincial personnel to with ineffective and hidebound state training institutions.
local units). Because support and minimal local capacity The Philippines and Indonesia have changed their institu-
either exists or it does not, these are really short-term is- tions and solicited international donor support with sub-
sues. Regimes also need to assess whether cultural-insti- stantial success. At the same time, only the Philippines has
tutional and civil society constraints arise from temporary recognized the importance of monitoring and evaluation
repression or total absence. In most cases, values and in- systems to the success of devolution. Despite technical as-
stitutions have been repressed, and gaps can be dealt with sistance recommendations in both countries, this is still a
through modification of incentives and training/technical major gap in the Pakistan program. Indonesia is beginning
assistance in the short term. The problem is often that re- to work with the Asia Foundation on a devolution monitor-
gimes intending to implement devolution do not provide ing and evaluation system that will link into the Office of
enough support (such as disorganized supervisory institu- Decentralized Local Government’s Center for Local Gov-
tions and inattention to the need for new kinds of capacity ernment Innovation. All three countries recognized the im-
building), and this creates problems for implementation. portance of local fiscal autonomy, but they also had to rec-
If regimes believe they can (1) give sustained public fiscal oncile mixed political interests in mandating former
and political support to the program, (2) increase the ca- central–provincial responsibilities to local units with tech-
pacity of local decision makers, (3) modify those cultural nical needs for local units to be financially autonomous for
constraints to modern systems requirements, and (4) program success. Provision of sufficient grants, loans, and
strengthen institutions sufficiently, they should proceed tax authority to local units in federal systems requires top-
with decentralization and move to the more immediate is- level support and strong supervisory institutions to push
sue of technical design and sequencing. In all three cases, through the reforms. More fiscal support from the center is
the regimes proceeded to that stage. required in both Indonesia and Pakistan.
Second, it was found that major differences in technical In two other technical design and sequencing areas, the
design and sequencing affect program success. The three Philippines adopted different approaches or priorities.
countries followed similar sequencing, but efforts varied These have been less immediately important for program
within each set of activities. The most advanced (more than success. For example, it is important for devolution suc-
10 years experience) and most successful decentralization cess to restructure local government offices and systems
program of the three was the Philippines. The Philippines and to adopt performance budgeting and management sys-
differed from the other two cases in the performance of tems. While the Philippine program focused to a greater
seven activities (see table 2). The only area in which all extent than the other two cases on these components, it is
three cases followed similar practice was in the deploy- apparent they can be deferred in the medium term without
ment of personnel to lower-tier governments from higher serious jeopardy to the program.
tiers. Even within this category, the three differed in provi- In conclusion, based on the three-case Asian compari-
sion of capacity-building incentives and salary financing son, it can be said that devolution programs that follow the
for newly deployed staff. performance path of the Philippines will be more success-
Five of the seven areas appear to be immediately im- ful. While all regimes must meet the common requirement
portant for decentralization success. For example, only the of initial macroeconomic stability to begin decentraliza-
Philippines stressed broad and responsive supervisory in- tion, subsequently the Philippine program was imple-

228 Public Administration Review • March/April 2005, Vol. 65, No. 2


mented differently in seven areas compared to Pakistan Notes
and Indonesia. It can be concluded that all regimes need to
respond to potential gaps in support and deal with cultural 1. Conversely, there is a case against fiscal decentralization (or
constraints to modern systems of administration and elec- for fiscal centralization), and it is stronger in transitional and
toral representation. Regimes must respond to local op- developing societies than in industrial countries. It is said
portunities by building on existing cultural practices and that centralization favors stabilization, economic growth, and
using them as support mechanisms for the more radical regional equity (see Prud’homme 1994; Guess, Loehr, and
institutional, fiscal, managerial, and political changes that Martinez 1997, 1).
may be required for effective decentralization. Regimes 2. Differences in decentralization refer to how well the activi-
that effectively respond to these shorter-term issues, then, ties are performed, the sequence in which they are performed,
and overall program results. Here, differences can be noted
need to follow the path of the Philippines, with (1) a broad
in how well the technical activities were performed. The se-
supervisory institutional structure, (2) substantial interna-
quence of activity performance was similar in all three cases.
tional inputs into the development of the legal and regula- Data on overall program results are not yet available.
tory framework, (3) innovative capacity-building exercises
3. As the decentralization program advances and statistics are
and institutions, (4) strong interest in monitoring and evalu- reported more systematically, the level of local own-source
ation of the devolution program, (5) provision of sufficient revenues should increase. The new district tier has the power
local fiscal autonomy, (6) efforts to streamline local gov- to set tax rates and bases of such dedicated taxes as the urban
ernment operations, and (7) efforts to replace input bud- immovable property tax. Districts also receive a dedicated
geting and legal management with systems driven by per- annual portion of the sales tax to increase local fiscal au-
formance incentives and targets. Regimes that focus on tonomy. The National Reconstruction Bureau and Ministry
these areas in sequence are likely to be more successful of Finance have largely agreed upon the concept of a divis-
than those that do not, illustrated by Pakistan and Indone- ible pool of provincial resources (provincial finance award)
sia at present. to be shared with the districts on the basis of needs and per-
More research needs to be done on the determinants of formance. To a large extent, districts can establish their own
effective decentralization implementation. This three-stage current and development budget priorities with inputs from
newly created civil society organizations for development
framework offers a modest start. In the future, to provide
projects called citizen community boards.
applied policy guidance to regimes contemplating design
4. The relationship between regime types and the level of sup-
and implementation, research should focus on differences
port for decentralization is not explored here. Manor (1999)
in the performance of technical activities by similar coun- notes that, paradoxically, authoritarian regimes may support
tries and programs. Specifically, research questions should decentralization to increase their base of support.
ask, what factors are associated with variation in perfor- 5. In Ecuador, exchanging tighter reporting requirements on
mance of these activities? Armed with more precise data outlays and adding in performance measures for provision of
and further lessons learned, it should then be possible to greater management authority to transfer and reprogram funds
measure the comparative program impact and link this to during the year was viewed as a positive incentive by finance
differences in performance of technical activities. With this ministry officials. This was accomplished by the incremental
applied information, regimes should have a better assess- reallocation of rewards and requirements that already existed
ment of the potential risks of their decentralization deci- within the budget-execution system. The small change in what
sions and how to minimize them. was viewed as a hopelessly centralist system produced im-
provements in budget management (Guess 1993).
6. On the other hand, the “wrong” kind of intermediary organi-
Acknowledgments zations may exist. The three regimes studied are gambling
that in the medium-term, decentralization will reduce sup-
The author thanks Rachel Quero, director of DAI-Philippines port for unsupportive, negative intermediary groups that still
in Manila, for her support and provision of materials on the de- exist, to some extent, in each country. Warlords and remnants
centralization program there. An earlier version of this article of al-Qaeda in the Pakistani tribal areas are unlikely to en-
was presented at the Association for Budgeting and Financial courage centrally sponsored government decentralization
Management conference in Kansas City, MO, October 10–12, programs that could deprive them of indigenous support.
2002. Disruption of established corruption networks by the devo-
The opinions expressed in this article do not necessarily re- lution of formal governmental control systems (such as in-
flect those of the Open Society Institute or the Local Govern- ternal audit) in Indonesia met the same resistance. Regimes
ment and Public Service Reform Initiative. recognize the threat of such organizations to sound gover-
nance and the rule of law and attempt to reduce their influ-
ence by political co-option strategies. The appropriate mix
of policies to co-opt or modify the behavior of negative groups

Comparative Decentralization Lessons 229


(that is, force and incentives) must be arrived at by each re- Miller, Tom. 1999. Fiscal Federalism in Theory and Practice:
gime on the basis of its own strategic and operational consid- The Philippines Case. Economists Working Paper Series No.
erations. 4, U.S. Agency for International Development.
7. The relevant Indonesian local government associations can North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and
be identified by their Indonesian acronyms: APPSI (provin- Economic Performance. New York: Cambridge University
cial), APEKSI (local and district) and APKASI (mayors). Press.
Pakistan. National Reconstruction Bureau (NRB). 2000. Local
Government: Proposed Plan. Islamabad, Pakistan: National
References Reconstruction Bureau.
Peters, B. Guy. 1978. The Politics of Bureaucracy. New York:
Abbasi, Ansar. 2002. Centre to Shift 2.5 % of GST to Provinces. Longman.
The News (Islamabad), May 26. Prud’homme, Remy. 1994. On the Dangers of Decentralization.
Alm, James, Robert H. Aten, and Roy Bahl. 2001. Can Indone- Policy Research Working Paper No. 1252, World Bank.
sia Decentralize Successfully? Plans, Problems, and Prospects. Putnam, Robert D. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Tra-
Jakarta, Indonesia: U.S. Agency for International Develop- ditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
ment. Press.
Brooke, Peter. 2002. Creating Budget Incentives for Better Per- Razon-Abad, Henedina. 2001. A Decade of Taking Root: Syn-
formance and Budgetary Control. Kansas City, MO: Asso- opsis Report and Action Plan. Manila, Philippines: U.S.
ciation for Budgeting and Financial Management. Agency for International Development/Accelerating Growth,
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, and Hilton Root. 2002. The Political Investment and Liberalization with Equity.
Roots of Poverty: The Economic Logic of Autocracy. Na- Richburg, Keith. 1998. Will Indonesia Be Balkanized? Wash-
tional Interest 68(34): 27–37. ington Post, June 4, A22.
Burki, Shahid Javed. 2001. Decentralization is Essential. The Shah, Anwar. 1994. The Reform of Intergovernmental Fiscal
Dawn (Islamabad), July 10. Relations in Developing and Emerging Market Economies.
Burki, Shahid Javed, and Guillermo Perry. 1998. Beyond the Washington, DC: World Bank.
Washington Consensus: Institutions Matter. Washington, DC: ———. 2003. Presentation at roundtable on: Linking Public
World Bank. Sector and Governance Work with Service Delivery: A The-
Cochrane, Glynn. 1983. Policies for Strengthening Local Gov- matic Discussion Series for the South Asia Region: Decen-
ernment in Developing Countries. Staff Working Paper No. tralization in Pakistan—Early Views. Washington, DC: World
582, World Bank. Bank.
The Economist. 2002. Corporate Culture: When Something Is Sindh, Baluchistan, Northwest Frontier Province, Punjab Prov-
Rotten. July 27, 56. inces (SBNP). 2001. Local Government Ordinance. Islama-
———. 2003. Emerging Market Indicators: Political and Eco- bad, Pakistan: National Reconstruction Bureau.
nomic Stability. February 8, 75. U.S. Agency for International Development (USAID). 2002.
Galang, Mario. 2001. The Status of Decentralization: 10 Years Local Government Finance Policy Study: Assessment of Cur-
after the Passage of the Local Government Code of 1991. rent Conditions and Future Requirements. Bethesda, MD:
Manila, Philippines: U.S. Agency for International Develop- Development Alternatives, Inc./Government Finance Group-
ment/Accelerating Growth, Investment and Liberalization ARD.
with Equity. Winkler, Don, and Randy Hatfield. 2002. The Devolution of
Guess, George M. 1993. Centralization of Expenditure Controls Education in Pakistan. Washington, DC: World Bank.
in Latin America. Public Administration Quarterly 16(3): World Bank. 1994. Philippines: Devolution and Health Services:
376–94. Managing Risks and Opportunities. Washington, DC: Inter-
Guess, George M., William Loehr, and Jorge Martinez Vazquez. national Bank for Reconstruction and Development.
1997. Fiscal Decentralization: A Methodology for Case Stud- ———. 2002a. Structural Adjustment Credit for Government of
ies. Discussion Paper No. 3, Harvard Institute for Interna- the Northwest Frontier Province. Washington, DC: Interna-
tional Development. tional Bank for Reconstruction and Development.
Inglehart, Ronald. 1988. The Renaissance of Political Culture. ———. 2002b. Pakistan: Development Policy Review: A New
American Political Science Review 82(4): 1203–31. Dawn? Washington, DC: International Bank for Reconstruc-
Jacobsen, Lev. 2000. Public Management in Russia: Changes tion and Development.
and Inertia. International Public Management Journal 4(1): Xavier, J.A. 1998. Budget Reform in Malaysia and Australia
27–48. Compared. Public Budgeting and Finance 18(1): 99–119.
Khan, Rashid. 2002. Notes on Tribal Areas Administration. Yap, Maria Eufemia, and Vanessa Sator. 2001. The Status of
Islamabad, Pakistan: Associates in Development. Decentralization of Health Services: A Decade of Birth Pains,
Manor, James. 1999. The Political Economy of Democratic De- Transition and Transformation. Manila, Philippines: U.S.
centralization. Washington, DC: World Bank. Agency for International Development/Accelerating Growth,
Investment and Liberalization with Equity.

230 Public Administration Review • March/April 2005, Vol. 65, No. 2

You might also like