You are on page 1of 113

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.

6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Supply Response of Rice in Ghana: A Co-integration Analysis


John K.M. Kuwornu (Corresponding author) Department of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, P. O. Box LG 68, University of Ghana, Legon-Accra, Ghana Tel: +233 245 131 807 E-mail: jkuwornu@ug.edu.gh / jkuwornu@gmail.com Maanikuu P. M. Izideen Department of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, P. O. Box LG 68, University of Ghana, Legon-Accra, Ghana Tel: +233 241 913 985 E-mail: maanikuu@yahoo.com Yaw B. Osei-Asare Department of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, P. O. Box LG 68, University of Ghana, Legon-Accra, Ghana Tel: +233 209 543 766 E-mail: yosei@ug.edu.gh Received: October 1st, 2011 Accepted: October 11th, 2011 Published: October 30th, 2011

Abstract This study presents an analysis of the responsiveness of rice production in Ghana over the period 19702008. Annual time series data of aggregate output, total land area cultivated, yield, real prices of rice and maize, and rainfall were used for the analysis. The Augmented-Dickey Fuller test was used to test the stationarity of the individual series, and Johansen maximum likelihood criterion was used to estimate the short-run and long-run elasticities. The land area cultivated of rice was significantly dependent on output, rainfall, real price of maize and real price of rice. The elasticity of lagged output (12.8) in the short run was significant at 1%, but the long run elasticity (4.6) was not significant. Rainfall had an elasticity of 0.004 and significant at 10%. Real price of maize had negative coefficient of -0.011 and significant at 10% significance level. This is consistent with theory since a rise in maize price will pull resources away from rice production into maize production. The real price of rice had an elasticity of 2.01 and significant at 5% in the short run and an elasticity of 3.11 in the long run. The error correction term had the expected negative coefficient of -0.434 which is significant at 1%. It was found that in the long run only real prices of maize and rice were significant with elasticities of -0.46 and 3.11 respectively. The empirical results also revealed that the aggregate output of rice in the short run was found to be dependent on the acreage cultivated, the real prices of rice, rainfall and previous output with elasticities of 0.018, 0.01, 0.003 and 0.52 respectively. Real price of rice and area cultivated are significant 10% level of significance while rainfall and lagged output are significant 5%. In the long run aggregate output was found to be dependent on acreage cultivated, real price of rice, and real price maize with elasticities of 0.218, 0.242 and -0.01 respectively at the 1% significance level. The analysis showed that short-run responses in rice production are lower than

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

long-run response as indicated by the higher long-run elasticities. These results have Agricultural policy implications for Ghana. Key Words: Supply response, Rice, Error Correction Model, Co-integration Analysis, Ghana 1. Introduction One of the most influential policy prescriptions for low-income countries ever given by development economists has been to foster industrialization by withdrawing resources from agriculture (e.g., Lewis, 1954). There is robust evidence that the majority of policy makers followed this prescription at least until the mid-1980s. The results of a comprehensive World Bank study (Krueger et al., 1992), for example, show for the period 1960 1985 that in most countries examined, agriculture was taxed both directly via interventions in agricultural markets and indirectly via overvalued exchange rates and import substitution policies. It is not obvious whether the disincentives for agricultural production have continued to exist since the mid-1980s. On the one hand, most developing countries have adopted structural adjustment programs which explicitly aim at a removal of the direct and indirect discrimination against agriculture. But, on the other hand, it is known that many of these programs were not fully implemented, especially in Sub-Saharan Africa (Kherallah et al., 2000; Thiele and Wiebelt 2000; World Bank, 1997). Hence it can be concluded that a certain degree of discrimination still prevails. One of the most important issues in agricultural development economics is supply response of crops. This is because the responsiveness of farmers to economic incentives determines agricultures contribution to the economy especially where the sector is the largest employer of the labour force. This is often the case in third world low income countries. Agricultural pricing policy plays a key role in increasing farm production. Supply response is fundamental to an understanding of this price mechanism (Nerlove and Bachman, 1960). There is a notion that farmers in less developed countries respond slowly to economic incentives such as price and income. Reasons cited for poor response vary from factors such as constraints on irrigation and infrastructure to a lack of complementary agricultural policies. The importance of non-price factors drew adequate attention in the literature: rainfall, irrigation, market access for both inputs and output, and literacy. The reason cited for a low response to prices in less developed economies is the limited access to input and product markets or high transaction costs associated with their use. Limited market access may be either due to physical constraints such as absence of proper road links or the distances involved between the roads and the markets, or institutional constraints like the presence of intermediaries (Mythili, 2008). In Ghana, the goals of agricultural price policy are among others fair incomes for farmers, low food prices for urban consumers, cheap raw materials for manufacturing (Ministry of Food and Agriculture (MOFA), 2005). Price support was one policy that was used by government in targeting these goals. Price support has been used in many countries across the world. The prices of major commodities have been set below world prices using subsidies and trade barriers, guaranteed prices (act as floors) and domestic market forces determining actual prices (Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO), 1996). The effect of liberalization on the growth of agriculture crucially depends on how the farmers respond to various price incentives. For many low-income countries, the impact of structural reforms on economic growth and poverty

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

alleviation crucially depends on the response of aggregate agricultural supply to changing incentives. Despite its policy relevance, the size of this parameter is still largely unknown (Thiele, 2000). Rice is a very important crop especially for those areas where it is produced. Rice is gradually taking the position as the main staple food for the majority of families in Ghana especially in the urban centres. The growth in consumption of rice has been not been matched with a corresponding growth in local production of the crop. Per capita consumption of rice has steadily increased over the years since the 1980s from about 12.4kg/person /year in 1984 to about 20kg/person /year (Statistical Research and Information Division (SRID), 2005). It continued to rise to 38kg/person/year in 2008 (National Rice Development Policy (NRDP), 2009). Over the last decade rice per capita consumption has increased by more than 35%. This is attributed mainly to the rapid urbanization and changes in food consumption patterns. It is estimated based on population and demand growth rates that per capita consumption will reach 41.1kg by 2010 and 63.0kg by 2015 giving an aggregate demand of 1,680,000tons/year (Statistical Research and Information Division (SRID), 2005). Changes in population dynamics and the taste or preference for foreign products is contributing to this trend. These changes are significant considering the rate of population growth. Ghanas population has grown by about 70% from 12.3 million in 1984 to about 21 million in 2004. The population is now 24 million (Ghana Statistical Service (GSS), 2011). The growing quantum of rice imports into the country has also been triggered partly by the fall in world market price. This is largely due to increased output levels in India and South Asia. Massive subsidies in rice exporting countries have also contributed to this phenomenon. Despite all these developments there seem to be a lack of coherent and comprehensive national policy for rice in Ghana. From the period of economic recovery and structural adjustment, the country has had to embark on trade liberalization and the removal of all forms of subsidies on agriculture. These policies no doubt have adversely affected rice production in the country. The smallholder rural farmer is faced with unfair competition from abroad. The role of incentives to farmers has generally been sidelined or ignored in most developing countries due to conditions of trade liberalization and global trade integration. However, a number of empirical studies in other developing economies addressed the question of farmers response to economic incentives and efficient allocation of resources (e.g. Chinyere, 2009). The agricultural sector in Ghana has undergone various policy regimes which has affected both the factor and product market resulting in changes in the structure of market incentives (prices) faced by farmers. Most of these policies have, however, not been crop specific and therefore has wide variations in the quantum of changes in the incentives. This study therefore follows the supply response framework of analysis to examine the dynamics of the supply of rice in Ghana. Effort in this direction will have to be preceded by a thorough analysis of the factors that affects the supply of rice. These teething problems lead to the following research questions; How responsive is rice production to price and non-price factors? What are the long run and short run elasticities of rice production? What are the trends in area cultivated, output and real prices of output? Therefore, objective of the study is threefold: (a) Examine the acreage and output response of rice production in Ghana. (b) Estimate and compare the long run and short run elasticities of rice production. (c) Analyze the trends in output, area cultivated and real prices. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 outlines the methodology. In section 3 we present the empirical applications and the results. Section 4 provides the conclusions.

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

2.0 Methodology This section presents the methodology of the study. 2.1 Linear Regression Linear regression was conducted to determine the growth rates of the variables over the study period. Time in years was regressed on acreage cultivated, aggregate output, real price of rice separately. 2.2 Time series analysis In empirical analysis using time series data it is important that the presence or absence of unit root is established. This is because contemporary econometrics has indicated that regression analysis using time series data with unit root produce spurious or invalid regression results (e.g. Townsend, 2001). Most time series are trended over time and regressions between trended series may produce significant parameters with high R2s, but may be spurious or meaningless (Granger and Newbold, 1974). When using the classical statistical inference to analyze time series data, the results are only stationary when the series are stationary. The solution to this problem was initially provided by Box and Jenkins (1976), by formulating regressions in which the variables were expressed in first difference. Their approach simply assumed that nonstationary data can be made stationary by repeated differencing until stationarity is achieved and then to perform the regression using these differenced variables. However, according to Davidson et al., (1978), this process of repeated differencing even though leads to stationarity of the series; it is achieved at the expense of losing valuable long run information. This posed a new challenge to time series econometrics. The concept of cointegration was introduced to solve these problems (Granger, 1981; Engle and Granger, 1987). By using the method of cointegration an equation can be specified in which all terms are stationary and so allow the use of classical statistical inference. It also retains information about the long run relationship between the levels of variables, which is captured in the stationary co-integrating vector. This vector will comprise the parameters of the long run equilibrium and corresponds to the parameters of the error correction term in the second stage regression (Mohammed, 2005). The cointegration approach takes into consideration the long-run information such that spurious results are avoided. 2.3 Stationarity Tests A data series is said to be stationary if it has a constant mean and variance. That is the series fluctuates around its mean value within a finite range and does not show any distinct trend over time. In a stationary series displacement over time does not alter the characteristics of a series in the sense that the probability distribution remains constant over time. A stationary series is thus a series in which the mean, variance and covariance remain constant over time or in other words do not change or fluctuate over time. In a stationary series the mean always has the tendency to return to its mean value and to fluctuate around it in a more or less constant range, while a non-stationary series has a changing mean at different points in time and its variance change with the sample size (Mohammed, 2005). The conditions of stationarity can be illustrated by the following: Yt = Yt-1 + t t=1T (1)

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Where t is a random walk with mean zero and constant variance. If < 1, the series Yt stationary and if = 1 then the series Yt is non-stationary and is known as random walk. In other words the mean, variance and covariance of the series Yt changes with time or have an infinite range. However Y t can be made stationary by differencing. Differencing can be done multiple times on a series depending on the number of unit roots a series has. If a series becomes stationary after differencing d times, then the series contains d unit roots and hence integrated of order d denoted as I (d). Thus, in equation (1) where = 1, Yt has a unit root. A stationary series could also exhibit other properties such as when there are different kinds of time trends in the variable. The DF (Dickey-Fuller)-statistic used in testing for unit root is based on the assumption that t is white noise. If this assumption does not hold, it leads to autocorrelation in the residuals of the OLS regressions and this can make invalid the use of the DF-statistic for testing unit root. There are two approaches to solve this problem (Towsend, 2001). In the first instance the equations to be tested can be generalized. Secondly the DF-statistics can be adjusted. The most commonly used is the first approach which is the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test. t is made white noise by adding lagged values of the dependent variable to the equations being tested, thus: Yt = (1 1) Yt-1 + Yt = 2 + (2 1) Yt-1 + Yt= 3+3t(31)Yt-1+
I I

Yt-I + t
I

(2) (3) (4)

Yt-I + t

Yt-I + t

The ADF test uses the same critical values with DF. The results of the ADF test for unit roots for each of the data series used in this study are presented in in the next section using equation (4) where Yt is the series under investigation, t is the time trend, 3 is the constant term and t are white noise residuals. Eviews was used in the analysis, all the data series was tested for stationarity and the results are presented in section three. 2.4 Cointegration Cointegration is founded on the principle of identifying equilibrium or long run relationships between variables. If two data series have a long run equilibrium relationship it implies their divergence from the equilibrium are bounded, that is they move together and are cointegrated. Generally for two or more series to be co-integrated two conditions have to be met. One is that the series must all be integrated to the same order and secondly a linear combination of the variables exist which is integrated to an order lower than that of the individual series. If in a regression equation the variables become stationary after first differencing, that is I (1), then the error term from the cointegration regression is stationary, I (0) (Hansen and Juselius, 1995). If the cointegration regression is presented as: Yt = + Xt + t (5) where Yt and Xt are both I (1) and the error term is I (0), then the series are co-integrated of order I (1,0 ) and measures the equilibrium relationship between the series Yt and Xt and t is the deviation from the long-run equilibrium path. An equilibrium relationship between the variables implies that even though Yt and Xt series may have trends, or cyclical seasonal variations, the movement in one are matched by

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

movements in the other. The concept of cointegration has implications for economists. The economic interpretation that is accepted is that if in the long-run two or more series Y t and Xt themselves are nonstationary, they will move together closely over time and the difference between them is constant (stationary) (Mohammed 2005). 2.4.1 Testing for Cointegration There are two most commonly used methods for testing cointegration. The Augmented Dickey-Fuller residual based test by Engle and Granger (1987), and the Johansen Full Information Maximum Likelihood (FIML) test (Johansen and Juselius, 1990). For the purpose of this study the Johansen Full Information Maximum Likelihood test is used due to its advantages. The major disadvantage of the residual based test is that it assumes a single co-integrating vector. But if the regression has more than one co-integrating vector this method becomes inappropriate (Johansen and Juselius, 1990). The Johansen method allows for all possible co-integrating relationships and allows the number of co-integrating vectors to be determined empirically. 2.4.2 Johansen Full Information Maximum Likelihood Approach The Johansen approach is based on the following Vector Autoregression Zt = AtZt-1 + + AkZt-k + t (6) Where Zt is an (n1) vector of I(1) variables (containing both endogenous and exogenous variables), At is (nn) matrix of parameters and t is (n1) vector of white noise errors. Zt is assumed to be nonstationary hence equation (6) can be rewritten in first difference or error correction form as; Zt = 1Zt-1 + + k-1Zt-k+1 + Zt-k + t where 1 = - ( 1- A1 - A2 - -Ai), (i = 1, , k-1) and = - (1- A1-A2- -Ak). 1 gives the short run estimates while gives the long run estimates. Information on the number of cointegrating relationships among variables in Zt is given by the rank of the matrix . If the rank of matrix r, is 0 < r > n, there are r linear combinations of the variables in Z t that are stationary. Thus can be decomposed into two matrices and where is the error correction term and measures the speed of adjustment in Zt and contains r co-integrating vectors, that is the cointegration relationship between nonstationary variables. If there are variables which are I(0) and are significant in the long run co-integrating space but affect the short run model then equation (7) can be rewritten as: Zt = 1Zt-1 + Zt-k + vDt + t where Dt represents the I(0) variables. To test for co-integrating vector two likelihood ratio (LR) tests are used. The first is the trace test statistic; trace = -2lnQ = -T ) (9) (8) (7)

Which test the null hypothesis of r co-integrating vectors against the alternative that it is greater than r. The second test is known as the maximal-eigen value test: max = -2 ln(Q: r 1 r + 1 = -T ln(1-r+1 ) (10) which test the null hypothesis of r co-integrating vectors against the alternative of r+1 co-integrating vectors. The trace test shows more robustness to both skewness and excess kurtosis in the residuals than the

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

maximal eigen value test (Harris, 1995). The error correction formulation in (7) includes both the difference and level of the series hence there is no loss of long run relationship between variables which is a characteristic feature of error correction modeling. It should be noted that in using this method, the endogenous variables included in the Vector Autoregression (VAR) are all I(1), also the additional exogenous variables which explain the short run effect are I(0). The choice of lag length is also important and the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC), the Scharz Bayesian Criterion (SBC) and the Hannan-Quin Information Criterion (HQ) are used for the selection. According to Hall (1991) since the process might be sensitive to lag length, different lag orders should be used starting from an arbitrary high order. The correct order is where a restriction on the lag length is rejected and the results are consistent with theory. 2.5 Error Correction Models (ECMs) The idea behind the mechanism of error correction is that a proportion of disequilibrium from one period is corrected in the next period in an economic system (Engle and Granger, 1987). The process of making a data series stationary is either done by differencing or inclusion of a trend. A series that is made stationary by including a trend is trend stationary and a series that is made stationary by differencing is difference stationary. The process of transforming a data series into stationary series leads to loss of valuable long run information (Engle and Granger, 1987). Error correction models helps to solve this problem. The Granger representation theorem is the basis for the error correction model which indicates that if the variables are cointegrated, there is a long-run relationship between them and can be described by the error correction model. The following equation shows an ECM of agricultural supply response involving the variables Y and X in its simplest form: Yt = Xt (Yt-1 Xt-1)+t (11) Where t is the disturbance term with zero mean, constant variance and zero covariance. Parameter takes into account the short run effect on Y of the changes in X, while measures the long-run equilibrium relationship between Y and X that is: Yt = Xt + t (12) Where Yt-1 Yt-1 + t-1 measures the divergence (errors) from long-run equilibrium. Also measures the extent of error correction by adjustment in Y and its negative sign indicates that the adjustment is in the direction which restores the long-run relationship (Hallam and Zanoli, 1993). In order to estimate equation (5), Engle and Granger (1987) proposed a two stage process. Firstly the static long run cointegration regression (6) is estimated to test cointegration between the two variables. If cointegration exists the lagged residuals from equation (5) are used as error correction term in the Error Correction Model (in equation 6) to estimate the short run equilibrium relationship between the variables in the second stage. The validity of the Error Correction Models (ECMs) depends upon the existence of a long-run or equilibrium relationship among the variables (Mohammed, 2005). The Error Correction Model (ECM) has several advantages. It contains a well-behaved error term and avoids the problem of autocorrelation. It allows consistent estimation of the parameters by incorporating both short-run and long-run effects. Most importantly all terms in the ECM are stationary. It ensures that no information on the levels of the variables is lost or ignored by the inclusion of the disequilibrium terms

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

(Mohammed, 2005). ECM solves the problems of spurious correlation because ECMs are formulated in terms of first difference which eliminates trends from the variables (Ganger and Newbold, 1974). It avoids the unrealistic assumption of fixed supply based on stationary expectations in the partial adjustment model. 2.6 Supply Response Models This study estimated the total area cultivated and aggregate output of rice in Ghana using double logarithmic regression models. Area cultivated of rice (lgarea) is a function of own price (Lrp), rainfall (lgrain), aggregate output (lgoutput) and price of maize (lmp). The equation used for the regression is: Lgarea = f1 (Lgoutput, Lrp, Lgrain, Lmp) of maize (Lmp), rainfall (lgrain). The estimating equation is: Lgoutput = f2 (lgrain, Lrp, Lmp, Lgarea)1. 3. Empirical Application and Results 3.1 Results for linear regression Table 1: The results of the regression analysis for the trend of the variables against time Variable Coefficient Std error t-statistic R2 F-statistic Lgarea 1.334274 1.149167 1.61079 0.035154 0.253046 Lgoutput -13.86625 68.09380 -0.20364 0.005889 0.844432 lgyield -25.99348 35.51112 -0.73198 0.071100 0.487957 Lrp 2.588941 5.221601 4.956136 0.399186 24.58311 Prob 0.2530 0.8444 0.4880 0.0000 (14) (13) Aggregate output of rice (lgoutput) is a function of the area cultivated (lgarea), the price of rice (Lrp), price

As can be seen from table 1 the results indicated that the regression for area, output and yield turned out insignificant. Only the trend of real price of rice was significant at 1% significance level. Real rice price yielded a positive coefficient of 2.589 which implies that for each year the real price of rice grew by 2.589 units. 3.2 Unit Root Test Results As a requirement for cointegration analysis the data was tested for series stationarity and to determine the order of integration of the individual variables. For cointegration analysis to be valid all series must be integrated of the same order usually of order one (Towsend, 2001). Eviews was used to perform these tests. The data series on annual acreage cultivated (Lgarea), aggregate output (Lgoutput), aggregate yield (Lgyield), real price of rice (Lrp), real price of maize (Lmp), rainfall (Lgrain) was tested for unit root for the study period 1970 - 2008. The Augmented Dickey-Fuller test was used for this test. The results are presented below.

Table 2: Results of unit root test at levels Series ADF test Mackinnon statistic critical value
1

Lag-length

Prob

Conclusion

Price of maize is included because we assume that the same resources (land type, fertilizer etc.) can be used to produce both maize and rice. Hence, a rise in the price of maize will pull resources away from rice production to maize production.

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
Lgarea Lgoutput Lgyield Lmp Lrp Lgrain 2.221125 1.519278 0.103318 0.378290 1.429037 3.006033 3.615588 5.119808 4.580648 3.621023 3.615588 2.963972

www.iiste.org

2 2 2 2 2 7

0.2024 0.4582 0.9419 0.9026 0.5579 0.0457

Non-stationary Non-stationary Non-stationary Non-stationary Non-stationary Stationary

The results of the unit root test after first differencing are presented in table 3. Table 3: Results of unit root test at first differences Series ADF test Mackinnon statistic critical value Lgarea 7.517047 3.621023 Lgoutput 9.577098 3.621023 Lgyield 7.517047 3.621023 Lmp 10.02189 3.621023 Lrp 6.346392 3.626784

Lag-length 2 2 2 2 2

Prob 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

Conclusion I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1)

Note; All variables are in log form. The ADF method test the hypothesis that H 0 : X ~ I(1), that is, has unit root (non-stationary) against H1 : X ~ I(0), that is, no unit root (stationary). The Mackinnon critical values for the rejection of the null hypothesis of unit root are all significant at 1%. Lgarea denotes log of area cultivated, Lgoutput denotes log total output, Lgyield denotes log of yield, Lmp denotes log of maize price, Lrp denotes log of rice price and Lgrain denotes log of rainfall. The results of the unit root tests showed that all the series are non-stationary at levels except for rainfall which is stationary at levels as shown in table 2 above. However as expected all the non-stationary series became stationary after first differencing. From table 2 the null hypothesis of unit root could not be rejected at levels since none except rainfall of the ADF test statistics was greater than the relevant Mackinnon Critical values. Hence the null of the presence of unit root is accepted. However the hypothesis of unit root in all series was rejected at 1% level of significance for all series after first difference since the ADF test statistics are greater than the respective Mackinnon critical values as shown in table 3 above. 3.3 Cointegration Results When the order of integration of the data series have been established, the next step in the process of analysis is to determine the existence or otherwise of cointegration in the series. This is to establish the existence of valid long-run relationships between variables. Basically there are two most commonly used methods to test for cointegration. These were suggested by Engle and Granger (1987) and Johansen and Juselius (1990). This study applies the Johansen approach which provides likelihood ratio tests for the presence of number of co-integrating vectors among the series and produces long-run elasticities. The Error correction model was then used to estimate short-run elasticities.

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
3.3.1 Supply Response of Rice Output

www.iiste.org

Firstly, the Vector Error Correction Modeling (VECM) procedure using the Johansen method involves defining an unrestricted Vector Autoregression (VAR) using the following equation. Zt=AtZt-1++AkZt-1+t results are shown in table 4. (15) Likelihood Ratio (LR) tests were conducted with maximum of three lags due to the short time series. The

Table 4: Results for lag selection output model VAR Lag Order Selection Criteria Endogenous variables: OUTPUT AREA MP RP Exogenous variables: C RAIN Lag 0 1 2 3 LogL -1208.968 -1184.928 -1174.563 -1138.068 LR NA 37.77692 13.32579 36.49514* FPE 6.64e+32 3.84e+32 6.37e+32 1.92e+32* AIC 86.92626 86.35198 86.75452 85.29058* SC 87.30689* 87.49387 88.65766 87.95499 HQ 87.04262 86.70107 87.33633 86.10511*

* indicates lag order selected by the criterion LR: sequential modified LR test statistic (each test at 5% level) FPE: Final prediction error AIC: Akaike information criterion SC: Schwarz information criterion HQ: Hannan-Quinn information criterion LogL: Log-likelihood

The results indicate that the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and the Hannan-Quin information criterion (HQ) selected lag order three while the Scharz Bayesian Criterion (SBC) selected the lag order zero. Thus, this study selects the lag order three as the order for the VAR models. The next step in the Johansen method is to test for the number of co-integrating vectors among the series in the model. The results for the cointegration test imply that both the trace test and the maximum eigen value test selects the presence of one co-integrating vector, thus it can be concluded that the variables in the model are cointegrated. The Johansen model is a form of Error Correction Model. When only one co-integrating vector is established its parameters can be interpreted as estimates of long run co-integrating relationship between the variables (Hallam and Zanoli, 1993). This implies that the estimated parameter values from this equation when normalized on output are the long run elasticities for the model. Eviews automatically produces the normalized estimates. These coefficients represent estimates of long-run elasticities with respect to area cultivated, real price of rice and real price of maize. The normalized cointegration equation

10

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
for rice output is given below; Output=0.216748area+0.241522rp-0.009975mp-12841.69

www.iiste.org

(16)

Since cointegration has been established among the variables, then the dynamic ECM can be used for supply response analysis since it provides information about the speed of adjustment to long run equilibrium and avoids the spurious regression problem between the variables (Engle and Granger, 1987). The ECM for rice output is presented as; output = 0+
1i

outputt-i +

2i

areat-i +

3i

rpt-I +

4i

mpt-I + 5rain ECt-I

(17)

Where ECt-I = (1outputt-I 2areat-I 3rpt-I 4mpt-I) In the ECM model above, the s explain the short run effect of changes in the explanatory variables on the dependent variable whereas s represent the long run equilibrium effect. EC t-I is the error correction term and correspond to the residuals of the long run cointegration relationship, that is the normalized equation (16). The negative sign on the error correction term indicates that adjustments are made towards restoring long run equilibrium. This representation ensures that short run adjustments are guided by and consistent with the long run equilibrium relationship. This method provides estimates for the short run elasticities, that is the coefficients of the difference terms and, whereas the parameters from the Johansen cointegration regression are estimates of the long run elasticities (Townsend and Thirtle, 1994). In selecting the best ECM estimates, models with lag lengths are estimated and those with insignificant parameters are eliminated. Note that the estimates presented above represent the short run effect of the explanatory variables on the dependent variable. The long run effect is captured by the estimates of the normalised Johansen regression results presented in equation (16). The diagnostic tests are the t-ratio test of the coefficients, LM test for autocorrelation and the Jarque Berra test for normality of residuals. Table 5: ECM results for rice output Variable Coefficient lgarea lgoutput(-1) lgRain lgmp lgrp Residual R2 (0.754242) 0.017611 0.523393 0.003740 -0.001107 0.009922 -0.174253 F-statistic (2.523411) t-statistic 0.668907 2.283959 0.997918 -0.298174 0.307758 -1.321005 Prob(F-stat) 0.058261 Prob 0.0510 0.0319 0.0328 0.7683 0.0761 0.0043

It indicates that aggregate rice output is dependent on area cultivated, previous years output, and previous years price of rice. The coefficient of maize price was not significant. An R2 of 0.754 indicates that 75% of the variation in the dependent variable can be accounted for by

11

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

variation in the explanatory variables. The results indicate that area cultivated was significant at 10%, with elasticity of 0.0176, which implies that a one percent increase in area cultivated of rice will lead to a 0.018 % increase in output in the short run. This is rather on the low side. This can be attributed to the fact that an increase in the land cultivated without a necessary increase in the resources of the farmer will increase adverse effect on the minimal resources available to the farmer hence resulting in this marginal increase in output. This result also indicates that the productivity of the farmer reduces with increase in farm size. The long run elasticity of area cultivated is 0.2167 (in equation (16)) is higher than the 0.0176 for the short run. This indicates that over the long run farmers adjust their farm sizes more to output than in the short run. That is, a 1% increase in area cultivated will lead to 0.217% increase in output in the long run. Lagged output has elasticity of 0.523393 in the short run and is significant at the 5% significance level implying that a one percent increase in output in a year will lead to a 0.52% increase in output the subsequent year. This simply means that an increase in output will make capital available for the farmer to invest in the subsequent years rice production activities. This is only true if the additional resource is invested into the following years rice production activities. Rainfall is significant at 5%. An elasticity of 0.003740 for rainfall indicates that a 1% increase in rainfall will result in a 0.004% rise in output. This low impact of rainfall can be explained by the fact that a large proportion of total rice output is produced under the irrigation projects across the country. This makes the response of output to rainfall highly inelastic. A coefficient of 0.009922 which is significant at 10% for real price of rice indicates that a 1% rise in real prices will lead to 0.01% increase in output the subsequent year in the short run. This makes prices also inelastic. This low rice price elasticity suggests that farmers do not always necessarily benefit from increasing prices due to the structure of the marketing system. Middlemen and other marketing channel members purchase the rice from farmers at the farm gate and thereafter transport it to market centres to be sold. Hence when there is a rise in prices a little fraction of it is transmitted to the famer. The low price elasticity could also be attributed to the fact that farmers are hindered by an array of constraints such as land tenure issues, rainfall variability, lack of capital resources and credit facilities which limits their capacity to respond to price incentives. The long run coefficient of 0.2415 indicates that 1% percent increase in real prices will lead to a 0.24% increase in output. The long run elasticity far exceeds the short run. This is because over the long run when prices show a continual rise, farmers are able to accumulate capital enough to enhance production. The residual which is the error correction term is significant at 1% and has the expected negative sign. It measures the adjustment to equilibrium. Its coefficient of -0.174 indicates that the 17.4% deviation of rice output from long run equilibrium is corrected for in the current period. This slow adjustment can be attributed to the fact that famers in the short run are constrained by technical factors as mentioned earlier which limits their ability to adjust immediately to price incentives. In the long run maize price is significant at 1%. With a negative coefficient of 0.009975 it implies that a 1% increase in the price of maize will lead to 0.01% reduction in the output of rice. This is to say that resources will be diverted to maize production relative to rice production leading to the fall in rice output. However, Maize price was not significant in the short run. The results of the LM test of serial correlation for up to fifth order show that there is no serial correlation in the data set.

12

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
3.3.2 Supply Response of Area Cultivated

www.iiste.org

Testing for the selection of lag length yielded the same results for both the acreage and output models. Hence the same lag order three is therefore used for the Vector Error Correction model (VEC). The trace test selects one co-integrating vector while the eigen value test selects two co-integrating vectors. But since the trace test is the more powerful test (Mohammed, 2005), the result from the trace test is used here. Thus the acreage model has one co-integrating vector. The normalised cointegration equation for area cultivated is given as; lgarea =4.613649lgoutput+3.11429lrp0.46020lmp59247 The ECM for area cultivated is presented as; lgarea = 0 +
1i

(18)

lgoutputt-i +

2i

lgareat-i +

3i

lgrpt-I +

4i

lgmpt-I +

5l

lgrain ECt-I

(19) Where ECt-I = (1areat-I 2outputt-I 3rpt-I 4mpt-I) The result of the estimated ECM is given in table 6 below. Table 6: ECM results for area cultivated Variable Coefficient lgarea(-1) 0.169747 lgoutput(-1) 12.80810 lgRain 0.003984 lmp(-1) -0.011350 lrp(-1) 2.016747 Residual -0.435411 R2 (0.770669) F-statistic (1.707148) t-statistic 1.343021 1.816372 0.138622 -0.401819 1.440683 -1.043641 Prob(F-stat) 0.017301 Prob 0.1192 0.0824 0.0891 0.0691 0.0265 0.0047

An R2 of 0.77067 indicates that 77% 0f the variation in the dependent variable is accounted for by variation in the explanatory variables. Output is significant at 10% with an elasticity of 12.80 indicating that a 1% increase in output this year will increase land cultivated in the subsequent year by 12.8% in the short run. Thus acreage cultivated is highly elastic with respect to output. An increase output level gives the farmers an opportunity to acquire necessary resources and equipment to put more land under cultivation. Output elasticity is even higher than that for real prices. This can be attributed to the fact that a large proportion of output is for household consumption and thus is independent of prices. Increased output alone is enough motivation to increase acreage under cultivation. In the long run output is insignificant. This because in the long run land will get exhausted and output will be dependent on productivity (and not the area of land cultivated). Rainfall is significant at 10% with a coefficient of 0.003984; this implies a 1% increase in rainfall leads to 0.004% increase in area cultivated. This low response to rain can be attributed to the fact that large areas under rice cultivation are in irrigated fields which depends less on rainfall for cultivation. Rainfall is an exogenous variable (I(0)), hence it measures short run effect.

13

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Maize price is significant at 10% with a negative coefficient of -0.011350 in the short run and -0.460 in the long run. This means over the long run if maize prices are continually increasing farmers will commit more resources into maize farming relative to rice farming. Thus as the price of maize rises area under rice cultivation reduces both in the short and long run. In the short run a 1% increase in maize price reduces area cultivated of rice by 0.0114% and by 0.46% in the long run. Real price of rice was significant at 5% with elasticities of 2.017 and 3.11 in the short run and long run respectively, thus price is elastic. This implies a 1% percent increase in real price of rice will result 2.017% and 3.11% increase in acreage cultivated in the short run and long run respectively. This is expected since in the long run farmers are able to adjust to overcome some the major challenges of production and hence are able to adjust more to price incentives. The error correction term has the expected negative sign and with a coefficient of 0.4354 indicating that 43.54% of the deviation from long run equilibrium is corrected for in the current period. The results of the test for serial correlation show that is no autocorrelation in the series. The Jarque-Berra test statistic of 10.18 with probability value of 0.25 implies that the residuals are normally distributed. 4. Conclusions Economic theory in the past had been based on the assumption that time series data is stationary and hence standard statistical techniques (Ordinary Least Squares regression (OLS)) designed for stationary series was used. However, it is now known that many time series data are non-stationary and therefore using traditional OLS methods will lead to invalid or spurious results. To address this problem, the method of differencing was introduced. Differencing according to Granger however leads to loss of valuable long-run information. Granger and Newbold (1974) introduced the technique of cointegration which takes into account long-run information therefore avoiding spurious results while maintaining long-run information. This study presents an analysis of the responsiveness of rice production in Ghana over the period 19702008. Annual time series data of aggregate output, total land area cultivated, yield, real prices of rice and maize, and rainfall were used for the analysis. The Augmented-Dickey Fuller test was used to test the stationarity of the individual series. The Johansen maximum likelihood criterion is used to estimate the short-run and long-run elasticities. The trend analysis for rice output, rice price, acreage cultivated, and yield revealed that only rice price is significant at 1% significance level. The results imply that for each year, the price of rice will increase by 2.589 units. All the time series data that was used were tested for unit root. They were found to be non-stationary at levels but stationary after first differencing at the one percent significance level except for rainfall which was stationary at levels at the 5% significance level. The Likelihood Ratio tests selection of lag order selected order three by the AIC and HQ criteria for both models. The Johansen cointegration test selected one cointegration vector (in both rice output and rice price models) indicating that the variables are cointegrated. The diagnostic tests of serial correlation and normality test was done using the Lagrange Multiplier test for autocorrelation and the Jarque-Berra test for normality of residuals. The results indicate no serial correlation and normally distributed residuals. The land area cultivated of rice was significantly dependent on output, rainfall, real price of maize and real price of rice. The elasticity of lagged output was 12.8 in the short run and was significant at 1%. However,

14

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
this elasticity was not significant in the long run.

www.iiste.org

Rainfall had an elasticity of 0.004 and significant at 10%. Also real price of maize had negative coefficient of -0.011 which was significant at 10%. This is consistent with theory since a rise in maize price will pull resources away from rice production into maize production. The coefficient of the real price of maize estimated by Chinere (2009) was -0.066 for rice farming in Nigeria. This is higher than the -0.011 estimated for Ghana (in this study). The real price of rice had an elasticity of 2.01 and significant at 5% in the short run and an elasticity of 3.11 in the long run. The error correction term had the expected negative coefficient of -0.434 which is significant at 1%. It was found that in the long run only real prices of maize and rice were significant with elasticities of -0.46 and 3.11 respectively. The error correction estimated by Chinere (2009) was -0.575. This indicates that adjustment to long run equilibrium is faster in Nigeria. This could be attributed to better agricultural infrastructure in Nigeria compared to Ghana. The error correction for Indian rice in the rice zone as estimated by Mohammed (2005) was -0.415. This could be attributed to the fact that Indian agriculture was highly constrained by land problems hence leaving room for little adjustments in terms of increasing acreage cultivated. The aggregate output of rice in the short run was found to be dependent on the acreage cultivated, the real prices of rice, rainfall and previous output with elasticities of 0.018, 0.01, 0.004 and 0.52 respectively. Real price of rice and area cultivated are significant 10% level of significance while rainfall and lagged output are significant 5%. In the long run aggregate output was found to be dependent on acreage cultivated and the real price of rice and real price maize with elasticities of 0.218, 0.242 and -0.01 respectively at the 1% significance level. Mythili (2008) used panel data to estimate the supply response of Indian farmers. His findings also support the view that farmers response to price is low in the short-run and their adjustment to reaching desired levels is low for food grains. The analysis showed that short-run response in rice production is lower than long-run response as indicated by the higher long-run elasticities. This is because in the short run the farmers are constrained by the lack of resources needed to respond appropriately to incentives. In the short-run inputs such as land, labour, and capital are fixed. To address these concerns government should devise policies to make land available to farmers so that prospective farmers could increase acreage cultivated. More irrigation facilities should be constructed to put more land under cultivation. It was also observed that the acreage model had higher elasticities than the output model. Thus farmers tend to increase acreage cultivated in response to incentives. This implies that farmers have more control over land than the other factors that influence output. Efforts should be put in place to make the acquisition of inputs such as tractors and fertilizer more accessible and affordable to farmers, and to improve the road network linking farming communities and the urban centres. Price control policy should be introduced and enforced to address the problem of frequent price fluctuation which is the main reason for the low response to prices. Since farmers are aware of these price fluctuations they are reluctant to immediately respond positively to price rises. Though there is a market for rice in Ghana, recent developments have shown that consumers prefer foreign

15

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

polished rice; therefore, government should put in place the needed infrastructure to process the locally produced rice to ensure the sustainability of local rice production. References Box G. E. P. and Jenkins G. M. (1976). Time Series Analysis: Forecasting and Control, 2nd ed, San Francisco, Holden-day. Cambridge University Press. Chinyere G. O. (2009). Rice output supply response to changes in real prices in Nigeria; An Autoregressive Distributed Lag Model approach. Journal of Sustainable Development in Africa, 11(4), 83 -100. Clarion University of Pennsylvania, Clarion, Pennsylvania. Davidson, J. E. H., Handry, D. F., Srba F., and Yeo S. (1978). Econometric modeling of aggregate time series relationships between consumers expenditures and income in the UK, Economic Journal. 88, 661692. Dickey D. A. and Fuller W. A, (1981). Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit root. Econometrica, 49, 1057-1072. Engle R. F, and Granger C. W. J. (1987). Cointegration and error correction: Representation, estimation and testing, Econometrica, 55, 251 -276. FAO (1996). Report of expert consultation on the technological evolution and impact for sustainable rice production in Asia and Pacific. FAO-RAP Publication No. 1997/23, 206 pp. Regional Office for the Asia and the Pacific. Granger C. W. J. (1981). Some properties of time series data and their use in econometric model specification. Journal of Econometrics, 16 (1), 121-130. Granger C. W. J. and Newbold P. (1974). Spurious Regression in Econometrics, Journal of Econometrics 2, 111-120. Ghana Statistical Service (2011). Ghana Statistical Service release. Hall S. G. (1991). The effect of varying length VAR on the maximum likelihood estimates of cointegrating vectors. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 38, 317- 323. Hallam D. and Zanoli R. (1993). Error Correction Models and Agricultural Supply Response. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 20, 151-166.

16

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Hansen S. and Juselius K. (1995). Cats in rats: Cointegration analysis of time series, Evanston, Illinois. Harris R, (1995). Using cointgration analysis in econometric modeling. Prentice Hall, Harvester Wheatsheaf, England. Johansen S. and Juselius K. (1990). Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on cointegration- with application to the demand for money. Oxford bulletin of Economics and statistics, 52, 170-209. Kherallah M C., Delgado E., Gabri-Madhin N. M., and Johnson M., (2000). The Road Half Travelled: Agricultural Market Reform in Sub-Saharan Africa. International Food Policy Research Institute, Food Policy Report 10. Washington D.C. Kiel Working Paper No. 1016. Krueger A. O., Schiff M, and Valds A. (1992). The Political Economy of Agricultural Pricing Policies. A World Bank Comparative Study, Baltimore. Lewis W. A, (1954). Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour. Manchester School 22: 139191. Ministry of Food and Agriculture, Ghana (2005), Ministry of Food and Agriculture report. Mohammed S. (2005). Supply response analysis of major crops in different agro-ecological zones in Punjab. Pakistan Journal of Agricultural Research, 2007, 124 (54). Mythili G. (2008). Acreage and yield response for major crops in the pre and post reform periods in India: A dynamic panel data approach, Report prepared for IGIDR-ERS/USDA project: Agricultural markets and policy, Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai. Nerlove M. and Bachman K L., (1960). Analysis of the changes in agricultural supply, Problems and Approaches. Journal of farm economics. 3(XLII), 531-554. National Rice Policy Development (2009). National Rice Policy Development Report. Statistical Research and Information Division (SRID). (2005). Statistics Research and Information Department Release. Thiele R., (2000). Estimating the aggregate supply response, a survey of techniques and results for developing countries. Kiel Institute of world Economics Duuesternbrooker Weg 120 241015 Kiel, Germany. Kiel working paper No 1016 Rainer Thiele. Thiele R, and Wiebelt M, (2000). Adjustment lending in Sub Saharan Africa Kiel Institute of World

17

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Economics. Kiel Discussion Papers 357, Kiel. Tobacco In Zimbabwe Contributed Paper Presented at the 41st Annual. Townsend R and Thirtle C. (1994). Dynamic acreage response. An error correction model for maize and tobacco in Zimbabwe. Occasional paper number 7 of the International Association Agricultural Economics. Townsend T. P. (2001). "World Cotton Market Conditions". Beltwide Cotton Conferences, Proceedings, Cotton Economics and Marketing Conference, National Cotton Council, Memphis, TN, pp. 401-405. World Bank. (1997). "Cotton and Textile Industries: Reforming to Compete." Vol. I, II, Rural Development Sector Unit; South Asian Region, World Bank. Report No. 16347- IN, Washington, D.C, 1997.

18

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Sustainable Use of Water Resources in the Form of Pisciculture to Generate Income in West Bengal -A study report.
Bairagya Ramsundar Department of Economics, SambhuNath College, Labpur, Birbhum, West Bengal, India, Pin-731303 Mobile No. +919474308362 Fax: +913463 266255, E-mail: ramsundarbairagya@gmail.com Received: October 1st, 2011 Accepted: October 11th, 2011 Published: October 30th, 2011 Abstract Though the two-third of earths volume is comprised of water the world is facing the problem of scarcity of fresh- water. Because most of the water is sea water which is salt in nature. It is the modern day tragedy that due to the scarcity of these valuable lives saving natural resources life will exist no more. So the sustainable use of this resource is very much important today. India was blessed with vast inland natural water resources. But Indian Economy faces the problem of proper utilization of these huge water resources spread over its vast stretches of land. A proper policy for utilization of these resources would become a governing direction of economic growth. The role of fisheries in the countrys economic development is amply evident. It generates employment, reduces poverty, generates income, increases food supply and maintains ecological balance between flora and fauna. Scientists have shown that 3 bighas forest areas are equivalent to 1 bigha plank origin in water bodies which create more O2. This paper intends to develop a scientific plan use of water with a view to sustainable management of water resources to generate income from fishery in the field of pisciculture by using the scarce water resources in a sustainable eco-friendly manner. Keywords: Ecology, Growth, Perishable, Pisciculture, Pollution, Project, Sustainable development, Composite fish culture

1. Introduction

According to 2001 Census India is the second (next to China) largest populous country in the world about 17.5% of world populations live in India which covers only 2.4% (Dutt R. and Sundharam K.P.M. 2009) of geographical land area. The density of population is 324 persons per sq. km. If the current growth rate of

19

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

population (i.e. 2.11% per annum) continues within 2030 India will be the most populous country in the world creating a food scarcity and a huge amount of unemployment in a massive scale. About 68% of total population spends their livelihood from agriculture and the per capita income is very low. Water scarcity is too much related to food scarcity. Hence it is very crucial to develop a scientific plan of water use with a view to sustainable management of water resource. Management of shortage of water and management of water pollution are complex task. These issues have drawn the attention of the developed and developing countries as well as the various national and international organizations including the Johannesburg Summit 2002, Year 2003 has been declared as year of Fresh -Water. But in India there are huge prospect to utilize the unused fresh water resources for pisciculture which can play an important role in this aspect. Realizing its importance during the 5th - five year plan the Government of India introduced beneficiary-oriented programme in the form of a pilot project entitled Fish Farmers Development Agency (FFDA) to provide self employment, financial, technical and extension support to fish farming in rural areas. In 1974-75 this Programme was further extended under World Bank-assisted, Inland fisheries project to cover about 200 districts of various states in India.

2. Sustainable development and Pisciculture

Sustainable development is a pattern of resource use that aims to meet human needs while preserving the environment so that these needs can be met not only in the present, but also for future generations. The term was used by the Brundtland Commission which coined what has become the most often-quoted definition of sustainable development as development that meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs. It is usually noted that this requires the reconciliation of environmental, social and economic demands - the three pillars of sustainability. This view has been expressed as an illustration using three overlapping ellipses indicating that the three pillars of sustainability are not mutually exclusive and can be mutually reinforcing. Sustainable development ties together concern for the carrying capacity of natural systems with the social challenges facing humanity. As early as the 1970s sustainability was employed to describe an economy in equilibrium with basic ecological support systems [Wikipedia]. A primary goal of sustainable development is to achieve a reasonable and equitable distributed level of economic well being that can be perpetuated continually for next generation. Thus the field of sustainable development can be broken into three constituent parts i.e. environmental, economic and social sustainability. It is proved that socio- economic sustainability is depended on environmental sustainability because the socio- economic aspects, like agriculture, transport, settlement, and other demographic factors are born and raised up in the environmental system. All the environmental set up is depended on a piece of land where it exists.

Water is a renewable natural resource and is a free gift of nature. In the early days the supply of water was plenty in relation to its demand and the price of water was very low or even zero but in course

20

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

of time the scenario has totally changed (Bairagya R. and Bairagya H. 2011). Water is a prime need for human survival and also an essential input for the development of the nation. For sustainable development management of water resources is very important today. Due to rapid growth of population, expansion of industries, rapid urbanization etc. the demand of water rises many-fold which is unbearable in relation to its resources in the earth. All the environmental set up is depended on a piece of land where it exists. So, to get sustainable environmental management, sustainable land management is necessary. As a result the use of water resources in the form pisciculture in a sustainable manner may gain priority.

4. Importance of the study

Social scientists have always identified the rural areas for investigation. In the case of India to a large number of studies have been carried out in rural situations including panchayats and co-operative societies. Though many research works have been done in the biological and marine sciences, the economic investigations of pisciculture have not yet been done so far. In this respect the present study has a clear economic importance for the upliftment of the rural economy at the grass root level. Thus pisciculture has a positive effect on ecology and hence to maintain ecological balance a meaningful use of unused water resources has an important role. Scarcity of water is a modern day tragedy human society will exist no more due to these scarce resources. So a meaningful use of this resources in the form of pisciculture to generate income of the rural poor gain topmost priority.

The state of West Bengal plays an important role for the implementation of the programme. Though the two districts Burdwan and Birbhum of W.B. are primarily agricultural districts, there is huge scope for pisciculture. A few studies have been undertaken by several experts, notably, D. Prasad (1968), R. Charan (1981), A.V. Natarajan (1985), K. M. B. Rahim (1992,93), A Chakravorty (1996), I Guha and R. Neogy (1996), P.K. Ghosh (1998) and others on the economic evaluation of pisciculture. Though these are useful guides to researchers, yet there is ample scope for further works relating to pisciculture in the rural areas of W.B. Besides, there is the necessity of developing studies concerning the impact of these programmes on the rural economy. The present study is a modest attempt in remedying this inadequacy.

4.1 Objectives

21

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

This pilot study was conducted on the following objectives i) To generate employment in rural India. ii) To rise in food supply and reduce mal-nutrition. iii) For proper utilisation of unused water resources. iv) To maintain ecological balance in a sustainable manner. V) Identification of fish farmers suitable and willing to develop fish farming in ponds.vi) Arranging training in organized manner and ensuring extension services to fish farmers.

4.2 Methodology of the study

4.2.1 Selection of study area

The present study was confined to survey the rural areas of Burdwan and Birbhum districts of W. B. in respect of implementation of the programme of Fish Farmers Development Agency (Mishra S. 1987). In the selection of districts following considerations weighed most: i) Both the districts are covered with water areas constituting half of the total inland water resources. ii) There is a heavy concentration of tanks and ponds in both the districts. iii) Both the districts are considered as having one homogeneous agro-climatic zone in view of the broad similarities of soils, climate and other features. Since they are also neighboring districts a suitable comparison can easily be made. iv) In both the districts, the FFDA programmes are being implemented in full fledged form by the Government authority. v) Data from both the districts can be obtained because of my personal knowledge about the two districts.

4.2.2 Selection of sample

Keeping in view the time factor, limited fund and limited ability it was not possible to collect data from all the recorded fish farmers of the two districts. At first 5 blocks from each district have been purposefully selected. Then 10 recorded fish farmers from each block have been selected purposefully. Thus 50 fish farmers from each district have been selected for interview. For comparative analysis of data each farmer was taken as the unit. For this study data have been collected on different aspects of the programme such as farmers income, water area, finance, total production, product price, cost of production, profit, duration of training period etc. The data have been collected by personal interview method through a questionnaire. Thus the collected data are entirely primary in nature.

4.2.3 Location map of the study area

22

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

The state of West Bengal lies between latitude 21038/ to 27010/ North and longitude 85038/ to 89050/ East. The district Burdwan lies between 22056/ and 25053/ North latitude and 86048/ and 88025/ East longitude. The district Birbhum lies between 23032/30// and 24035/00// North Latitudes and 88001/40// and 87005/25// East Longitudes shown in figure-1.

5. Fisheries in India

Indian fisheries can broadly be divided into two categories: i) Inland fisheries & ii) Marine fisheries. Further Inland fisheries can be classified into two types: i) Capture & ii) Culture. Capture fisheries consist of rivers, lakes canals etc. where farmers do not cultivate fishes. Natural breeding process is the common phenomenon there. On the other hand, culture fisheries consist of ponds, tanks, swamps, marshes etc. In this case, farmers have to sow fish seeds, nurse it and send it to proper size before harvesting. India is the third largest producer of fish in the world and the second in inland fish production. Indian fishing resources comprising of 2 million sq.km.of EEZ for deep sea fishing, 7,520 km. of coast line, 29,000 km. of Rivers, 1.7 million Ha. of reservoirs, 1 million Ha. of brackish water and .8 million Ha. of ponds, lakes and tanks for inland and marine fish production (Giriappa S. (ed) 1994) . About 14 million fishermen draw their livelihood from fishery. During the period 1981 to 2002 the contribution of fishery to GDP has increased from Rs.1230 crores to Rs.32060 crores. The fish production increased from 0.7 million tons in1951 to 6.8 million tons in 2006.

5.1 Fisheries in West Bengal

West Bengal has a vast water resource potentiality. By utilizing these water resources there is a huge prospect of pisciculture (Chakraborty S. K.1991). These resources can be divided into two categories: i) Inland water resources and ii) Marine water resources. Inland resources constitute ponds, rivers, marshy lands, canals, reservoirs etc. Water Resources of West Bengal shown in figure-2.

It should be noted that tanks/ponds occupy the major share i.e. 46.70% of total inland water resources. But out of 2, 76,202 Ha. area under ponds and tanks only 2, 20,000 Ha. i.e. 79.65% are presently used for pisciculture which means 20.35% remains unused. Moreover, out of 5, 91,476.71 Ha. total inland water resource only 2.87000 Ha. water area is brought under pisciculture i.e. 48.56% are presently used and 51.44% remains unused. These unused water resources can be brought under pisciculture through proper utilization.

23

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

In West Bengal marine fishery has a substantial share amounting to a coast line of 158 km. inshore area up to 10 fathoms depth is 770 sq. km. (Mamoria C.B. 1979), offshore area (10-40) fathoms depth is 1813 sq. km. and a continental shelf up to 100 Fathom is 17,049 sq.km. Out of 19 districts of West Bengal only two districts East- Midnapur and South 24-Parganas are coastal. West Bengal is on the top of the list in fish production in the country. With the passage of time, more and more people are getting themselves involved in fishery. As fish constitutes the staple food of the people efforts are being made to augment fish production.

From the period 1986 to 2000, the total fish production increased from 424000 tons to 1045,000 tons (i.e. 2.46 times). At the same period the inland fish production increased 2.25 times and marine fish production increased 4.50 times. In the year 1986, the share of inland and marine fisheries to total fish production were 91% and 9% respectively. But in the year 2000, the share of inland and marine fisheries to total fish production are 83% and 17% respectively. Thus we see that during the period 1986 to 2000, the share of inland fish to total production declined (from 91% in 1986 to 83% in 2000) and the share of marine fisheries increased (from 9% in 1986 to 17% in 2000).

Not only in fish production but also in the demand for fish West Bengal is the highest in the country. The domestic demand for fish in West Bengal is high because almost all the people of West Bengal are fisheating. But the state has a higher demand for fish than its production of fish i.e. this state has a deficit in fish supply. To meet this gap the state West Bengal has to import fish from other states like Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu etc. At the same time various efforts have been made to augment fish production to bridge this gap.

5.2 Fisheries in Burdwan district

The district of Burdwan is mainly an agricultural district though it is also well advanced in industrial production. It is called the granary of West Bengal. The district is filled with well fertile productive land. Not only that, the district is also well endowed with a large number of water bodies in the form of rivers, ditches, canals, marshy lands, ponds, tanks etc. The principal rivers are Ajoy, Damodar and Kunur etc. There is a good prospect of pisciculture by utilizing these water resources. The distribution of total water resources in Burdwan district (i.e. 66480.82 Ha.) is shown in figure-3.

Though the district has huge water resources, during the period 1982-1998 only 50% of this water area was brought under scientific pisciculture. In the year 1999, the districts total fish production was 55,500 metric tons while demand in that year was 65,000 metric tons. Thus there was a deficit of 9,500 metric tons. To

24

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

meet this demand the district had to import fish from neighboring states. The district will be self-sufficient in fish production if the unused 50% water resources are brought under pisciculture.

5.3 Fisheries in Birbhum district

The district of Birbhum is a part of Rarh area. The district is well-drained by a number of rivers and rivulets. The principal rivers of this district are: Ajoy, Brahmani, Dwarka, Kopai, Mayurakshi etc. But most of the rivers remain dried up during a greater part of the year. Due to this adverse natural factor pisciculture has not made any significant progress in this district. Agriculture is the main occupation of the common people of this district. The main water areas for pisciculture of this district are rivers, tanks, ponds, khals, Bills, baors, reservoirs etc. The distribution of total water resources in Birbhum district (i.e. 45215.81 Ha.) is shown in figure-4.

The figure-4 shows that this district has a large number of water resources. But during the period 19801999, only 46% of this water area was brought under pisciculture through FFDA. So there is a huge prospect of pisciculture by utilizing these unused water resources. In the year 1999 total number of fish farmers in this district was 2, 00747 out of which 56.5% were males and 43.5% were females. The total number of fisherman family in this district was 4,975. The average fish production of this district was 21,000 metric tons and the annual demand was 24,000 metric tons. Thus the district had a deficit (3000 mt) in fish production. To meet its own demand the district has also to import fish from the neighbouring states.

6. Findings

6.1 Income distribution of sample fish farmers before and after assistance from FFDA

It was observed that 26 farmers in Burdwan district & 32 farmers in Birbhum district have pisciculture as the main occupation while others have pisciculture as a subsidiary occupation. Their basic occupations are agriculture, business and service and have various types of incomes from those occupations. But as income generation scheme only income from fishery was taken into account i.e. income means income earned from selling fishes. From sample survey we have collected two sets of income data (one showing income before and other showing income after the assistance of FFDA) for each fish farmer. Thus the amount of income reveals the income of the fish farmer before the receipt of assistance of FFDA and the income after the assistance of FFDA. In this regard the income comparison has done in two areas (namely within the district, between the district and the overall change of income) andt (Gujarati D.N. 2009) test was used for

25

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

statistical analysis. Now the various types of incomes distribution of fish farmers of the two districts are shown in terms of four tables.

From table- 1 it is clear in both the districts the average income of most of the fish farmers (i.e. 89 out of 100 fish farmers of the two districts taken together) has monthly income before assistance below Rs. 4000 i.e. they are basically come from poor family income group

i) From the field survey we get that the per capita availability of fish in Burdwan district is 24 kg. per head per year while in Birbhum district it is 23.5 kg. per head per year. Now the worlds per capita availability of fish is 11.5 kg. per head per year and for developed countries it is 25 kg. per head per year. But India has a low per capita availability of 3.5 kg. per head per year only. Thus we see that the fishermen have a standard level of per capita fish consumption. The point is very important to reduce mal-nutrition (which is a common phenomenon for the country) by means of intensive pisciculture. But India has a poor per capita availability of fish of only 3.5 kg per head per year. Thus we see that the per capita availability of fish for these 100 farmers families of these two districts are much higher than that of India and worlds average and even equal to the standard of the developed countries.

ii) It was found that the average monthly income of fish farmers before the assistance of FFDA in Burdwan district was Rs. 2680 and in Birbhum district it was Rs. 2045. But after the assistance of FFDA the average monthly incomes of the fish farmers of the two districts increased to Rs.3935 and Rs.3721 respectively. Thus we see that the average monthly income of fish farmers of Burdwan district has increased 1.47 times and in case of Birbhum district it has increased 1.8 times. The result indicates that the average income of fish farmers of Burdwan district was higher than the average income of those of Birbhum district in respect of both before and after the assistance of FFDA. However, the rate of increment was higher in Birbhum than that of Burdwan district. Thus we can say that the incomes of the fish farmers have improved due to pisciculture.

iii) Statistical methods were adopted is to judge whether the change of income of the sample fish farmers before and after the assistance of FFDA was significant or not. This has been done in two areas: - a) Change of income within the district and b) Overall change of income of the two districts.

6.2 Change of income within the district

Burdwan district- It is seen that the value oft = 3.31 is significant at .01 level, meaning thereby that the

26

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

change income of sample fish farmers of Burdwan district is significant. The gain is in favor of the assistance of FFDA. It may be concluded from the result that there is a positive impact of assistance on fish farming (i.e. the production of fish). It may also be concluded that production has increased significantly in Burdwan district.

Birbhum district-The result indicates that t is significant at .01 level. Hence it may be said that in Birbhum district the change of income of fish farmers is significant.

6.3 Overall change of income taking the two districts together

It is seen from the above table that the value oft is significant at .01 level which indicates that the income of fish farmers before and after assistance differ significantly. The result reveals that the mean income after assistance is significantly greater than that before assistance. It may be concluded from the overall results considering both the districts that the impact of assistance on fish production is significant.

The finding of these results was that the assistance of FFDA programme has raised the fish farmers income undoubtedly in both the districts. Not only that the change of income was statistically significant but also the result revealed that there was a positive impact of FFDA assistance on fish production (i.e. fish production has significantly increased). Moreover, it was also found that the gain of income of fish farmers of Birbhum district was higher than that of Burdwan district. Thus we can conclude that in case of the implementation of the programme of FFDA the district Burdwan has more successful achievements than the district of Birbhum.

7 Suggestions

7.1 General suggestions

i) In pisciculture, fishermen are not only directly employed in fishing but also some other alternative occupations like net making, marketing of fish seed and fishery product , transport, boat making etc. many rural people earn income. Since fish is a perishable commodity proper marketing channels should be established. Hence to reduce pressure from agriculture pisciculture may be alternative occupations for generating income and employment for a large number of poor people. ii) In Burdwan district there are some open caste pits (OCP) in Ranigang coal belt and in Birbhum district also such pits are available at

27

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Khoirasole block, calamines at Md.Bazar block. Fish production may increase by utilizing these water resources for pisciculture purposes.iii) The urban waste (i.e. garbage) may be recycled as fish feed (to those ponds and water areas lying near the towns) to raise fish production and to prevent the environmental pollution in those areas. v) To make financial support for the poor fishermen Bank should grant loan on a long-term basis and at a low rate of interest in proper amount and in proper time.vi) the selection of actual beneficiary is very much essential and it should be made on the basis of need and neutrally not in politically. vii) Since fish is a perishable commodity storage facilities should be provided such that the fishermen are not forced to sell their product at a lower price. Prices of organic manures and fish seeds should be kept as low as possible or the Government should give more subsidies in the case of chemical fertilizers so that the poor fish farmers can buy them. viii) For welfare measures of the rural poor fishermen some Group and Personal Insurance Schemes, Old- Age Pension Schemes should be taken and the Fishery Dept. should issue Identity Card to each fisherman. ix) Since both the districts are agricultural based we should interlink agriculture with pisciculture shown in figure-5. Along with pisciculture in ponds other allied culture can be inter-linked in composite farming. The concept of composite farming e.g. in the pondthere are pisciculture and on one side of the pond mulberry trees can be cultivated for the development of sericulture industry-from there silk industry can be grown. Thus the final products (i.e. silk yarn and silk cloth) come to the market and their waste materials are drained off to the pond and used as fish feed. In the same pattern on another side of the pond animal husbandry can be practiced (e.g. poultry, duccary and piggery). Their waste can be used as a valuable manure for fish feed and the residual can be utilized for agricultural production. The excreta of the animal husbandry can also be used in the bio-gas plant for fuel and light. The products of animal husbandry e.g. milk, meat and egg come to the market directly. On another side of the pond some fruit plants such as papine, guava, mango etc. can be cultivated by using the excess manure of animal husbandry and the products can be sold in the market.

x) Composite fish culture: Stocking of various species should be in a certain proportion such that various types of fishes live in various layers and eat the entire food organism (so called Polyculture or Composite Fish Culture). Stocking is an important factor to raise fish production. On an average the survibility of stocking is 80% (Jhingran V.G. 1991). This means that 20% of stocking is lost for various reasons such as improper handling, netting and also eaten by preratory animals like snakes, frogs etc. The main species cultured in India are Rahu, Catla, Mrigel, Silver Carp (S.C.), Grass Carp (G.C.), Cyprinus Carpio (Cy, Ca.) and Bata etc. In polyculture (where various fishes are cultured simultaneously) (Agarwal S.C. 1990) system all these species are cultured in certain ratios. It is found that all of these species do not generally live in the same layer. In mixed (or polyculture or composite culture) culture all these fishes are cultured in such a way that all layers feed are used. If we divide the whole layer into 3 parts i.e. upper, middle and lower layers, then Cattla and S.C live in the upper layer, Rahu and G.C. live in the middle layer and Mrigel and Cy. Ca. live in the lower layer. It is also to be noted that these two species in the same layer are not competitors of each other. In their feed habit one eats waste weeds and the other eats green weeds. Hence in polyculture all the ponds feed are used scientifically and economically. The production of Big head and Big head African giant hybrid magur are totally banned because their food habits are too much and hamper

28

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

the foods of other common species. Suppose 1000 fish seed is cultivated in the pond. Then the stocking ratios for various fishes are Rahu: Catla: Mrigel: S.C.: G.C.: Cy.Car = 3 : 1 : 1.5 : 1.5 : 1 : 2 Thus the number of seeds are, Rahu = 300, Catla = 100, Mrigel = 150, S.C = 150, G.C. = 100, Cy. Ca. = 200. Now the survibility rate is 80%.Thus the number of produced matured fishes are Rahu = 240, Catla = 80, Mrigel = 120, S.C. = 120, G.C. = 80, Cy.Car. = 160. Fishes are cultivated for 9-12 months. The culture period may extend up to 18 months with partial harvesting between. Moreover, the general annual growth of these fishes are, Rahu = 1kg, Catla 1.5 kg. Mrigel 0.75kg, SC. = 0.8 kg, G.C. = 1.5 kg, Cy. Car. = 0.8 kg. The fish farmers collect fish seeds from private traders or from Government fish farm.

xi) Since training is a necessary ingredient to raise fish production the Government has initiated some special training programmes for fish farmers. Moreover to motivate the poor fish farmers some amount of remuneration or stipend is paid to the participant during training. The amount of remuneration depends upon the kind of training, place of training organization and duration of the training programmes conducted by the FFDA. To attend the district level training programmes for the farmers of distant villages, traveling allowances are also paid.

xii) It is very essential to use mahua cake because it has dual roles in pisciculture. It firstly acts as a pesticide but later it acts as organic manure and produces a desired quantity of fish food organism for the baby fishes. The presence of Saponin in mahua cake kills the pre-ratory animals / fishes of the pond. This poisonous effect continues about 10-15 days and after that it acts as manure. On the other hand, the use of pesticides has a negative long-term effect to ecological balance. So the pesticides are not generally used though they are cheaper. The mahua cake should be applied at the rate of 333.33kg/ Yr. / bigha.

7.2 Limitations of the study

The following are the limitations of the study: i) Regarding the change in the level of income before and after the assistance of FFDA, the statements of the fish farmers have been taken into consideration on good faith. ii) Due to limited time, ability and resource constraints, data have been collected from a small number of fish farmers of the two districts and results are assumed to be the representative for the district as a whole. Iii) Due to difficulties in getting responses from the sample fish farmers sometimes we had to rely on the different FEOs opinions and also on different official records on good faith. iv) The observations made on the basis of collected data are obviously particularistic in nature in so far as these data relate to micro-study like the present one (i.e. only 100 fish farmers from the two districts were taken into consideration). Micro-studies do not attempt to build general theories but the utility of this type of study is that large number micro-studies may, in course of time, be helpful in constructing meaningful generalizations. Moreover, it is an explorative study which seeks to explore the conditions of fish farmers

29

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

before and after the assistance of FFDA programme. A much larger study may be undertaken to vindicate the results obtained from this explorative study.

8. Conclusion

The study indicates that the introduction of the programme of FFDA had a clear positive impact on the rural economy through employment and income generation and also raising the standard of living and socioeconomic performances of the rural community of the two districts. It is environmentally viable, sustainable and eco-friendly in nature. So for sustainable use of the scarce water resources it is very essential in the present context. Unemployment is a curse for the society today and pressure of population on agricultural sector is rising day by day. Thus fish farming may be an alternative occupation for those unemployed people and undoubtedly generate income in a viable method. Therefore it is recommended that the present programme should be further spread in the rural areas by means of proper planning, adequate supervision, effective implementation and better monitoring in a sustainable manner.

References:

Agarwal S.C. (1990), Fishery Management, Ashis Publishing House, New-Delhi. Bairagya R. and Bairagya H. (2011), Water Scarcity a Global Problem- An Economic Analysis, Indian Journal of Landscape Systems and Ecological Studies, Vol.-34, Institute of Landscape, Ecology & Ekistics, Kolkata, 127-132 Bairagya R. (2004), A Comparative Study of the Functioning of Fish Farmers Development Agency (FFDA) in the Districts of Burdwan and Birbhum (1985-1995), PhD Thesis, Department of Commerce, the University of Burdwan. Bureau of Applied Economics, Burdwan (1998), Key Statistics of Burdwan, Govt. of W.B. Bureau of Applied Economics, Birbhum (1998), Key Statistics of Birbhum, Govt. of W.B Chakraborty S. K. (1991), A Study in Bhery Fisheries, Agro-Economic Reaserch Centre, Visva- Bharati. Dutt R. and Sundharam K.P.M. (2009), Indian Economy, S. Chand and Co. New-Delhi, 101-103 Jhingran V.G. (1991), Fish and Fisheries in India, Hindustan Publishing Cor.-Delhi. Giriappa S. (ed) (1994), Role of Fisheries in Rural Development, Daya Publishing House, Delhi.

30

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Gujarati D.N. (2009), Basic Econometrics, McGraw-Hill., 98-133 Mamoria C.B. (1979), Economic & Commercial Geography of India, Shiblal Agarwala Company, Agra-3 Mishra S. (1987), Fisheries in India, Ashis Publishing House, New-Delhi Acknowledgement: In preparation of this paper I deeply acknowledge my respected sir Prof. Jaydeb Sarkhel, Department of Commerce, Burdwan University, West Bengal, India, e-mail: jaydebsarkhel@gmail.com

Tables and Figures:

31

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Figure-1

32

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

33

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Figure-2

Figure-3

Figure-4

Table -1 Change of income distribution of Burdwan.

34

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Table -2 Change of income distribution of Birbhum district

Table--3 Classification of sample fish farmers according to their monthly incomes after the assistance

35

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Table- 4 Classification of sample fish farmers according to their monthly incomes after the assistance

Source: All tables data sources are computed from field survey.

36

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

MARKET

Light, Fuel

Silk yarn & Silk cloth

Gobar gas

Milk, Meat & Egg Silk industry waste materials Cow, Piggary, Duccary, Poultry

te as w ls ia er at m

Sericulture

Mulburyculture

Produced Fish

Agricultural production (Fruit, papaine, guava, mango etc.)

Side

POND

Side

Circular flow of pisciculture and other allied culture

Figure: 5

37

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

The Nexus of Private Savings and Economic Growth in Emerging Economy: A Case of Nigeria
Adelakun, Ojo Johnson Department of Economics, Joseph Ayo Babalola University P.M.B. 5006, Ilesa, Osun State, Nigeria, email joadelakun@yahoo.co.uk

Received: October 11st, 2011 Accepted: October 19th, 2011 Published: October 30th, 2011 Abstract This study discusses the trend in Nigerian saving behaviour and reviews policy options to increase domestic saving. It also examines the determinants of private saving in Nigeria during the period covering 1970 2007. It makes an important contribution to the literature by evaluating the magnitude and direction of the effects of the following key policy and non-policy variables on private saving: Income growth, interest rate, fiscal policy, and financial development. The framework for analysis involves the estimation of a saving rate function derived from the Life Cycle Hypothesis while taking into cognizance the structural characteristics of a developing economy. The study employs the Error-Correction modelling procedure which minimizes the possibility of estimating spurious relations, while at the same time retaining long-run information. The results of the analysis show that the saving rate rises with both the growth rate of disposable income and the real interest rate on bank deposits. Public saving seems not to crowd out private saving; suggesting that government policies aimed at improving the fiscal balance has the potential of bringing about a substantial increase in the national saving rate. Finally, the degree of financial depth has a negative but insignificant impact on saving behaviour in Nigeria. Keywords: Private Saving, Saving Rate, Macroeconomic Policy, Interest Rate, Economic Growth.

Introduction Researchers and policy makers are known to be having growing concern among researchers and policy makers over the declining trend in saving rates and its substantial divergence among countries. This is due to the critical importance of saving for the maintenance of strong and sustainable growth in the world economy. Over the past three decades, saving rates have doubled in East Asia and stagnated in Sub-Saharan Africa, Latin America and the Caribbean (Loayza, Schmidt-Hebbel and Serven, 2000). The personal saving rate has been drifting downward for the last two decades. According to the latest statistics, personal saving

38

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

declined from about 10% of disposable income in the early 1980s to 1.8% in 2004. The decline has received particular attention recently because saving was negative in 2005 for the first time since the Great Depression. Although saving declined in other developed countries during this period, the U.S decline was more pronounced than in most of the three countries. Development economists have been concerned for decades about the crucial role of domestic saving mobilization in the sustenance and reinforcement of the saving-investment-growth chain in developing economies. For instance, Aghevli et al (1990) found that the saving rate and investment in human capital are indeed closely linked to economic growth. The relationship among saving, investment and growth has historically been very close; hence, the unsatisfactory growth performance of several developing countries has been attributed to poor saving and investment. This poor growth performance has generally led to a dramatic decline in investment. Domestic saving rates have not fared better, thus worsening the already precarious balance of payments position (Chete, 1999). In the same vein, attempts to correct external imbalances by reducing aggregate demand have led to a further decline in investment expenditure, thus aggravating the problem of sluggish growth and declining saving and investment rates (Khan and Villanueva, 1991). In addition, low personal saving has created short-run concerns that a sudden increase in the saving rate could reduce growth of consumer spending, and output and employment.

Statement of the Problem The strong positive correlation which exists between saving, investment and growth is well established in the literature. The dismal growth record in most African countries, relative to other regions of the world has been of concern to economists. This is because the growth rate registered in most African countries is often not commensurate with the level of investment. In Nigeria for instance, the economy witnessed tremendous growth in the 1970s and early 1980s as a result of the oil boom and this led to the investment boom especially in the public sector. However, with the collapse of the oil market in the 1980s, investment fell, thereby resulting in a fall in economic growth. For instance, during the investment boom, gross investment as a percentage of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) was 16.8 and 31.4 percent in 1974 and 1976 respectively, whereas it declined to 9.5 and 8.9 percent, respectively in 1984 and 1985(CBN 2008). One question begging for an answer is: What is the impact of saving and investment on growth? It has been argued that saving affects investment, which in turn influences growth in output. The transformation of initial growth into sustained output expansion requires the accumulation of capital and its corresponding financing. An output expansion in turn sets in motion a self reinforcing process by which the anticipated growth encourages investment, which supports growth, as well as financial development. It is certain that without a significant increase in the level of investment (public and private), no meaningful growth in output would be achieved. Indeed if private investment remains at the current low level, it will slow down potential growth and reduce long run level of per capita consumption and income, thereby leading to low savings and investment.

39

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
Objective of the Study This study has the following objectives:

www.iiste.org

To know the impact of private saving in economic growth in Nigeria. To also carry out an analysis of the sources and trend of saving in Nigeria. To also know the motivations of saving and how savings are measured. To also know how saving affects the economic performance in the country. To also evaluate the impact of the main determinants of saving identified in the literature on private saving in Nigeria.

Method of the Study (Methodology) The framework for this analysis is derived from the life-cycle model which has withstood the test of time in explaining the changes in private saving over time. It is appropriately modified to accommodate the peculiarities of a developing country and builds on the existing cross-country literature on saving which quantifies the effects of a variety of policy and non-policy variables on private saving. Its attractiveness lies in its elegant formulation of the effects of interest rate and growth on saving. In addition, its flexibility makes it possible for other relevant theoretical considerations to be incorporated, thus forming an integrated analytical framework, without altering its fundamental structure. This framework makes a new contribution to the literature by employing time series data in evaluating the determinants of private saving in Nigeria between 1970 and 2009. It does this while explicitly addressing some of the econometric problems arising from the use of time-series data.

Literature Review, Theoretical Framework and Empirical Evidence Introduction Keynes (1936) defined savings as the excess of income over expenditure on consumption. Meaning that savings is that part of the disposable income of the period which has not passed into consumption (Umoh, 2003 and Uremadu, 2005). Given that income is equal to the value of current output; and that current investment (i.e. Gross capital formation) is equal to the value of that part of current output, which is not consumed; savings is equal to the excess of income over consumption. Hence, the equality of savings and investment necessarily follow thus: Income = Value of output = Consumption + Investment Savings = Income Consumption Savings = Investment ex-post. There abound numerous theoretical evidences concerning the functional relationships between savings and a wide range of causal variables. For instance, Juster and Taylor (1975) report that savings is an increasing function of income. Moreover, Modigliani (1970), Madison (1992), Bosworth (1993), Caroll and Weil (1993), Schmidt-Hebbel, Sarven and Solimano (1994), Modigliani (1992), Jappeli and Pugano (1994),

40

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Edwards (1995), Collins (1991) and Uremadu (2000) maintain that there exists a positive relationship between savings and income growth rates. Aghevli (1990) in Ozigbo (1999) reported that there is consensus that the level of savings is largely determined by the level of income. In Nigeria and other developing economies, there are other evidences that interest rate has significant effect on financial savings especially time and savings deposits while the structure of deposits was determined by differentials in deposit rates as has been demonstrated in Ndekwu, (1991). He also showed using monthly data that interest rates deregulation in Nigeria have a positive impact on financial savings during the period, 1984-1988. Literature Survey Franco Modigliani in his Life Cycle model determined that over the typical individuals lifetime his level of income will fluctuate from low levels in his younger years, to high levels in his middle-aged working years, back to low levels in his retirement years. However, this individual prefers to maintain a relatively stable level of consumption. In order to maintain this steady consumption, the individual will be forced to borrow during his younger years, save during his middle-aged years and then spend down his savings in his retirement years. From estimating his model, Modigliani concludes that individuals have a marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of income of approximately 0.70 and an MPC out of net worth if approximately 0.07 to 0.08. (Ando and Modigliani, 1962) Many researchers have studied the possible determinants of private savings behavior. In Amaotengs survey article, he shows that saving has been found to be positively correlated with income, wealth, education, age, a high level of risk tolerance, and a favorable perception of ones own financial status; and negatively correlated with a larger family size. (Amaoteng 2002) Modiglianis life cycle model illustrates that age structure can have a strong impact on the level of savings in an economy. Since individuals in the middle-aged working years (which we will define as ages 25-55) tend to save more than individuals in the younger (ages 0-24) or retirement years (ages 56+), a population with a higher concentration of individuals in the middle-aged range will have higher savings rates. (Amaoteng 2002) Trend of Saving in Nigeria In mobilizing funds from the surplus units of the economy, banks incur some costs mainly in interest payments on deposit accounts. In order to recover the cost of deposit mobilization and other operating overheads, banks lend at higher interest rates. The difference between the two types of rates is referred to as the interest rate spread or the intermediation spread. The spread measures the efficiency of the intermediation process in the market, such that, a high intermediation spread implies that there is inefficiency in the market, especially as it discourages potential savers and borrowers, thus, hampering investment and growth. Prior to the deregulation of the banking sector, interest rates were administratively determined by the Central Bank. Both the deposit and lending rates were fixed by the CBN on the basis of policy decisions. At that time, the major goals were socially optimum resource allocation, promotion of orderly growth of the financial market, as well as reduction of both inflation and the internal debt service burden on the government. During the period 1970 to 1985, the rates were unable to keep pace with prevailing

41

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

inflation rate, resulting in negative real interest rates. Moreover, the performance of the preferred sectors of the economy was below expectation, thus, leading to the deregulation of the interest rate in August 1987 to a market-based system. This enabled banks to determine their deposit and lending rates according to the market conditions through negotiations with their customers. However, the minimum rediscount rate (MRR) which is the central banks nominal anchor continued to be determined by the CBN. The lack of responsiveness of the structure of deposit and lending rates to market fundamentals makes the interest rate inefficient. The wide divergence between the deposit and lending rates (interest rate spread) is inimical to economic growth and development of the Nigerian economy. Between 1980 and 1984, interest rate differentials averaged 3.9 per cent. Even though this was reasonable within the accepted limit, the spread widened between 1985 and 1989, averaging 4.3 per cent per annum. This impacted negatively on the amount of loanable funds available to the private sector for investment. The interest differential further widened to an average of 7.9 per cent between 1990 and 1994. Thereafter, the yearly interest rate spread maintained an upward trend, rising from 8.2 per cent in 1995 to 24.6 per cent in 2002, before declining to 15.7 per cent in 2005 (see Figure 1). The widening gap between the deposit and lending rates reflects the prevailing inefficiencies in the Nigerian banking sector and has deterred potential investors from borrowing, and thus lowered the level of investment in the economy.

Interest Rate Spread (in Percentage) Source: Central Bank of Nigeria i) Statistical Bulletin, 2006 and ii) Annual Report and Statement of Accounts, various years.

42

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

The use of interest rate spread has however been criticized given that higher levels of interest rates are usually associated with higher inflation rates, and therefore a higher cost of holding money. In addition, higher inflation rates tend to be associated with higher country premia. As a result of these disadvantages of interest rate spread as an indicator of efficiency, net interest margin has been proposed as a better alternative. Net interest margin is equal to total interest revenues minus total interest expenditure divided by the value of assets. Higher values of net interest margin indicate a higher spread on deposit and lending rates and therefore lower efficiency.

Figure 2 shows the interest rate figures in Nigeria between 1970 and 2009. A cursory look reveals that the nominal interest rate was institutionally determined by the monetary authorities throughout the 1970s and the first half of the 1980s. However, with the advent of the structural adjustment programme in the mid 1980s which brought with it a rash of financial sector reforms, Nigeria abandoned its fixed interest rate regime that saw nominal interest rates rising from 9.3 percent in 1985 to 26.8 percent in 1989, and reaching a peak of 29.8 percent in 1992. The figure has since hovered between 13.5 percent and 24.4 percent. It stood at 16.5 percent in 2009.

Real Interest Rate (in Percentage) Source: Central Bank of Nigeria i) Statistical Bulletin, 2006 and ii) Annual Report and Statement of Accounts, various years. The real interest rate figures present an interesting picture. Between 1970 and 2009, the figure was negative 20 times, attaining positive figures on 18 occasions. The fixed interest rate regime of the 1970s and early 1980s no doubt contributed to this negative trend by fixing the interest rate at artificially low levels. For instance, in the first two decades (1970 to 1989) when the fixed regime dominated, real interest rate was negative 14 times and positive only 6 times. However, in the last two decades (1990 to 2009), when market forces took over, the real interest rate was negative on only 6 occasions. The inflation rate also played a very important role in making the real interest rate negative for most of the period. A cursory glance at figure 2 shows that the years when the real interest rate was negative usually coincided with those of double-digit inflation rates. Table components of 1 saving shows in the Nigeria

including savings and time deposits with deposit money banks, the national provident fund, federal savings bank,

43

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
federal mortgage bank, life insurance funds and other deposit institutions. Saving and time deposits in banks is by far the single most important component of saving in Nigeria and has witnessed a continuous growth over the years. Beginning with a sum

www.iiste.org

of N337 million in 1970, it rose to N5.2 billion in 1980. By 1990, the figure had climbed to N23.1 billion, rising further by 2000 to N343.2 billion. As at 2005, the figure stood at N1.3 trillion. Its contribution to total saving has however been mixed. In 1970, savings in banks consisted of 98.8 percent of total saving, with this figure reducing gradually to 89.5 percent in 1980, and further declining to 78 percent in 1990. From then the percentage of savings in banks in total saving has witnessed an upward trend, rising to 89.1 percent in 2000. Since 2003, this percentage has been 100 percent showing that it has become the only component of saving. The National Provident Fund and the Federal Mortgage bank were both established in 1974. Beginning with N130 million, the National Provident Fund rose to N724 million in 1990, reaching a peak of N1.37 billion in 1998. The fund maintained this figure till 2002 when it was scrapped by the government. The Federal Mortgage Bank on the other hand experienced a more rapid growth, rising from a paltry N7.3 million at its inception in 1974 to N305 million in 1990. By 2002 when it ceased to exist, it had mobilized N22.3 billion. The figures for the Federal Savings Bank have been mixed. It stood at N4.9 million in 1970, increasing to N8.1 million in 1978. It thereafter declined to N4.0 billion in 1982, after which the figure climbed steadily till it reached N37.5 billion in 1989 when it was discontinued. Life insurance funds were established in the same year 1989 with the sum of N1.1 billion. The figure rose sharply to N19.4 billion in 1994 thereafter witnessing a rapid decline. The amount mobilized stood at N8.5 billion in 2002 when the federal government scrapped it.

Savings, Growth and Fiscal Deficit (in percent) Notes: i) Savings is the ratio of private saving to Gross National Disposable Income (GDNI); ii) Growth is the growth rate of real per capita GNDI; iii) Fiscal Balance is the surplus or deficit of the entire federation as a percentage of GDP. Source: Central Bank of Nigeria i) Statistical Bulletin, 2006 and ii) Annual Report and Statement of Accounts, various years. Figure 3 shows the other macroeconomic variables of interest, including private saving rate, growth and fiscal balance. The Nigerian economy has witnessed several fluctuations in its chequered

44

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

history, with economic growth fluctuating between 45 percent and -31 percent in the period between 1970 and 2009. In the 27 year period between 1974 and 2001, the economy experienced negative growth 14 times, while making a positive showing only 13 times. However, growth has been positive since 2002. Fiscal balance was even more troubling given that Nigeria experienced a budget surplus only six times out of the 38 year period between 1970 and 2009. The State governments have been as culpable as the government at the centre, with each level seemingly competing to outspend the other. Private saving witnessed much less volatility, with the variable recording a negative value only once in the 38 year period. The saving rate fluctuated between 20 percent and 41 percent between 1970 and 1979. This figures changed to 14 percent and 36 percent in the next decade. Between 1990 and 1999, the saving rate hovered between -0.6 percent and 39 percent, reaching an impressive range of between 20 percent and 65 percent in the period 2000 to 2009. The private saving rate stood at 58 percent in 2009. Theoretical Framework The life-cycle hypothesis was formulated by Modigliani (1970) and is the principal theoretical underpinning that has guided the study of savings behaviour over the years. A critical analysis of this theory however shows that it seems to mirror what happens in developed economies with little or no regard to the peculiarities of developing countries like Nigeria. There are a number of reasons that make it imperative for saving behaviour in developing countries to be modelled separately from that in developed economies. First, at the microeconomic level, developing-country households tend to be large and poor. They have a different demographic structure, more of them are likely to be engaged in agriculture, and their income prospects are much more uncertain. The problem of allocating income over time thus looks rather different in the two contexts, and the same basic models have different implications for behaviour and policy. Second, at the macroeconomic level, both developing and developed countries are concerned with saving and growth, with the possible distortion of aggregate saving, and with saving as a measure of economic performance. However, few developing countries possess the sort of fiscal system that permits deliberate manipulation of personal disposable income to help stabilize output and employment. Third, much of the literature in the last five decades expresses the belief that saving is too low, and that development and growth are impeded by the shortfall. Sometimes the problem is blamed on the lack of government policy, other times on misguided policy. Lastly, saving is even more difficult to measure in developing than in advanced economies, whether at the household level or as a macroeconomic aggregate. The resulting data inadequacies are pervasive and have seriously hampered progress in answering basic questions. Given the above, and following Deaton (1989), this paper appropriately modifies the life-cycle theory by developing a model of households which cannot borrow but which accumulate assets as a buffer stock to protect consumption when incomes are low. Such households dissave as often as they save, do not accumulate assets over the long term, and have on average very small asset holdings. However, their consumption is markedly smoother than their income.

45

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Following McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973), we argue that for the typical developing country, the net impact of a change in real interest rate on saving is likely to be positive. This is because, in the typical developing economy where there is no robust market for stocks and bonds, cash balances and quasimonetary assets usually account for a greater proportion of household saving compared to that in developed countries. In addition, in an environment where self-financing and bank loans constitute the major source of investment funds, accumulation of financial saving is driven mainly by the decision to invest and not by the desire to live on interest income. Given the peculiarities of saving behaviour, in addition to the fact that the bulk of saving comes from small savers, the substitution effect is usually larger than the income effect of an interest rate change. Empirical Evidence There is an abundance of empirical studies that deal with the impact of the different variables of interest on savings mobilization. Some authors have found a strong positive relationship between real per capita growth and saving rates (see for example, Modigliani, 1970; Bosworth, 1993; and Carrol and Weil, 1994). However, its structural interpretation is controversial, since it is viewed both as evidence that growth drives saving (Modigliani, 1970; and Carrol and Weil, 1994) and that saving drives growth through the saving-investment link (Levine and Renelt, 1992; and Mankiw, Romer and Weil, 1992). Given the importance of controlling for the joint endogeneity of saving and income growth, a panel instrumental-variable approach to estimate the effect of income growth on saving was carried out by Loayza, Schmidt-Hebbel, and Serven (2000). They found that a one percentage point rise in growth rate increases the private saving rate by a similar amount, although this effect may be partly transitory. In their study, they utilized the world saving database, whose broad coverage makes it the largest and most systematic collection of annual time series on country saving rates and saving-related variables, spanning 35 years (1960 1994) and 134 countries (112 developing and 12 industrial). Obadan and Odusola (2001) employed both graphical analysis as well as Granger Causality tests to determine the impact of growth on saving. Their results revealed that growth of income does not Granger-cause saving, suggesting that saving is not income-induced in Nigeria. Evidence on the reverse causation argument also shows that saving does not Granger-cause growth. The findings therefore do not show any direct relationship between saving and income growth. Analytically, the effect of financial liberalization on private saving rates works through the expansion of the supply of credit to previously credit-constrained private agents. This allows households and small firms to use collateral more widely, and reduces down payments on loans for consumer durables and housing. Quantitative evidence strongly supports the theoretical prediction that the expansion of credit should reduce private saving as individuals are able to finance higher consumption at their current income level. Loayza, Schmidt-Hebbel, and Serven (2000), find that a 1 percentage point increase in the ratio of private credit flows to income reduces the long-term private saving rate by 0.75 percentage point. Bandiera and others (2000), on carrying out a deeper analysis of eight episodes of financial liberalization, failed to find a systematic direct effect on saving rate: it was positive in some cases (Ghana and Turkey), clearly negative in others (Mexico and Korea), and negligible in the rest.

46

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

These studies however, have a number of shortcomings. To begin with, each of them focuses on only one of the determinants of saving. They therefore do not identify the determinants of saving and analyze their impact on the saving rate. In addition, the conclusion of Essien and Onwioduokit (1998) should be taken with a measure of caution. This is because the time span of their study is relatively short (1987-1993). It is therefore difficult to separate the effect of financial development from the effect of recovery and increased capital inflow to the economy, all of which were taking place concurrently. Our study will try to overcome this problem of simultaneity by using a longer time frame dating from 19702009.

Research Methodology The methodology used in this study is the Cointegration and Error-Correction Methodology (ECM). The ECM is made up of models in both levels and differences of variables and is compatible with long-run equilibrium behaviour. Model Specification Drawing from the analysis above on the life cycle framework, the following model was specified: PSR= 0 + 1GRCY +2RIR + 3FB + 4DFD + Where: 1 2 and 4 0, while 3 0 and PSR = private saving rate GRCY = growth rate of real per capita GNDI RIR = real interest rate FB = fiscal balance DFD = degree of financial depth The saving equation was estimated using annual data for the period 1970-2009. The estimation period was determined largely by the availability of adequate data on all variables. Descriptive Statistics. The characteristics of the distribution of the variables are presented in Table 1 below. Jarque-Bera is a test statistic for testing whether the series is normally distributed. The test statistic measures the difference of the skewness and the kurtosis of the series with those from the normal distribution. Evidently, the Jarque-Bera statistic rejects the null hypothesis of normal distribution for the real interest rate. On the contrary, the null hypothesis of normal distribution is accepted for degree of financial depth, fiscal balance, income growth and private saving. In Nigeria, as in most developing countries, due to the absence of detailed statistical coverage of sectoral financial activity, most of the data on saving are obtained from the national accounts statistics as the difference between measurable aggregates. This residual or indirect approach to the calculation of saving has some drawbacks. First, the saving of one group of economic units used by another for

47

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

consumption is not captured. Second, capital gains and losses induced by price changes are not treated adequately. Third, consumer durables and certain elements of government expenditure are also not adequately treated (see Shafer, Elmeskov, and Tease, 1992). For these reasons, the results obtained should be interpreted with caution. Table 2. Summary of the Descriptive Statistics of the Variables DFD Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera Probability Sum Sum Sq. Dev. Observations 24.24 24.00 35.00 12.00 6.39 -0.07 2.009 1.54 0.46 897.00 1472.81 37 FB -3.46 -3.50 9.80 -11.10 4.29 0.52 4.01 3.24 0.20 -127.99 661.12 37 GRCY 2.02 3.00 45.00 -31.00 17.84 0.48 3.33 1.61 0.45 74.70 11459.88 37 PSR 28.69 26.00 65.00 -0.60 12.79 0.56 4.05 3.65 0.16 1061.40 5886.52 37 RIR -5.31 -0.60 18.00 -52.60 16.01 -1.05 3.74 7.61 0.02 -196.40 9229.21 37

Source: National accounts statistics Results of Stationarity Tests Testing for the existence of unit roots is a principal concern in the study of time series models and cointegration. The presence of a unit root implies that the time series under investigation is non-stationary; while the absence of a unit roots shows that the stochastic process is stationary (see Iyoha and Ekanem, 2002). The time series behaviour of each of the series using the Augmented Dickey-Fuller and PhillipsPerron tests are presented in Tables 3 and 4, respectively. The results show that while the private saving rate (PSR), growth rate of real per capita GNDI (GRCY) and fiscal balance (FB) are I(0) variables (stationary before differencing), real interest rate (RIR) and the degree of financial depth (DFD) are I(1) variables (stationary after first differencing). This is deduced from the fact that the absolute values of both the ADF and PP test statistics of RIR, GRCY and FB before differencing are greater than the absolute value of the critical values at the 1 percent significance level. For the other variables, this is the case only after differencing once. Table 3. Results of Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) Unit Root Test Variable ADF Value before Differencing -3.657* ADF Value After Differencing n.a Critical Value Level of Integration I(0)

PSR

3.621

48

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
GRCY RIR FB DFD -5.068* -3.204 -4.450* -1.979 n.a -6.275* n.a -5.784*

www.iiste.org

3.627 3.621 3.621 3.621

I(0) I(1) I(0) I(1)

Notes: * denotes significant at 1 percent; the null hypothesis is that there is a unit root. n.a = not applicable

Table 4. Results of Phillips-Perron (PP) Unit Root Test Variable PP Value Before Differencing -3.683* -5.019* -3.045 -4.405* -2.047 PP Value After Differencing n.a n.a -13.017* n.a -5.784* Critical Value Level of Integration I(0) I(0) I(1) I(0) I(1)

PSR GRCY RIR FB DFD

3.621 3.627 3.621 3.621 3.621

Notes: * denotes significant at 1 percent; the null hypothesis is that there is a unit root. n.a = not applicable Cointegrated Models In this study, the method established by Johansen (see Johansen, 1991) was employed in carrying out the cointegration test. This is a powerful cointegration test, particularly when a multivariate model is used. Moreover, it is robust to various departures from normality in that it allows any of the five variables in the model to be used as the dependent variable while maintaining the same cointegration results. Accordingly, Johansens test was carried out to check if the saving equation is cointegrated. Table 5 shows that both the Trace and Maximum Eigen statistics rejected the null of no cointegration at the 5 percent level; while Trace test indicated that there are two cointegrating equations at the 5 percent level; Maximum Eigen test indicated only one cointegrating equation at the 5 percent level. The implication is that a linear combination of all the five series was found to be stationary and thus, are said to be cointegrated. In other words, there is a stable long-run relationship between them and so we can avoid both the spurious and inconsistent regression problems which otherwise would occur with regression of nonstationary data series. Table 5 Johansens Cointegration Test Results Maximum Eigenvalue Test Null Hypothesis r=0 Alternative Hypothesis r=1 Eigen-value Critical Value 95% 39.79* 37.5 99% r1 108.69* Alternative Hypothesis Trace Test LR Ratio Critical Value 95% 87.3 99% 96.58

49

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
2 r1 r2 r3 r4 r=2 r=3 r=4 r=5 31.30 18.02 16.09 3.49 31.4 6 25.5 4 18.9 6 12.2 5 42.3 6 36.6 5 30.3 4 23.6 5 16.2 6

www.iiste.org

* r2 r3 r4 r5 68.90* 37.60 19.58 3.49

1 62.9 9 42.4 4 19.5 8 12.2 5 70.05 48.45 30.45 16.26

Notes: * denotes significant at the 5% level ** denotes significant at the 1% level Long run Model We now present the results for the long run relationship. PSR = +0.4013 +0.5016GRCY +0.0028RIR -0.0190FB -0.1226DFD (3.346)** (2.233)* (3.769)** (0.459)

As postulated by our modified version of the lifecycle hypothesis, the income growth variable (GRCY) is an important determinant of the private saving rate. The coefficient of GRCY is both positively signed and statistically significant at the 1 percent level. An increase in the growth rate by one percent leads to a long-run increase in the saving rate by 0.5 percent. These results are consistent with those obtained by Modigliani (1970), Maddison (1992), Bosworth (1993) and Carroll and Weil (1994). Thus, as the incomes of private agents grow faster, their saving rate increases. This is consistent with the existence of consumption habits and our modified version of the Lifecycle model. The implication is that any policy that encourages income growth in the long run will have a strong impact on private saving rate. Given the historical close link between saving and investment rate, a rise in growth rate will lead to a virtuous cycle of higher income and saving rates. The result for the real interest rate variable suggests that the real rate of return on bank deposits has a statistically significant positive effect on saving behaviour in Nigeria. A one percent increase in RIR is associated with a 0.003 percentage point increase in the private saving rate. This finding is consistent with the McKinnon-Shaw proposition which states that, in an economy where the saving behaviour is highly intensive in money and near-money assets, the direct incentive effect of high real interest rates on saving behaviour (i.e. the income effect) generally overwhelms the substitution of other assets for financial assets in response when faced with such interest rate changes (i.e. the substitution effect). The implication is that government should find an effective mechanism for increasing the abysmally low interest rate on bank deposits if the present crusade to increase the private saving rate is to achieve any measure of success. The result for fiscal balance points to a significant substitutability between public and private saving in the Nigerian context. However, there is no support for full Ricardian equivalence, which predicts

50

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

full counterbalancing of public saving by private dis-saving. Specifically, an improvement in the fiscal balance by one percent is associated with 0.019 percentage point reduction in the private saving rate. The rather weak private saving offset to changes in the fiscal balance behaviour may be explained by substantial uncertainty in the economy, widespread liquidity (or wealth) constraints, tax-induced distortions and limits in households attempts to smooth consumption over time. Thus in the Nigerian context, policies geared to improvement in fiscal balance has the potential of bringing about a substantial net increase in total domestic saving. This finding is consistent with cross-country results of Corbo and Schmidt-Hebbel (1991) and those of Athukorala and Sen (2004) for India. The degree of financial depth failed to attain statistical significance in the saving function. Thus, there is no empirical support for the view that the development of the financial sector has contributed to the growth in private saving. The implication is that financial deepening may not bring about an automatic improvement in the saving rate. For this, one requires a deeper analytical understanding of the various factors at work here.

Empirical Results Dynamic Error-Correction Model Having identified the cointegrating vector using Johansen, we proceed to investigate the dynamics of the saving process. Table 6 reports the final parsimonious estimated equation together with a set of commonly used diagnostic statistics. The estimated saving function performs well by the relevant diagnostic tests. In terms of the Chow test for parameter stability conducted by splitting the total sample period into 1970-1986 and 1987-2009 there is no evidence of parameter instability. The results show that the coefficient of the error-correction term for the estimated saving equation is both statistically significant and negative. Thus, it will rightly act to correct any deviations from long-run equilibrium. Specifically, if actual equilibrium value is too high, the error correction term will reduce it, while if it is too low, the error correction term will raise it. The coefficient of -0.4415 denotes that 44 percent of any past deviation will be corrected in the current period. Thus, it will take more than two years for any disequilibrium to be corrected. The Keynesian absolute income hypothesis is found to hold for saving behavior in Nigeria. The coefficient for real per capita GNDI (GRCY) is positive and statistically significant at the 1 percent level. Thus the Nigerian experience provides support for the argument that, for countries in the initial stages of development, the level of income is an important determinant of the capacity to save. In this respect, our results are consistent with the cross-country results of Modigliani (1993), Hussein and Thirlwall (1999), Loayza et al (2000) and the results for India of Athukorala and Sen (2004). This implies that the high unemployment rate which results in low disposable income is a strong impediment in raising the saving rate in Nigeria. Contrary to the postulation of the Life-Cycle Model, the income growth variable (GRCY) was found to have a significant negative impact on the private saving rate. This result is interesting given that it

51

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

does not conform to those obtained from earlier studies (see Modigliani, 1970; Madison, 1992; Bosworth, 1993 and Carroll and Weil, 1994). Our Nigerian experience seems to provide support for the simple permanent income theory which predicts that higher growth (i.e. higher future income) could reduce current saving. In other words, at sufficiently high rates of economic growth, the aggregate saving rate may decrease if the lifetime wealth of the young is high enough relative to that of their elders (see Athukorala and Sen, 2004). There are two plausible explanations for this finding. The first is the penchant of Nigerians to indulge in conspicuous consumption. As a result, growth in per capita income could actually lead to a decrease in saving. The second is that income growth was actually negative in roughly half of the period under observation. Table 6. Estimated Short Run Regression Results for the Private Saving Model Dependent Variable: DPSR Included observations: 35 after adjusting endpoints. Variable C DPSR(-1) DGRCY DRIR(-1) DFB DDFD ECM(-1) Adjusted R-squared S.E of regression DurbinWatson stat Coefficient 0.1137 0.0303 0.3047 -0.0016 -0.0054 0.8020 -0.4415 0.3356 0.0867 2.2200 T-Statistic 2.9728 0.1952 3.5435 -1.6013 -1.2194 1.6733 -3.3118 S.D Dependent Var. F-Statistic Prob. (F-statistic) Probability 0.0063 0.8467 0.0015 0.1214 0.2337 0.1063 0.0027 0.1064 3.6936 0.0087

JBN 2 (1) = 0.33 Probability (JBN) = 0.85 ARCH 2 (1) = 1.0 Probability (ARCH) = 0.32

LM 2 (1) = 1.92 Probability (LM) = 0.18 CHOW 2 (1) = 1.6 Probability (CHOW) = 0.20

Furthermore, it is only the income growth variable that is statistically significant at the 1 percent level, indicating that in the short run, it is only growth in income that has a relationship with the private saving rate. The implication is that short run changes in private saving rate that correct for past deviations emanate principally from changes in income growth. The coefficient estimate shows that a unit change in income growth will bring about a 0.3 percent change in private saving. The other four explanatory variables (PSR (-1), RIR, FB and DFD) do not have any short run impact on the private saving rate. This result is in keeping with the long run relationship where over 50 percent of changes in private saving are explained by changes in income growth.

52

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
Conclusion

www.iiste.org

This paper has investigated the determinants of private saving in Nigeria for the period 1970-2009. In the first place, it attempts to shed more light on the problems associated with the conventional models of determinants of saving. Drawing on econometric analysis, it goes on to propose the alternative of an ErrorCorrection Model of the determinants of saving function. The estimation results for the long run model point to the growth in income and the real interest rate as having statistically significant positive influences on domestic saving. There is also a clear role for fiscal policy in increasing total saving in the economy, with the private sector considering public saving as an imperfect substitute for its own saving. The Ricardian equivalence was thus, found not to hold in Nigeria contrary to what obtains in industrialized and semi-industrialized economies. Finally, financial development seems not to have any impact on the saving rate. We began this study by asking what the relevant policies for raising the Nigerian saving rate are. Our results help to understand the effectiveness of policy variables in raising the saving rate in terms of their magnitude and direction. Policy Implications A stronger policy framework is imperative in bringing about improved macroeconomic performance. The government should sustain its National Economic Empowerment and Development Strategy (NEEDS) programme which is partly responsible for the increasing diversification emerging in the economy. The growing contribution of non-oil sectors in GDP growth in recent years is a positive development and should be encouraged. Agriculture has grown strongly in recent years and was the largest industry contribution to GDP in 2009. With about 70 per cent of the working population employed in the agricultural sector, the strong agricultural contribution to GDP bodes well for employment. More importantly, governments efforts to diversify the economy appear to be yielding results and should be sustained. Recommendations Some major recommendations for policy can be drawn from the analysis. First, the focus of development policy in Nigeria should be to increase the productive base of the economy in order to promote real income growth and reduce unemployment. For this to be achieved, a diversification of the countrys resource base is indispensable. This policy thrust should include a return to agriculture; the adoption of a comprehensive energy policy, with stable electricity as a critical factor; the establishment of a viable iron and steel industry; the promotion of small and medium scale enterprises, as well as a serious effort at improving information technology. Second, contrary to popular belief, income growth has a negative influence on private saving in Nigeria. Policy makers should thus take explicit account of this result in the formulation of economic policy. For instance past experience has shown that rapid increases in wages of urban sector workers did not result in any appreciable increase in private saving. Rather, the extra income was used in the purchase of mainly imported consumer goods, thus increasing our dependence on imports. Third, public saving has been shown to be a complement rather than a substitute for private saving in Nigeria. Government should therefore sustain its oil- price-based fiscal rule (OPFR) which is designed to

53

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

link government spending to notional long run oil price, thereby de-linking government spending from current oil revenues. This mechanism will drastically reduce the short term impact of fluctuations in the oil price on governments fiscal programmes. State governments should also desist from spending their share of excess crude oil revenue indiscriminately. This is because this practice can severely test the absorptive capacity of the economy in addition to risking the fuelling of inflation. The challenge is for state governments to save excess revenue or spend it directly on imported capital goods in order to sustain Nigerias hard-won macroeconomic stability. Fourth, monetary policy should focus on ways of increasing the abysmally low real interest rate on bank deposits. It should also devise means of substantially reducing the interest rate spread. Lastly, it is pertinent to note that even though this paper has concentrated on Nigeria, its results can be applied to other African countries not previously studied. They contain some valuable lessons for informing policy measures in the current thrust towards greater mobilization of private saving in the African continent. References Aghevli, Bijan, James Boughton, Peter Montiel, Delano Villanueva, and Geoffrey Woglom. 1990. The Role of National Saving in the World Economy: Recent Trends and Prospects. IMF Occasional Paper No. 67. Ajakaiye,Obadan, and Ayodele Odusola 1995. Real Deposit Rates and Financial Savings Mobilization in Nigeria: An Empirical Test. Journal of Economic Management. Vol.2. No.2 October 1995. Amoateng, Kofi A. 2002. Do Stock and Home Ownership Influence U.S. Personal Savings? Managerial Finance 28 no.4: 1-11. www.emeraldinsight.com (accessed September 5, 2006) Ando, Albert and Franco Modigliani. 1962. The Life Cycle Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate Implications and Tests. The American Economic Review 52 no.5 (Dec):55-82 Athukorala, Prema-Chandra, and Kunal Sen. 2004 The Determinants of Private Saving in India, World Development, Vol. 32, No. 3, pp. 491-503. Bandiera, Oriana, Gerard Caprio, Patrick Honohan, and Fabio Schiantarelli. 2000. Does Financial Reform Raise or Reduce Private Saving?, Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(2): 239-263. Barro, Robert. 1974. Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?, Journal of Political Economy, 82(6): 10951117. Bosworth, B.P. 1993. Saving and Investment in a Global Economy. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution. Carroll, Christopher, and David Weil. 1994. Saving and Growth: A Reinterpretation. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 40:133-192. Central Bank of Nigeria. 2003 & 2006. CBN Statistical Bulletin. Abuja, Nigeria Chete, Louis. 1999. Macroeconomic Determinants of Private Savings in Nigeria. Monograph Series No. 7. Nigerian Institute of Social and Economic Research (NISER). Collins, S.M. 1991. Savings Behaviour in Ten Developing Countries, in B.D.

54

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Corbo, Vittorio, and Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel. 1991. Public Policies and Saving in Developing Countries, Journal of Development Economics, 36(1) :89-115. Craigwell, R. 1991. Demand for money in Jamaica: A Cointegration Approach. Money Affairs, Vol. 4, pp 19-41 Dickey, D. and W. Fuller. 1981. Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit root. Econometrica, 50, 1057-1072 Douglas and J.B. Shoven, (eds): National Savings and Economic Performance. National Bureau of economic research, University of Chicago Press Downes, A., C. Holder, and H. Leon. 1991. A Cointegration Approach to Modelling Inflation in a Small Open Economy, Journal of Economic Development, Vol. 16, No. 1, pp. 57-67. Edwards, S. 1995. Why are Savings Rates so Different across Countries? An International Comparative Analysis, NBER Working Paper No. 5097 Essien, E, and Onwioduokit. 1989. Recent Developments in Econometrics: An Application to Financial Liberalization and Saving in Nigeria. NDIC Quarterly, Vol.8, No. 112. Gersovitz, M. 1988. Saving and Development, in H. Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan, eds., Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. 1, Amsterdam: Elsevier. Hussein, K. and A. Thirlwall. 1999. Explaining differences in the domestic savings ratio across countries:A panel data study.Journal of Development Studies,36,31-52. International Monetary Fund (IMF). 1999, 2006. International Financial Statistics Yearbook. Washington, D.C. Iyoha, Milton, and O.T. Ekanem. 2002. Introduction to Econometrics. Mareh Publishers, Benin City, Nigeria. Johansen, S. 1991. Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors, in Gaussian vector autoregressive models. Econometrica, 59:1551-1580. Juster, F.T. and L.D. Taylor 1975. Towards a Theory of Saving Behaviour, American Economic Review 65 (May) pp.203-204 Keynes, J.M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, London: MacMillan and Company Ltd Khan, M and D Villanueva. 1991. Macroeconomic Policies and Long-term Growth. AERC Special Paper, 13, May, p.39. Kimbal, M. 1990. Precautionary Saving in the Small and the Large, Econometrica, 58, 53-73. Levine, Ross, and David Renelt. 1992. A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions. American Economic Review 82(4): 942-963 Lewis, Arthur. 1955. Theory of Economic Growth, London: Allen and Unwin.

55

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Loayza, Norman, Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, and Luis Serven. 2000. What Drives Private saving Across the World? Review of Economics and Statistics 82(2):165-181. Maddison, Angus. 1992. A Long-Run Perspective on saving. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 94(2): 181-196. Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weil. 1992. A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2): 407-437. McKinnon, R. 1973. Money and Capital in economic development. Washington, D.C: The Brooking Institute. Modigliani, Franco. 1970. The Life-Cycle Hypothesis of Saving and Inter-country Differences in the saving Ratio. In W.A Eltis, M.F.G. Scott, and J.N. Wolfe, eds., Induction, Trade, and Growth: Essays in Honour of Sir Roy Harrod. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Modigliani, F. 1992. Savings in Developing Countries: Income, Growth and Other Factors Pacific Basin Capital Markets Research, Vol. 3, pp.23-35 Mwega, Francis. 1997. Saving in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Comparative Analysis. Journal of African Economies. 6(3) (Supplement) 199-228. Nwankwo, Green O. (1994). The Nigerian Financial system. London: Macmillan Publishers Ltd. Schmidt-Hebbel, Klaus, Steven B. Webb, and Giancarlo Corsettii. 1992. Household Saving in Developing Countries: First cross-country Evidence. The World Bank Economic Review 6(3): 529-547. Shafik, N. 1992. Modelling Private Investment in Egypt. Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 39, pp. 263-277. Shaw, E. 1973. Financial deepening in economic development. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Summers, L. H., and C. Carroll. 1989. The Growth-Saving Nexus, Paper presented to National Bureau of Economic Research Conference of Saving, Maui, Hawaii, January. Umoh,O.J. 2003. An Empirical Investigation of the Determinants of Aggregate National Savings in Nigeria, Journal of Monetary and Economic Integration, Vol. 3, No. 2 (December 2003) pp.113-132 Uremadu, S.O. 2006a. The Impact of Real Interest Rate on Savings Mobilisation in Nigeria: An Error Correction Approach, An Unpublished Project Proposal to CBNs Application for Diaspora Collaborative Research Program (DCRP)/Visiting Research Scholars Program (VRSP), 2006 ----- 2006b. The Impact of Real Interest Rate on Savings Mobilisation in Nigeria, An unpublished Ph.D. Thesis Proposal submitted to the Department of Banking and Finance, UNN, Enugu Campus ----- 2002. Introduction to Finance. Benin: Mindex Publishing Company Ltd. pp, 1-7

56

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Monetary Policy and Output-inflation Volatility Interaction in Nigeria: Evidence from Bivariate GARCH-M Model

Onyukwu E. Onyukwu (corresponding author) Department of Economics, University of Nigeria, Nsukka, Enugu State, Nigeria Tel: +234-8034741642 E-mail: oonyukwu@yahoo.com Emmanuel O. Nwosu Department of Economics, University of Nigeria, Nsukka Enugu State, Nigeria E-mail: emmanuel.nwosu@unn.edu.ng Diejomaoh Ito African Institute for Applied Economics 54 Nza Street, Independence Layout, Enugu, Nigeria E-mail: idiejomaoh@aiaenigeria.org

Received: October 11st, 2011 Accepted: October 19th, 2011 Published: October 30th, 2011 Abstract This article reports on a recent study that applies bivariate GARCH methodology to investigate the existence of a tradeoff between output growth and inflation variability in Nigeria and to ascertain the impact of monetary policy regime changes (from direct control regime to indirect or market based regime) on the nature of the volatility tradeoffs. Investigations reveal the existence of a short run tradeoff relationship between output growth and inflation within and across both regimes. However, no strong evidence of long run volatility relationship could be established. Our results further reveal that regime changes affected the magnitude of policy effects on output and inflation. Monetary policy had a stronger effect on output growth than on price stability during the period of direct control while it has a much larger impact on inflation during the current period of market-based regime. Also volatility of output and inflation

57

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
became more persistent during the period of indirect control.

www.iiste.org

Keywords: Monetary Policy, Output-Inflation Volatility, Bivariate GARCH-M Model

58

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

1. Introduction and Background to the Study Over the past four decades, economists and policy makers have shown considerable interest in understanding causes of macroeconomic volatility and how to reduce it. Conceptually, macroeconomic instability refers to conditions in which the domestic macroeconomic environment is less predictable. It is of concern because unpredictability hampers resource allocation decisions, investment, and growth. This article focuses on the volatility interaction of the growth rate of output and the levels of inflation rates. Changes in the behavior of these endogenous variables usually reflect changes in the macroeconomic policy environment as well as external shocks. Both Okonjo-Iweala & Phillip (2006) and Baltini (2004) have described the Nigerian macroeconomic environment as one of the most volatile among emerging markets. Among emerging market economies, Nigeria exhibits the highest inflation and exchange rate variability, the lowest output volatility, and an interest rate volatility that is slightly smaller than that of South Africa and much smaller than that of Brazil, but slightly larger than that of Chile (Baltini 2004). Nigeria offers unique opportunity to the study of output-inflation volatility interaction and its relationship with monetary policy. This is due to the fact that monetary policy conduct in Nigeria has witnessed two alternative regimes since the mid-1970s, the direct control regime and indirect or market-based regime with different relative weights attached to output growth and price stability objectives.

1.1 Statement of the Problem


This study evaluates the effect of monetary policy regime changes, by estimating a bivariate GARCHM model of output and, thus examines the nature of output-inflation variability trade-off as well as volatility persistence which are of major interest in macroeconomic policy debates. Our study further ascertains the efficacy of monetary policy regime change from direct to indirect approaches (Note 1) in reducing macroeconomic volatility, particularly in the light of the Taylor curve tradeoff hypothesis. Thus, our basic research objectives are: To ascertain if there is evidence of output-inflation volatility trade-off in Nigeria;
To investigate if a change in monetary policy regime affects the nature of output growth-inflation volatility tradeoff. To ascertain how monetary policy shocks affect inflation and output growth variability dynamics.

What is remaining of this article has been organized into three sections. Section two is devoted to an overview of relevant theoretical framework and methodology of analysis. Section three presents and discusses the results of our analyses. Section four summarizes the study findings and makes some policy recommendations.

59

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

The period covered by the study is 1981 to 2007, essentially due to data availability. The study period cuts across two monetary policy regimes, thus affording us the opportunity to make sub-sample comparisons. The study uses quarterly data in the analysis in order to capture substantial variability in the variables of interest.
2. Methodology of Study

On the relationships between monetary policy, output volatility, and inflation volatility, one theory holds that the volatility of output and inflation will be smaller the stronger monetary policy reacts to inflation than output gap (Gaspar & Smets 2002) (Note 2). In this case it is customary to assume that the economys social loss function is the sum of the variance of inflation and output. If the economy is hit by demand shocks, the central bank will never face a trade-off between output stability and inflation stability, that is, a monetary policy action that reduces output volatility is consistent with stable inflation. However, in a more general case when the economy is hit by demand shocks as well as supply shocks, the central bank faces an inescapable tradeoff between output stability and inflation stability if it chooses, (as is commonly the case), to minimize the social loss function. Thus, monetary policy action which reduces the variance of inflation will increase the variance of output, and vice versa. These hypotheses have been jointly studied using bivariate GARCH-M class of models (Fountas et al 2002; Grier et al 2004; Lee 2002). According to Lee (2004), the GARCH approach has two major advantages over the conventional measure of volatility, such as moving standard deviations and squared residual terms in vector autoregression (VAR) models. The first advantage is that conditional volatility, as compared to unconditional volatility, better represents perceived uncertainty which is of particular interest to policy makers. The second advantage is that the GARCH model offers insights into the hypothesized volatility relationship in both the short run and the long run. Whereas timevarying conditional variances reveal volatility dynamics in the short run, the model also generates a long run measure of the output-inflation covariance that will be helpful in evaluating monetary policy tradeoffs. These inform the use of bivariate GARCH model in this study.

2.1 Our Empirical Models


Following Fountas et al. (2002), Grier et al. (2004) and Lee (2002) we use a bivariate GARCH model to simultaneously estimate the conditional variances and covariance of inflation and output growth in order to address our first and second research questions. We employ the following bivariate VAR (p) model for estimating the conditional means of output and inflation:

60

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
p p

www.iiste.org

t = 0 + 1i t i + 2j Yt j + t .......... .........1 .1
i =1 j=1

where t / t ~ N(0, H t ) and is informatio n set available up to time t - 1 such that H t = (h yt , h t ) 0 = yo , 0 is a 2x1 vector of constants t = [ y t , t ] is a 2 x 1 vector of real output growth y t and inflation rate t . t is a vector of additional explanator y variable s such as inflation uncertaint y, etc 1i , 2j are vectors of 2x2 matrices of parameters to be estimated. t = yt , t is a 2x1 vector of output and inflation innovation s. The vector of conditional variances of output and inflation are specified as follows:

61

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

' C + A H A + B B + D F D. . . . 1. .2. . . . . H t = C0 0 t 1 t 1 t 1 t 1 w hH t e= ( ryh e, ht t ) i as 2 xv 1eo c ft tch ooe r n l dv i at iro oiofanuna t cnpi nedu sf t l a t i o n C A B, a, ,nD a d 2r eux p2 pn eg rmu t laraoit praf ia c r ea; a smnF i dase v t eo rcefstx o p ry l a vn sa a, t h i asF = ,t( M PO Ri l ,ep t r c i )c . e s , M e o x r pe tl mhi ce aio t plfr yai cr eac mab sne ep te ei cnur ispf ipne egd rf uo tal r:asmra i c1 c1 2 a1 a1 2 b1 b1 2 C0 = ; A = ; B = ; a 0 c2 2 a 2 1a 2 2 b2 1b 2 2 1 1 2 nD = d . 2 1 2 2

62

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

2.2 Economic Meaning of Coefficients and Apriori Expectations


The diagonal elements in matrix Co represent the means of conditional variances of output growth and inflation, while the off diagonal element represents their covariance. The Parameters in matrix A depict the extents to which the current levels of conditional variances are correlated with their past levels. In specific terms, the diagonal elements (a11 and a22) reflect the levels of persistence in the conditional variances; a12 captures the extent to which the conditional variance of output is correlated with the lagged conditional variance of inflation. For the existence of output-inflation volatility tradeoff, the variable is expected to have negative sign and be statistically significant. The parameters in matrix B reveal the extents to which the conditional variances of inflation and output are correlated with past squared innovations; b12 depicts how the conditional variance of output is correlated with the past innovation of inflation. This measures the existence of cross-effect from an output shock to inflation volatility. In order to estimate the impact of monetary policy on the conditional variances, we include one period lagged change in the Central Banks monetary policy rate (MPR) (or VAR-based generated monetary surprises) in the vector F. The resulting coefficients in matrix D measure the effects of these variables on inflation and output volatility. For monetary policy to have a trade-off on the conditional variances, the diagonal elements have to alternate in signs. In order to address the third research question we augment the VAR model specified in (1) by adding monetary policy variable in the vector X and then compute the generalized impulse responses and generalized variance decompositions to analyse the short run dynamic response of output growth and inflation monetary policy shocks/innovations. The generalized variance decomposition and impulse response functions are unique solution and invariant to the ordering of the variables in the VAR (Pesaran & Shin 1998). Also, it has been argued, however, that in the short run unrestricted VARs perform better than a cointegrating VAR. For example, Naka & Tufte (1997) studied the performance of VECMs and unrestricted VARs for impulse response analysis over the short-run and found that the performance of the two methods is nearly identical. We adopt unrestricted VARs in attempting to answer our third research question because of the short-term nature of the variance decomposition and impulse response analysis. AIC and SBC will be used for lag order selection.

2.3

Method of Estimation and Data Sources

The models are estimated by the method of Broyden, Fletcher, Goldferb and Shanno (BFGS) simplex algorithm. We employed the RATS software in the estimation of the system. This is due to the fact that RATS has an inbuilt bivariate GARCH system that supports simultaneous estimation and thus is able to implement different restrictions that might be assumed on the variance-covariance structure of the system. The data used for the estimations are quarterly data from the Central Bank of Nigeria Statistical 63

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Bulletin of various years, the Annual Report and Statement of Account of various years. Monetary Policy Measure: According to Nnanna (2001) the Minimum Rediscount Rate (MRR) is the nominal anchor, which influences the level and direction of other interest rates in the domestic money market. Its movements are generally intended to signal to market operators the monetary policy stance of the CBN. Similarly, Agu (2007) observes that the major policy instrument for monetary policy in Nigeria is the minimum rediscount rate (MRR) of the Central Bank and notes that while both interest and inflation rates are high, a worrisome problem in the observed response to these macroeconomic imbalances is the lack of policy consistency and coherence. This could be on account of inadequate information on the nature and size of impact of the MRR on key macroeconomic aggregates. This type of inconsistency in the conduct of monetary policy is likely to increase rather than stabilize macroeconomic volatility. Hence, we shall use MRR (MPR) as a measure of monetary policy stance.
3. Presentation of Results and Discussion

Table 1 shows the summary statistics of the variables used in the study. Inflation and GDP growth rates are calculated as annualized quarterly growth rates of consumer price index (CPI) and real GDP respectively. As the table indicates, average nominal GDP was almost two times greater in 1995-2007 period compared to 1981-1994 period. But, the consumer price index for the period, 1995-2007, was almost twenty fold of that in the period, 1981-1994. For this reason average real GDP for the period 1995 to 2007 was lower than that of 1981-1994. However, the average growth rate of real GDP was higher in the second period compared to the first; while average inflation rate for the second period was lower compared to the first period. This shows that the economy performed better on the average under market-based monetary regime compared to the controlled regime. The standard deviation of inflation is lower in the second period implying lower unconditional volatility and there is no significant change in the unconditional volatility of real GDP growth which appears to suggest that real quarterly GDP fluctuations are modest over the two periods but slightly higher in the second period. The minimum rediscount rate, a measure of monetary policy stance of the Central Bank of Nigeria (CBN) was on the average lower during the controlled regime period compared to the indirect regime period. This suggests that monetary policy became tighter during the period of indirect or market-based regime aimed specifically to control inflation by reducing the rate of money growth. Oil prices being used to control for exogenous shocks in the model had a low average during the period of controlled regime. At that time lower oil prices affected GDP growth adversely as the economy entered into a recession that led to the introduction the Structural Adjustment Programme (SAP), which further depressed the economy. The adverse supply effect resulting from SAP and lower oil revenue together with tighter controls on interest rate helped to put a strain on the economy. During the period of indirect monetary approach, oil prices began to increase rapidly in the international market and this resulted in positive output growth for most of the period and quick recovery of the economy from the adverse effects of SAP. However, the Central Bank has been very cautious with rising oil prices and as a result has been setting the minimum rediscount rate in order to accommodate 64

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

the adverse effects of the rise in oil prices on inflation. Table 2 shows the tests for serial correlation, autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity effect, and normality. A series of Ljung-Box (1978) tests for serial correlation suggests that there is a significant amount of serial dependence in the data. Output growth is negatively skewed, and inflation is positively skewed and output growth failed to satisfy the Jarque-Bera tests for normality (Jarque & Bera 1980). The ARCH tests also reveal the presence of first order serial dependence in the conditional variances of output growth and inflation suggesting that our application of GARCH (1, 1) model is appropriate to the data. Valid inference from GARCH model requires that the variables be stationary, at least in their conditional means (Lee 2002). As a result, unit root tests were conducted on the variables using the Dickey & Fuller (1981) methodology. The analysis, however, was eventually based on the augmented Dickey-Fuller unit root tests. The results are presented in table 3 below. The results show that only inflation rate is level stationary while other variables are stationary in their first differences. Table 4 shows the results from GARCH estimations of the two sub-samples and the overall sample. The results would help to address our concerns in the first and second research questions, which are: whether or not the change in the approach to monetary policy in Nigeria from direct to indirect led to a change in volatility interactions, transmissions and tradeoff between output growth and inflation. The results are in two parts. The first part shows the estimations of the conditonal mean equation while the second part shows the time-varying conditional variance equation which is of particular interest to us. The first part of the conditional mean and conditonal variance eqautions represents output growth while the second vector denotes inflation rate. The conditional mean for GDP growth shows that inflation volatility does affect output growth negatively and this is statistically significant across the two regimes but was highly significant during the period of indirect regime. But the effect of inflation volatility on inflation was not certain as the cofficient was neither stable nor significant across the two periods. Past levels of inflation are found to have positive effects on currrent inflation levels and this is significant across the two samples while the coefficient was almost the same across the two periods. Oil price shocks do not have any meaningful effect on inflation but do have positive and significant effects on output growth especially in the second period. This may be due to the fact that oil price increases which characterized most of the sample period from 1995 to 2007 may have contributed positively to the output growth in Nigeria as a largely oil dependent economy. This result should not be surprising as most studies have found positive output effect of oil price shocks in major oilexporting countries. We are especially interested in the conditional variance equations. The estimates show that the long run or unconditional volatilities of inflation and output growth were higher in the first period than in the second period. The estimates for the mean covariance terms are negative and but significant only in the first sample period. The estimates also indicate that over the sample periods, the mean unconditional variance of output is significant across the two sample periods. The parameters in matrix A show the extents to which the current levels of conditional variance are correlated with their past levels. The higher estimates in the second period seem to suggest that a 65

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

current shock will have relatively long lasting effects on the future levels of the conditional variances of output growth and inflation than it had in the first sample period. The estimates also reveal that following change in monetary policy regime, inflation volatility and output volatility have relatively become more persistent in Nigeria. The off-diagonal elements in A that is A (1, 2), on the other hand, reveal the extent to which the conditional variance of one variable is correlated with the lagged conditional variance of another variable. The estimate for A (1, 2) appears with the expected negative sign and is statistically different from zero for all sub-samples and the overall sample. This confirms the existence of Taylor-curve volatility tradeoff in Nigeria. Interestingly the estimate for the sample period 1981 to 1994 is relatively larger than the estimates for the sample period 1995 to 2007 suggesting that low inflation variability is now associated with higher output gap variability. This seems to suggest that CBNs efforts to stabilize prices or specifically to target low inflation must come at a heavy cost of output fluctuations. This result is therefore, consistent with the finding by Castelnuovo (2006) that the tighter the monetary policy, the higher is the inflation-output gap volatility. The parameters in B matrix reveal the extents to which the conditional variances of inflation and output are correlated with past squared innovations (deviations from their conditional means). Of particular interest is the off-diagonal elements B (1, 2) and B (2, 1) which depict how the conditional variance of inflation is correlated with the past squared innovations of output. In the first sample period there is a positive and significant volatility cross-effect from inflation to output. While in the second period there is positive and significant volatility cross effect from output growth to inflation variability. In order to address the third research question we computed the impulse responses and variance decompositions from the VAR specification augmented by including monetary policy variable as one of the endogenous variables in equation (1.1) and then using oil prices as exogenous variable. We computed separate impulse responses and forecast error variance decompositions for each variable for the two regime periods in order to understand how output growth and inflation respond to innovations in monetary policy over the two regimes (see Figure 1 and Table 5 in the appendix). The impulse response functions are interpreted in conjunction with the variance decompositions. For example, in the period of direct control regime, inflation responded negatively to innovations in monetary policy but the variance decompositions show that this response was not significant because monetary policy only account for a small part of the forecast error variance of inflation and this seems to remain constant in the long run. During the period of indirect regime inflation also responded negatively to innovations to monetary policy but monetary shocks accounted for larger part of its forecast error variance, which is almost twice that of the direct control period. Real GDP growth rate responded positively to innovations in monetary policy during the direct approach. This may be due to the positive effects of low interest rates pursued during most of that period. The variance decomposition of output growth shows that monetary policy accounted for a larger part of the forecast error variance of output growth during the period of direct control regime than it accounts for inflation. This result is expected because the primary objective of monetary policy then was to achieve rapid output growth. However, inflation innovations had larger effect on output 66

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

growth in both periods of monetary regimes showing that inflation volatility is very crucial in determining movements in output variance. During the two regimes output growth responded negatively to shocks on inflation. This finding is consistent with the results in the GARCH estimations. During the period of the indirect regime output growth responded negatively to innovations to monetary policy and this shows there is existence of policy tradeoff between inflation and output growth. The pursuance of low inflation objective during the period of indirect regime does trigger off negative output reactions. The variance decomposition shows that this reaction is not significant since monetary policy shocks account for an insignificant part of forecast error variance of output growth even in the long run.
4. Summary, Policy Recommendations and Conclusion

4.1 Summary of Findings


The study on which report this article focuses investigated the existence of tradeoff relationship between output growth and inflation in Nigeria and the impact of alternative monetary policy regimes on inflation and output growth. The study findings show evidence of short-run tradeoff relationship between the variability of output growth and inflation but no evidence strong long run volatility relationship was found. The study also found that monetary policy accounted for a larger part of the forecast error variance of output growth during the period of direct control monetary policy than in the period of indirect control monetary policy. This result was expected given that the objective of monetary policy during the direct control regime was to achieve rapid and stable output growth. On the other hand, the response of inflation to monetary policy changes in the period of indirect or market-based regime was larger compared to its response during the period of direct control. Again, this result is not surprising because the major focus of monetary policy in Nigeria during the period of indirect control was to achieve low inflation. The results of the study further reveal that the volatility of output growth and inflation during the period of market-based policy regime are more persistent compared to the period of direct controls. Evidence of volatility cross-effect from output to inflation and vice versa was present but not significant across the two sample periods. The results fail to establish clearly any evidence to suggest that monetary policy tradeoff is a long run phenomenon. From these findings, the following policy recommendations could be made.

4.2

Policy Recommendations

Market-based or indirect control approach to monetary policy conduct in Nigeria should be carefully examined regularly in order to ascertain its desirability and workability. This would help to determine when changes in monetary policy stance actually affect the variability of output and inflation and in what direction. Policy makers should be careful not to believe too fervently that the market works in 67

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Nigeria. Policy changes could trigger off more volatility than demand or supply shocks. This reflects the fact that market imperfection is very typical of developing countries with underdeveloped financial markets. In Nigeria, it is hard to believe that inflation is caused by excessive money growth or the growth of credit. Instead, inflation has been driven largely by high cost of doing business, rising cost of energy prices and depreciating exchange rate that has made the cost of imported raw materials exceedingly high. This has intensified the effect of adverse supply shocks on inflation. Again, the size of the informal and non-monetized sector of the economy is quite substantial making it possible for monetary policy to have a big impact. In such a macroeconomic environment, tightening of monetary policy in response to high inflation would exacerbate an already heated environment by increasing the cost of credit to firms that depend on borrowing as the major source of finance. Our study reveals that volatility tradeoff is higher during the period of indirect monetary regime than during the period of direct control and that output is responding negatively to monetary shocks. This implies that the Central Bank should be very cautious of the objective of targeting low inflation as such a policy could trigger off not only low output growth but also high output growth volatility. Finally, we suggest that monetary policy instruments be supported by other fiscal and physical measures such as ensuring that energy cost, the cost of imported raw materials and possibly the cost of housing are reduced through other improved supply-side processes. While, attention is being focus on low inflation it is also pertinent to realize that high and stable output growth objective is equally important to Nigeria as a developing economy. There should be a balance between output growth objective and low inflation. The study reveals that monetary policy objective that targets low inflation would be likely achieved at a heavy cost in terms of adverse output growth effect.

4.3

Conclusion

This study has shown that there is very little empirical evidence to suggest that monetary policy regime change necessarily alters existing inflation-output growth variability tradeoff. It could not find strong evidence of long run tradeoff between output growth and inflation, which is required in order to ascertain the effectiveness of monetary policy regime changes from that perspective. This is not altogether surprising as half of the studies undertaken on this same issue in other jurisdictions have thus far found no evidence of long run policy tradeoff (see Lee 2004 for example). However, most studies did find that volatility tradeoff changed when monetary policy regime changed, this study seems to corroborate the same findings. It is perhaps important to observe here that the availability of good quality macroeconomic data at short-time intervals like monthly or quarterly series remains a major challenge to policy-relevant research in Nigeria. However, the situation is not very much different in most other developing countries. Using extrapolated quarterly GDP data in empirical studies of this nature may influence the research outcomes since such data were econometrically generated under certain assumptions. Further research is therefore recommended in this issue in the future, particularly as high frequency and good quality data begin to be available. It would indeed be very informative to policy makers in Nigeria who are currently experimenting with the adoption of inflation targeting monetary policy regime to read this research output. It will perhaps assist them in 68

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

appreciating the cost of such regime in terms of output growth volatility.

References

Agu, C. (2007). What Does the Central Bank of Nigeria Target: An Analysis of Monetary Policy Reaction Function in Nigeria. African Economic Research Consortium (AERC), Nairobi, Kenya. Baltini, N. (2004). Achieving and Maintaining Price Stability in Nigeria. IMF Working Paper, WP/04/97. Castelnuovo, E. (2006). Monetary Policy Switch, the Taylor Curve and Great Moderation, [Online] Available: http://ssrn.com/abstract=880061]. Dickey, D. A., & Fuller, W. A. (1981). Likelihood Ratio Statistics for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Econometrica, 49, 10571072. Fountas, S., Menelaos, K. & J. Kim (2002). Inflation and Output Growth Uncertainty and their Relationship with Inflation and Output Growth. Economics Letters, 75, 293-301. Fountas, S. & Menelaos, K. (2007). Inflation, Output Growth, and Nominal and Real Uncertainty: Empirical Evidence for the G7. Journal of International Money and Finance, 26, 229-250. Fuhrer, J. (1997). Inflation/Output Variance Trade-offs and Optimal Monetary Policy. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29(2), 214-34. Gaspar, V. & Smets, F. (2002). Monetary Policy, Price Stability and Output Gap Stabilization. International Finance, 5(2), 193-211. Grier, K. B., Henry, O. T., Olekalns, N. & Shields, K. (2004). The Asymmetric Effects of Uncertainty on Inflation and Output Growth. Journal of Applied econometrics, 19, 551565. Jarque, C. M. & Bera, A. K. (1980). Efficient tests for normality, homoscedasticity and serial independence of regression residuals. Economics Letters, 6, 255259. Lee, J. (2002). The Inflation-Output Variability Tradeoff and Monetary Policy: Evidence from a GARCH Model. Southern Economic Journal, 69(1), 175-188. Lee, J. (2004). The Inflation-Output Variability Tradeoff: OECD Evidence. Journal of Contemporary Economic Policy, 22(3), 344-356. Ljung, G. M. & Box, G. E. P. (1978). On a Measure of Lack of Fit in Time Series Models. Boimetrika, 66: 6672. Naka, A. & Tufte, D. (1997), Examining the Impulse Response Functions in Cointegrated Systems; Applied Economics, 29, 1593-1603. Nnanna, O. (2001). Monetary Policy Framework in Africa: the Nigerian Experience. Central Bank of Nigeria, Working Paper. Okonjo-Iweala, N. & Philip Osafo-Kwaako. (2006). Nigerias Economic Reforms: Progress and Challenges. Brookings Global Economy and Development, Working Paper, 6, 1-30. Pesaran, M. H. and Y. Shin (1998). Generalised impulse response analysis in linear multivariate models. Economic Letters, 58 , 17-29. 69

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Roberts, J. M. (2006). Monetary Policy and Inflation Dynamics. International Journal of Central Banking, September, 2006. Taylor, J. (1979). Estimation and control of Macroeconomic Model with Rational Expectations. Econometrica, 47(5), 1267-86. Taylor, J. (1994). The Inflation/Output Variability Trade-off Revisited, in Goals, Guidelines and Constraints Facing Monetary Policymakers. FRB of Boston, Conference Series 38, 21-38.

Notes

Note 1. Other studies failed to distinguish the two periods in their analyses and thus evaluate the effectiveness of the CBNs monetary policy even over the period when monetary policy in Nigeria had overbearing political interference. Note 2. Gaspar, Victor and Frank Smets (2002) Monetary Policy, Price Stability and Output Gap Stabilization. International Finance, 5:2, 193-211
Figures Impulse Response Functions

Plot of responses of inflation rate 1981-1994


0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00 -0.02 -0.04 -0.06 -0.08 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23
Real GDP Growth Rate 1981-1994 MRR 1981-1994 inflation rate 1981-1994

Figure 1. Plot of responses of inflation rate 1981-1994

70

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Plot of responses of MRR 1981-1994


10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23
Real GDP Growth Rate 1981-1994 MRR 1981-1994 inflation rate 1981-1994

Figure 2. Plot of responses of MRR 1981-1994


Plot of responses of Real GDP Growth Rate 1981-1994
2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23
Real GDP Growth Rate 1981-1994 MRR 1981-1994 inflation rate 1981-1994

Figure 3. Plot of responses of Real GDP Growth Rate 1981-1994

Plot of responses of inflation rate 1995-2007


0.050 0.025 -0.000 -0.025 -0.050 -0.075 -0.100 -0.125 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23
Real GDP Growth Rate 1995-2007 MRR 1995-2007 inflation rate 1995-2007

71

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Figure 4. Plot of responses of inflation rate 1995-2007

P lo t o f r e s p o n s e s o f M R R 1 9 9 5 - 2 0 0 7
14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23
R e a l G D P G r o w th R a te 1 9 9 5 - 2 0 0 7 M R R 1 9 9 5 -2 0 0 7 i n fl a ti o n r a te 1 9 9 5 - 2 0 0 7

Figure 5. Plot of responses of MRR 1995-2007

2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 0 5 10 Real GDP Growth Rate 1995-2007 MRR 1995-2007 15 20 inflation rate 1995-2007

Figure 6. Plot of responses of Real GDP Growth Rate 1995-2007 Tables Table 1. Summary Statistics of Study Variables

Series GDP

Sample 1981:1 2007:1 1981:1 1994:4 1995:1 2007:4

obs 108 56 52

mean 409541.01 283126.25 545679.97 72

Std Dev 220926.82 44004.84 252724.21

Minimum 205045 205045 348746.7

Maximum 1317391.3 347271.1 1317391.3

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011 CPI INFLAcbn Oilprices Mrr LOGRGDP GDPGRT 1981:1 2007:1 1981:1 1994:4 1995:1 2007:4 1981:1 2007:1 1981:1 1994:4 1995:1 2007:4 1981:1 2007:1 1981:1 1994:4 1995:1 2007:4 1981:1 2007:1 1981:1 1994:4 1995:1 2007:4 1981:1 2007:1 1981:1 1994:4 1995:1 2007:4 1981:1 2007:1 1981:1 1994:4 1995:1 2007:4 108 56 52 108 56 52 108 56 52 108 56 52 108 56 52 107 55 52 2459.17 291.44 4793.65 23.66 27.77 19.23 28.07 23.56 32.94 14.07 13.28 14.93 10.7 11.94 9.35 0.54 0.31 0.77

www.iiste.org

2697.68 320.28 2107.46 19.91 19.89 19.14 15.23 6.94 19.71 4.41 5.24 3.12 1.43 0.81 0.20 1.1 1.02 1.1

47.9 47.9 1669.9 1.3 3.0 1.3 11.4 13.6 11.4 6 6 8 9.0 10.1 9.0 -1.1 -1.1 -0.6

8722.6 1458.4 8722.6 77.9 66.7 77.9 90.7 38 90.7 26 26 20 14.1 13.1 10.0 6.8 6.8 4.6

Table 2. Tests for Serial Correlation, ARCH and Normality

Tests for Serial Correlation, ARCH and Normality Series Q(8) Q(16) Q(24) GDPGRWT 21.778[0.0006 54.765[0.000 82.40[0.000 ] ] ] INFLACBN 65.281[0.0000 76.992[0.000 82.846[0.00 ] ] ]
Table 3. Unit Root Tests of Variables of the Model

ARCH(1) 16.636[0.000 ] 11.787[0.006]

ARCH(2) 5.846[0.00537 ] 40.51[0.0000]

JB-STAT 2.228[0.3283] 21.037[0.07]

Variable Logrgdp Inflacbn Oilprices Logoilprices MRR GDPGRT

Level -3.139162* -2.450268** 1.576064 -0.001255 -2.890303 -2.385600

First Difference -3.755954** -3.935362** -4.293117** -4.789354** -5.668382** -7.695887**

Lags 1 1 1 1 1 3

Table 4. Bivariate GARCH Estimations of Output Growth and Inflation

BIVARIATE GARCH ESTIMATIONS OF OUTPUT GROWTH AND INFLATION CONDTIONAL MEAN EQUATIONS 1981:1 2007:4 1981:1 1994:4 1995:1 2007:4 Variables Mod1 Mod11 Mod21 CONSTANT -7.51810** -5.546* -3.43389 Trend 0.07571** -0.011 0.021079 GRGDP{1} 0.05173 0.073 -0.1475 INFLA_VOL -0.09100** -0.0897* -0.1000** OILP_SHOCK 3.98553** 6.7809 6.3037** CONSTANT 7.65128** 10.3289** -0.1001 Trend -0.07907** -0.10556 0.009257 73

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011 INFLACBN{1} 0.70064** INFLA_VOL 0.2668** OILP_SHOCK 0.05470 CONDITIONAL VARIANCE EQUATIONS C(1,1) 2.55319** C(1,2) -0.51521 C(2,2) 1.9726** A(1,1) 0.9095** A(1,2) -0.41810** A(2,2) 0.73918** B(1,1) 0.63512** B(1,2) -0.1518 B(2,1) 0.3460** B(2,2) -0.6345** Convergence 72 Iters
Table 5. Variance Decompositions

www.iiste.org

0.7497** 0.28209 -18.9548** 4.4927** -4.57815** 0.7345 0.1876 -1.0158** 0.15856 0.7660** -0.10767 0.5393** 0.05555 54 Iters

0.70817** -0.10738 0.10766 3.7733** -0.4757 0.000055 0.87385** -0.37536** 0.74536** 0.24098 0.2372** -0.23189 -0.23189 55 Iters

Decomposition of Variance for Series MRR 1981-1994 Step Std Error MRR INFLACBN LOGRGDP 1 2.2635274 100.000 0.000 0.000 2 3.0798643 99.840 0.113 0.047 3 3.5912226 99.454 0.503 0.043 4 3.9572332 98.817 1.146 0.037 5 4.2363533 98.038 1.915 0.047 6 4.4549927 97.254 2.674 0.073 7 4.6272535 96.569 3.328 0.104 8 4.7622814 96.030 3.838 0.132 9 4.8671344 95.642 4.205 0.153 10 4.9477657 95.383 4.451 0.166 11 5.0092686 95.221 4.606 0.172 12 5.0559098 95.127 4.698 0.175 13 5.0911552 95.076 4.749 0.174 14 5.1177424 95.052 4.775 0.173 15 5.1377856 95.042 4.787 0.172 16 5.1528939 95.040 4.790 0.171 17 5.1642808 95.041 4.789 0.171 18 5.1728585 95.043 4.786 0.171 19 5.1793125 95.046 4.782 0.173 20 5.1841599 95.048 4.777 0.175 21 5.1877921 95.049 4.773 0.177 22 5.1905074 95.050 4.769 0.181 23 5.1925336 95.049 4.766 0.184 24 5.1940455 95.048 4.763 0.189 Decomposition of Variance for Series INFLACBN 1981-1994 Step Std Error MRR INFLACBN LOGRGDP 1 6.1520145 0.071 99.929 0.000 2 11.1840983 1.802 95.291 2.907 3 15.0407379 3.934 91.002 5.063 4 17.5910999 5.983 87.708 6.308 5 19.0795657 7.843 85.209 6.949 74

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

www.iiste.org

19.8504330 9.436 83.355 7.209 20.2077581 10.698 82.044 7.258 20.3628070 11.607 81.174 7.220 20.4350821 12.201 80.627 7.172 20.4786903 12.556 80.296 7.149 20.5120032 12.752 80.092 7.155 20.5388952 12.857 79.962 7.182 20.5596652 12.911 79.872 7.217 20.5748203 12.941 79.807 7.252 20.5855134 12.958 79.758 7.285 20.5930675 12.967 79.719 7.313 20.5985954 12.972 79.689 7.338 20.6028938 12.975 79.665 7.360 20.6064990 12.975 79.645 7.380 20.6097764 12.973 79.627 7.400 20.6129850 12.970 79.611 7.420 20.6163087 12.966 79.595 7.439 20.6198692 12.961 79.580 7.459 20.6237341 12.957 79.564 7.480 Decomposition of Variance for Series LOGRGDP 1981-1994 Step Std Error MRR INFLACBN LOGRGDP 1 0.0606513 2.224 35.541 62.235 2 0.1051127 4.838 41.180 53.982 3 0.1455233 6.553 43.994 49.453 4 0.1817223 7.954 45.165 46.882 5 0.2136589 9.201 45.422 45.376 6 0.2416622 10.339 45.191 44.470 7 0.2662894 11.377 44.717 43.906 8 0.2881627 12.320 44.145 43.535 9 0.3078669 13.172 43.556 43.272 10 0.3258997 13.937 42.997 43.066 11 0.3426582 14.624 42.488 42.888 12 0.3584433 15.240 42.039 42.722 13 0.3734729 15.793 41.647 42.559 14 0.3878983 16.293 41.310 42.398 15 0.4018202 16.745 41.019 42.236 16 0.4153033 17.157 40.767 42.076 17 0.4283879 17.534 40.548 41.918 18 0.4410995 17.880 40.355 41.765 19 0.4534554 18.201 40.183 41.616 20 0.4654687 18.498 40.028 41.474 21 0.4771516 18.774 39.887 41.338 22 0.4885159 19.032 39.758 41.210 23 0.4995741 19.273 39.639 41.088 24 0.5103391 19.499 39.529 40.973 Decomposition of Variance for Series MRR 1995-2007 Step Std Error MRR INFLACBN LOGRGDP 1 1.1350644 100.000 0.000 0.000 2 1.6579561 98.990 0.634 0.376 3 1.9518658 98.041 1.594 0.365 4 2.1059278 97.576 2.035 0.389 75

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

www.iiste.org

2.1890956 97.572 1.940 0.488 2.2471307 97.176 2.068 0.757 2.3094247 95.447 3.279 1.275 2.3891806 92.145 5.816 2.039 2.4856879 87.850 9.202 2.949 2.5901409 83.418 12.706 3.876 2.6920664 79.478 15.792 4.730 2.7834456 76.298 18.235 5.467 2.8600548 73.886 20.033 6.081 2.9210218 72.125 21.291 6.584 2.9676945 70.865 22.140 6.995 3.0025083 69.967 22.701 7.332 3.0281459 69.320 23.069 7.611 3.0470430 68.841 23.314 7.845 3.0611754 68.473 23.482 8.045 3.0720291 68.178 23.603 8.219 3.0806628 67.931 23.695 8.374 3.0878022 67.716 23.771 8.514 3.0939296 67.522 23.836 8.642 3.0993574 67.344 23.894 8.762 Decomposition of Variance for Series INFLACBN 1995-2007 Step Std Error MRR INFLACBN LOGRGDP 1 2.6954031 5.347 94.653 0.000 2 5.4978721 7.572 89.068 3.360 3 8.1216124 11.195 84.123 4.682 4 10.2911556 14.430 80.076 5.494 5 11.9097715 17.231 76.848 5.921 6 13.0111184 19.547 74.326 6.127 7 13.6946354 21.374 72.430 6.196 8 14.0795505 22.727 71.083 6.191 9 14.2745317 23.651 70.196 6.153 10 14.3626479 24.223 69.665 6.113 11 14.3984216 24.535 69.380 6.085 12 14.4124976 24.679 69.246 6.075 13 14.4192880 24.730 69.190 6.080 14 14.4241316 24.737 69.168 6.095 15 14.4283203 24.729 69.157 6.114 16 14.4318686 24.718 69.149 6.133 17 14.4346655 24.708 69.140 6.152 18 14.4367583 24.701 69.131 6.167 19 14.4383088 24.696 69.123 6.181 20 14.4394976 24.692 69.116 6.193 21 14.4404705 24.689 69.109 6.203 22 14.4413283 24.686 69.102 6.212 23 14.4421380 24.683 69.097 6.221 24 14.4429453 24.680 69.091 6.229

76

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

New approaches to sustainable forest management: a study of service innovation in conserving forestry resources
Verma Rajeev (corresponding author) Fellow Participant in Management Indian Institute of Management, Indore, India Email: f09rajeev@iimidr.ac.in

Received: October 11st, 2011 Accepted: October 14th, 2011 Published: October 30th, 2011 The author would like to thank Prof. P C Kotwal, Indian Institute of Forest Management, Project Coordinator, IIFM ITTO Project and Forest MIS of Chhattisgarh Forest Department, to operationalize this study.

Abstract Sustainability has been a primary concern for the forestry professionals. This paper is concerned with the continuing evolution of approaches to monitor sustainable forest management. It summarises the existing knowledge base and primary techniques and strategies for achieving socially and environmentally acceptable SFM in various forest formations. Service innovation is one means for the improved monitoring of SFM through the introduction of scientifically based criteria and indicators. This set has been developed on the basis of Dry Forest Asia Initiative. In addition, their implementation has played a key role in interactions with local beneficiaries. Yet, research on the link between service innovation and natural resource management is scant. The paper identifies innovation orientation, external partner collaboration, and information capability as operant resources along with the operand resources captured under the 8 criteria and their respective field level indicators. These antecedents are analyzed to know impact of overall service innovation on social economic development of the area.

Keywords: sustainable forest management, service innovation, C&I, community participation

1. Introduction

77

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

The United Nations Conference on Environment and Development (UNCED) in 1992 led the general adoption of a concept of sustainable development based on the equilibrium between three prime components i.e., economic development; conservation of the environment and social justice. Forestry resources have been featured prominently at the conference and have remained high on the international agenda for sustainable development. In pursuance of the Forest Principles and of Agenda 21 (chapter 11) adopted at UNCED, the notion of sustainable forest management has been adopted in more specific and operational terms. Criteria and indicators were identified in order of planning, monitoring and assess the forest management practices at the national as well as for the individual forest management unit (FMU) level. The selection and use of suitable criteria and indicators are thus one of the keys to progress in the practice of sustainable forest management.

These criteria and indicators are mainly intended for defining objectives and priorities for Sustainable Forest Management (SFM) and for monitoring progress during their implementation. The objective of SFM is, to increase the adoption of forest management practices to sustain and enhance the yields of multiple products, services and values for multiple stakeholders, over the long term. However, the intermediate goal is to contribute, sustain and enhance the benefits from natural tropical forests like India, by increasing opportunities and benefits to various stakeholders. The end benefit of the project includes rural livelihood promotion; industrial timber production; and environmental services. In a way, improving the level of adoption of scientific findings in forest management, leads to adoptive management process and hence use of best practices. In India, all the forestry resources are under the direct control of the government. Hence, it provides a very less scope for the innovative management. However, the latest management practices such as, Sustainable Forest Management (SFM), Joint Forest Management (JFM) bring the inputs from various stake holders and a hope to bring the service innovation in the management of the forestry resources.

These service innovations in the management of natural resources have been an effective way for the forestry organizations to accelerate its growth rate and profitability as products or services become more or less homogeneous or an original competitive advantage cannot be sustained (Berry, Shankar, Janet, Susan and Dotzel, 2006). Accordingly, researchers and practitioners are interested in explaining and predicting key antecedents of and outcomes associated with service innovation in managing forestry resources. Much of the research on service innovation in the last few decades has addressed many considerations, including decisions of service innovation adoption (Frambach, Barkema, Bart and Wedel, 1998; Kleijnen, Ruyter, and Andreassen 2005), typologies (Avlonitis, Papastathopoulou, and Gounaris 2001) of service innovation, service innovation strategy and process (Blazevic and Lievens 2004), and drivers of service innovation (Berry et al. 2006) mainly in the corporate scenario of the western countries. However, the present work focuses on the importance of innovation practices in conserving forestry resources and highlights the need of future research in this area. By shedding light on the short and long-term benefits and different goods/ services for different stakeholders, this forest management practice contributes both to the environment as

78

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
well as to its various stakeholders.

www.iiste.org

As suggested by Berry et al. (2006), service innovation aims to create new markets and hence possibilities of extending the organizational service reach. Research seeks to contribute to sustainable forest management by increasing the understanding of the costs and benefits for different stakeholders of sustaining or replacing, managing well or degrading natural forests, by enhancing the incentives for improved forest management through contributions for institutional development and policy decisions; and by evaluating harvesting and management recommendations to sustain commodities and environmental values from natural tropical forests.

However, this topic has recently attracted increasing interest from academics and practitioners (e.g., Blind 2006; Dean 2004; Pavlovski 2007; Verganti and Buganza 2005; Zomerdijk and de Vries 2007), there is little evidence of significant innovation in managing forestry resources. We argue that there is no full and adequate understanding of the concept of service innovation and its role in managing forestry resources. Recently, the field of marketing has evolved toward a service-dominant (S-D) logic (Vargo and Lusch 2008) through which we can re-examine the role of innovation in service delivery. Compared to traditional goods-dominant (G-D) logic, service in S-D logic is the application of specialized competences (knowledge and skills, i.e., operant resources) to provide through goods (operand resources) that benefit an entity.

In the present article, we argue that service innovation is the process of applying specialized competences, consistent with S-D logic. Innovation in this context is the process of applying new ideas or current thinking in fundamentally different ways, resulting in significant changes. According to S-D logic, innovations had significantly changed the user preferences and their perception about the service quality (Madhavaram and Hunt, 2008). Therefore, by implementing innovative practices in service delivery, organizations could change their method of creating stakeholders value and hence positively impact their perceptions. Accordingly, we argue that service delivery innovation in the SFM context, involves an entire organization viewing and addressing both value creation and environmental services within an S-D logic framework.

The purpose of this article is to contribute to the literature on Sustainable Forest Management through service delivery innovation by developing and empirically testing a model that attempts to explain what motivates service delivery innovation and, in turn, influences performance in terms of optimum utilization of forestry resources. Here the performance has been measured on the basis of Bhopal-India initiative for SFM, which in itself is an outcome of Dry Forest Asia Initiative. We had three research objectives: (a) to understand the role of service innovation in SFM (b) to investigate the antecedents of service delivery innovation based on the Local Unit Criteria and Indicator Development (LUCID) for SFM, and (c) to examine whether proposed service innovation can result in better social economic development in terms of

79

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
rural livelihood promotion.

www.iiste.org

This article makes three contributions to the literature. First, we try to identify the nature of service delivery innovation in the management of natural resources. By studying innovation within the framework of S-D logic, we view service delivery innovation as ability of a firm to create stakeholder value (Lievens and Moenaert, 2000). Second, based on resource advantage (R-A) theory (Lusch, Vargo and Brien, 2007), we test the links among organizational innovation orientation, service delivery innovation, and performance through an empirical survey with samples from 126 JFMCs. Third, the results provide practical steps for managers to understand service innovation that can result in better social economic development in terms of rural livelihood promotion. The article is structured as follows. First, we review Sustainable Forest Management in terms of S-D logic framework to identify the key operant resources that facilitate service delivery innovation. Then, after describing the research framework (Figure 1), we report the results of a study conducted in the Forest Management Committees aimed at empirically testing the research model (Figure 2). At last, we conclude with a discussion of theoretical and managerial implications and directions for future research.

2. Theoretical Background and Conceptual Framework

Looking into the service innovation literature, most of the prior innovation literature has treated service innovation as product innovation. However, extensive literature review includes the interaction (i.e., coproduction with end users) between new service development and service delivery (Zaltman, Duncan and Holbek, 1973). Although strategic innovation theory (Markides, 1997) addresses a new way of delivering new products or services to existing or new customer segments and most adequately explains service innovation, it focuses mainly on goods (i.e., operand resources) but not on operant resources.

As we know, R-A theory is compatible with the S-D logics emphasis on competences, value propositions, and operant resources. In this study, we view service delivery innovation from the R-A theory to better understand the relationships among strategic and organizational issues. R-A theory is a process theory of competition, which asserts that firms achieve superior financial performance by occupying marketplace positions of competitive advantage. Here in terms of forest management, the competency may be achieved in terms of optimum utilization of forestry resources, socio-cultural benefits and better ecosystem function and vitality.

Hence it relies on those resources that provide the firm a comparative advantage over its competitors. These comparative resources, in the S-D logic perspective, are mainly operant resources. Figure 1 presents our research framework.

80

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Figure 1: The Research Framework

Operant resources that can be leveraged to develop innovation practices, a source of sustained competitive advantage, produce superior performance in terms of improved sustainability indicators. Further, we are also suggesting a direct effect between innovation practices on sustainability of forestry resources. In our discussion, we refer to the concept of applying R-A theory to support service delivery innovation research. To determine which operant resources facilitate service delivery innovation, however, one needs a model describing the resources/capabilities of a firm and how these enable service delivery innovation. The model has been based on the study Verganti and Buganza (2005) that describes service delivery as being facilitated by organization (internal and external) and technology. We therefore propose a research model and suggest that innovation practices in service delivery are mainly influenced by organizational, relational, and informational resources (Hunt 2000). In R-A theory, organizational (e.g., cultures), relational (e.g., relationships with partners), and informational (e.g., technology) assets are operant resources.

We further identify organizational resources as innovation orientation, relational resources as external partner collaboration, and informational resources as IT capabilities. The emphasis in the literature is the discussion of organization, relationships, and technology and their influence on service delivery innovation and monitoring of sustainable management of forestry resources. It shows the relationships that we hypothesized exist among innovation orientation, external partner collaboration, IT capability, service delivery innovation, and performance of sustainability indicators.

81

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Figure 2: The Research Model 3. Operationalization of Constructs

Innovation orientation of a Stakeholder: refers to an organizational openness to new ideas and propensity to change through adopting new technologies, resources, skills, and administrative systems (Zhou, Gao, Yang, 2005). Innovation orientation consists of both openness to innovation (Zaltman, Duncan, and Holbek 1973) and capacity to innovate (Bolton, 2003). Here it has been measured on the basis of individual efforts for conserving the forestry resources.

External partner collaboration: Its an important parameter for conserving ecosystem biodiversity as high degree of networking efforts took place while conserving the forestry resources. It has been measured using modified scales of Kalaignanam, Shankar and Varadarajan (2007). Apart from institutional efforts (forest committee), the organizational participation in exchanging resources and capabilities with external partners such as universities, research institutions, customers, and suppliers have also been studied.

IT capability: It includes the availability of IT infrastructure, human IT resources, and IT-enabled intangibles. It also includes the availability of GPS, palmtops at the beat level. It has been measured the scale by Bharadwaj (2000). It also includes the computerization of land records and computer awareness at the grass-root level.

Service Delivery Innovation: It refers to the actual delivery of a service (Zeithaml, Berry, and Parasuraman 1988) and the delivery of services and products to the stakeholders (Lovelock and Gummesson, 2004). In forest management terms, it is a process of applying specialized competences

82

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

(knowledge and skills) to maintain and enhance the ecosystem function and vitality. It has been measured by using 10 items adapted and modified from research on the S-D logic perspective by Vargo and Lusch (2004).

Measuring the forest sustainability: Standards for sustainable forest management typically consist of a number of principles which are the components of the overall goal and objective, and of criteria and indicators which are meant to enable an assessment as whether or not the objective and its components are being accomplished. In the present study, criteria have been formulated to describe a desired state or dynamics of the biological or social system and allow a verdict on the degree of achievement of an objective in a given situation. A scale consists of 8 criteria and 44 indicators have been used to monitor the forest sustainability at the National Level.

4. Hypothesis Development

In a study conducted by Zhou et al, (2005) the innovation orientation has been determined as one of the factors for service innovation. It has been noted as a key driver for overcoming hurdles and enhancing organizational ability to successfully adopt or implement new systems, processes, or products. In case of conserving forestry resources, it comes in the form of individual efforts to maintain the forest resource productivity. Therefore, innovation orientation represents the extent to which (a) an organization is open to new ideas (i.e., culture) through the adoption of new technologies and integrated resources and (b) encouragement of forest management committee members to consider the adoption of innovation. Hence, we propose that the organizational ability to adapt to changing or existing service depends upon innovation orientation of its individual members. We formulate the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1: Innovation orientation of individual JFMC members has a positive impact on service innovation in forest conservation scenario at 95 percent confidence level.

The Inter-organizational collaboration is important in supplementing the internal innovative activities of organizations (Deeds and Rothaermel 2003). Therefore, firms need to collaborate to build greater innovation practices and lock-in partners for the long term. Due to this firms may improve their ability to engage in process innovation by managing their relationships with suppliers and customers (Kaufman, Wood, and Theyel 2000). Therefore, we propose that innovative service delivery that a firm creates is based on support from external partners collaboration (e.g., stakeholders, research institutions, and universities). Hence, we propose that firms having stronger collaborations with external partners will be better at developing new methods (approaches) of service innovation for conservation of natural resources. Therefore, we hypothesize the following:

83

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Hypothesis 2: External partner collaboration has a positive impact on service innovation in forest conservation scenario at 95 percent confidence level.

Based on the study on operant resources that bundle basic resources (Hunt 2000), we propose that IT capability is a hierarchy of composite operant resources (COR) that includes IT infrastructure, human IT resources, and IT-enabled intangibles. Technology may influence organizational ability to create value that will transform the way customers interact with an offering. To create a new channel or method of service delivery, organization needs to possess this infrastructure. In terms of managing the sustainable resources, it comes in the form of latest GPS supported infrastructure; Satellite based forest fire fighting equipments etc. Thus, IT capability is the operant resource for a new service that offers an opportunity to provide new and innovative services. We hypothesize the following:

Hypothesis 3: IT capability has a positive impact on service innovation in forest conservation scenario at 95 percent confidence level.

Prior research has studied business performance from different perspectives, such as financial performance, business unit performance, or organizational performance (Wiertz, Ruyter, Keen and Streukens, 1986). Based on R-A theory, once competitors achieve superior performance through obtaining marketplace positions of competitive advantage, firms attempt to leverage the advantages through major innovation practices. We therefore propose that if organization is able to innovate in more varied ways to deliver service, they will achieve superior performance objectives. The criteria and indicators; are used to describe a systematic approach to measuring, monitoring and reporting SFM. C&I indicate the direction of change as regards the forests and also suggest the ways to expedite the process of SFM. Hence, we postulate the following:

Hypothesis 4: Service innovation in forest management has a positive impact on sustainability of forestry resources. 5. Research Methodology

84

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

The Study Site: To achieve the purposes of the study, the field data has been collected through 126 JFMC members under localized community biodiversity programme (L-CBP) at Marwahi (North Bilaspur) Forest Division in the state of Chhattisgarh, India. It is one of the project site where C&I approach for SFM is being implemented with the help of International Tropical Timber Organization (ITTO), Japan. The division is rich in species diversity and the dependency of local community on the forest resources is relatively higher. The forest division is located between 81 0 48 to 820 24 E longitude and 220 8 to 230 7 N Latitude. As per the Champion & Seths (1968) classification of Forests Types of India, forest of the division has been classified under the 5B / C1c Dry Peninsular Sal Forest. The criteria and indicator approach has been used to develop a sitespecific set of criteria and indicators for Marwahi Forest Division, North Bilaspur. This set has been developed on the basis of Bhopal-India initiative for SFM, which in itself is an outcome of Dry Forest Asia Initiative.

Design/methodology/approach: The research plan is deductive in nature as the theory building process precedes the data collection process. The data collection has been done using a 24 item scale (Forest Sustainability Index) refined from previous studies. To measure the scale internal reliability consistencies, alpha value has been found out between 0.76 and 0.87, exceeding the 0.70 benchmark suggested by Nunnally (1978). A set of hypotheses has been developed pertaining to potential predictors of two distinct facets (Operant and Operand resources) of service innovation and the impact of the latter on the measures of forestry indicator performance in terms of, increase in bio-diversity, soil and water conservation, forest production of NTFPs and socio-economic development of the village. Path analysis using SEM technique has been used for the data analysis.

Measure: All constructs in the study has been measured using multiple items. A five-point likert scale has been used to capture the variables and indicator items. The scale has been adopted from previous studies and checked for scale reliabilities (coefficient ). It consists of total 30 (6+24) items to operationalize 5 construct level variables. The 6 item scale has been used to measure service innovation (SI) and 24 item FMU level Criteria and Indicator scale has been used to measure the construct of Innovation Orientation, External Partner Collaboration, Information Technology Capability and Forest Sustainability Index. However, the final questionnaire for IO, EPC and IT has been adopted from various authors apart from ITTO scale.

S. No

Measure

Construct variables

and

indicator

Scale Reliability () 0.76 0.79

Questionnaire adopted from

1 2

IO EPC

Innovation Orientation External Partner

Burns and Stalker (1977) Faems, Looy, and Debackere

85

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
Collaboration 3 4 5 IT SI SFM Information Capability Technology 0.81 0.76 0.87

www.iiste.org

(2005) Bharadwaj (2000) Vargo and Lusch (2004) Kotwal P.C. et.al (2006)

Service Innovation Forest Sustainability Index

Table 1: Construct indicator variables and scale reliability values

The Descriptive statistics for the selected variables are, Variables Sample Size Mean Standard Deviation Skewness IO 126 3.563 1.467 -0.913 EPC 126 4.453 0.564 -0.343 IT 126 2.113 0.478 -0.221 SI 126 3.652 1.510 -0.212 SFM 126 4.120 0.893 -1.513

Table 2: The Descriptive statistics for the studied variables

The correlation table among the variable and cronbachs alpha along the diagonal is as, 1 1 2 3 4 5 Innovation Orientation External Collaboration Information capability Partner Technology (0.76) 0.231** 0.198** 0.495** 0.219** (0.79) 0.301** 0.201** 0.136** (0.81) 0.256** 0.436** (0.76) 0.524** (0.87) 2 3 4 5

Service Innovation Forest Sustainability Index

86

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2 tailed), * correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2 tailed), Note: alpha values in the parenthesis along with the diagonal

Table 3: The correlation table among the variable and cronbachs alpha along the diagonal

6. Data Analysis and Results

Figure 3: The path coefficient values in the studied model

We used structural equation modelling technique for the data analysis. AMOS 18.0 has been used for the path analysis. A review of the literature indicated that empirical testing of service innovation in forestry performance is quite less, it worked as a pioneer study in this domain. Based on the 4 proposed hypotheses,

87

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

the effect of mediator variables has been studied. Result shows the significant relationship of innovation orientation and external partner collaboration with service innovation. Both together explained 15.6% of the total variance. Collaborative competence has found to have a positive and significant effect (r=0.403, p< 0.001).

The main effect model has been explained using the structural equation modelling. The structural model with relevant path coefficients has been mentioned in the Figure 3. SEM takes a confirmatory approach to test the dependence relationships and account for measurement errors in the process of testing the model. The assessment of model fit has been done using the various fit indices. The testing of moderator effect has been done using a interaction variable. The results of the SEM for main effects are shown in the table, 2/df 3.115 AGFI 0.751 PGFI 0.812 NFI 0.962 TLI 0.855 CFI 0.862 PNFI 0.813 RMSEA 0.721 RMR 0.026

Table 4: SEM model fit summary The chi-square/ df ratio of 2 to 3 is taken as good or acceptable fit (Bollen, 1989; Gallagher, Ting and Palmer, 2008). The various incremental fit indices include the Normal Fit Index (NFI), comparative Fit Index (CFI) or the Tucker-Lewis Index (TLI), with suggestions for a cut of 0.90 for a good fitting model (Hu and Bentler, 1999). Further the absolute fit index of Adjusted Goodness of Fit Index (AGFI) is greater than the minimal 0.75 cutoff (Gallagher, Ting and Palmer, 2008). The multiple R square for the model is 0.612.

The first hypotheses (H1) focus on the interrelationships innovation orientation and extent of service innovation among the stakeholders. Similarly second and third hypothesis (H2 and H3) focused on the external partner collaboration and IT support with extent of service innovation respectively. In the present model the direct effect and indirect effect (mediated by burnout) has been summarized as, Hypothesized Relationship Service Innovation Service Innovation Service Innovation Forest Indices Sustainability Innovation orientation External Partner Collaboration Information support Service Innovation Technology Estimate 0.371 0.291 0.072 0.471 P-value 0.002 0.000 0.004 0.050

Table 5: Path coefficients from the SEM analysis

88

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

It can be seen from the SEM results that all the direct and indirect relationship has been found significant (p<0.05). The direct estimate of Job demand and Job resource on performance and turnover intentions have been found significantly higher than the indirect effect (mediated by burnout). It signifies that the burnout partially mediates the overall effect (lowering the estimate value with a significant relationship).

7. Discussion and Conclusion

With the rapid pace of structural change in the forest management practices, service innovation and its relationship with forest sustainability performance have increasingly attracted the attention of both researchers and practitioners. In this study, we investigated the role of service delivery innovation as a mediator in a causal framework concerning the link with service innovation antecedents and the impact of innovation on SFM practices. The Assessment of model fit in SEM using the model fit indices (2 = 15.04, p = .087, RMSEA= .072, NFI = .96, NNFI = .95, CFI = .86, SRMR= .026) explains 62% of the total variance.

The primary findings suggest that (a) innovation orientation and external partner collaboration are the key drivers that lead to service delivery innovation, (b) service delivery innovation leads to improved management of forestry resources and in turn sustainability of forestry resources. Further, result shows that incorporating service innovation in sustainable forest management techniques significantly contribute to the rural livelihood generation and hence socio-economic development of the area.

8. Implications for Research

Our results have three significant implications for research. First, our study highlights the S-D logic perspective to link service delivery innovation, with the overall performance of the sustainable forest management programme. The study has been found pioneer in this direction as no previous other study has been made in this direction till date. Further, the study has investigated the role of operant resources in the service innovation on overall performance of the programme.

This study provides encouraging evidence for the service innovation modes that integrate service providers

89

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

competences, services, service channels and stakeholders. Delivery innovation reshapes the users behaviour and helps organizations innovate service value with end users (co-creation value with the end users). Further, this study develops robust insights into the effects of innovation orientation and IT capability on system performance. More importantly, we propose that this research model is a more suitable framework of service innovation than others in the literature because it includes not only intra organizational components (i.e., innovation orientation and IT capability) but also inter organizational ones (i.e., external partner collaboration).

9. Implications for Practice

This study is having has various significant implications for practice. If an organization can create an advantage in operant resources, it not only can gain competitive advantage in the marketplace but also sustain its resources for the longer term. In the preview of sustainable forest management practice, forest managers as well as forest conservation group members need to foster creativity in conservation practices, train employees to accept or adopt any radical new ideas for putting up into the indicator list and develop an innovation environment or culture of openness within the organization. With regard to IT capability, IT plays a critical role in the implementation of service innovation practices, especially in corporate firms. However in the current study, with regard to the sustainable forest management practices, it includes use of GPS in forest monitoring and satellite based equipments in forest fire fighting.

As for external partner collaboration, inter organizational collaboration is important for supplementing the internal innovative activities of organizations (Deeds and Rothaermel 2003; Kalaignanam, Shankar, and Varadarajan 2007). This means that forest development authorities need to collaborate with agencies like, soil and water conservation, horticulture and other biodiversity conservation authorities that offer different operant resources to facilitate service innovation in forest conservation. Second, considering the different types of service innovation already popular with the forest department, we recommend that organization evaluate the risks/benefits of offering new service for both existing and new stakeholders. Third, these service innovations in forestry sector will play a critical role in facilitating superior forest management practices. Once successfully implemented in one forest management unit, the same can be replicated to different other units and hence larger forest area may come in the preview of SFM practice of criteria and indicator approach.

10. Limitations and Future Research

Even though this study offers valuable insights into service innovation in forest management practices, it still has some limitations. First, the study was conducted with only 126 JFMCs of Marwahi Forest Division, so the generalization of the results may not be applicable to other forest areas especially

90

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

belonging to other forest types. Second, the research model is based on the cross sectional data and is thus essentially a static perspective. It may be worthwhile to study the relationship between service innovation and sustainability of forestry resources over time to explain the effects of innovation on performance indicators and also taking the time lag effect in picture. This consideration is especially important because of the central role of innovation in this study. The effects of service innovation on forestry indicator performance may not be immediately apparent. Third, the three operant resources may not be sufficient to cover the entire scope of the study. Here we did not address the properties of the partner collaboration (e.g., governance structure, power, trust, etc.).

Further, as this empirical study included only self-reported data, future research should capture the points of view of external partners. The in depth case studies might add to our knowledge in the same subject especially in the preview of national and localised indicators of forest sustainability measurement.

91

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Appendix 1: Refined set of Criteria and Indicators at FMU Level (2006) based on Bhopal- India Process Criteria Criterion 1: Increase in the extent of forest and tree cover Criterion 2: Maintenance, conservation and enhancement of biodiversity 2.3 Criterion 3: Maintenance and enhancement of ecosystem function and vitality Criterion 4: Conservation and maintenance of soil and water resources Criteria 5: Maintenance and Enhancement of Forest Resource Productivity Criteria 6: Optimization of forest resource utilization Criteria 7: Maintenance and enhancement of social, benefits 7.2 cultural and spiritual 3.1 3.2 3.3 4.1 4.2 4.3 5.1 5.2 5.3 1.1 1.2 1.3 2.1 2.2 Indicators Forest area under encroachment Area of dense, open and scrub forests Tree cover outside forest area Area of protected eco-systems (Protected Areas) Status of locally significant species (a) Animal and (b) Plant species Status of non-destructive harvest of wood and Non-Wood Forest Produce Status of natural regeneration Incidences of forest fires Incidences of pest and diseases Area under watershed treatment Area prone to soil erosion Soil fertility/Site Quality Growing stock of wood Increment in volume of identified species of wood Efforts towards enhancement of forest productivity: Technological inputs 6.1 6.2 6.3 7.1 Recorded collection of Non-Wood Forest Produce Direct employment in forestry and forest based industries Contribution of forests to the income of forest dependent people (a) Number of JFM committees and area(s) protected by them (b) Degree of peoples participation in management and benefit-sharing (c) Level of participation of women Use of indigenous technical knowledge: Identification, Documentation and Application

92

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
7.3

www.iiste.org

Extent of cultural/sacred protected landscapes: forests, trees, ponds, streams, etc. (a) Type and area of landscape (b) Number of visitors

Criteria 8: Adequacy of Policy, Legal and Institutional framework

8.1 8.2 8.3

Existence of policy and legal framework Number of forest related offences Forest Resource Accounting (a) Contribution of forestry sector to the GDP (b) Budgetary allocations to the forestry sector

References Avlonitis, George J., Paulina G. Papastathopoulou, and Spiros P. Gounaris (2001), An Empirically-Based Typology of Product Innovativeness for New Financial Services: Success and Failure Scenarios, Journal of Product Innovation Management, 18 (5), 324-342. Berry, Leonard L., Shankar V., Janet T. Parish, Susan Cadwallader, and Thomas Dotzel (2006) Creating New Markets through Service Innovation, Sloan Management Review, 47 (2), 56-63. Bharadwaj, Anandhi S. (2000), A Resource-Based Perspective on Information Technology Capability and Firm Performance: An Empirical Investigation, MIS Quarterly, 24 (1), 169-196. Blazevic, Vera and Annouk Lievens (2004), Learning during the New Financial Service Innovation Process: Antecedents and Performance Effects, Journal of Business Research, 57 (4), 374-391. Blind, Knut (2006), A Taxonomy of Standards in the Service Sector: Theoretical Discussion and Empirical Test, Service Industries Journal, 26 (4), 397-420. Bollen, K.A. (1989), Structural Equations with Latent Variables, Wiley, New York, NY. Bolton, Ruth N. (2003), Marketing Challenges of e-Services, Communication of the ACM, 46 (6), 43-44. Burns, Tom and George M. Stalker (1977), The Management of Innovation, 2nd ed. London: Tavistock. Dean, Alison M. (2004), Links between Organizational and Customer Variables in Service Delivery: Evidence, Contradictions and Challenges, International Journal of Service Industry Management, 15 (4), 332-350 Deeds, David L. and Frank T. Rothaermel (2003), Honeymoons and Liabilities: The Relationship between Age and Performance in Research and Development Alliances, Journal of Product Innovation Management, 20 (6), 468-485. Frambach, Ruud T., Harry G. Barkema, Bart Nooteboom, and Michel Wedel (1998), Adoption of a Service Innovation in the Business Market: An Empirical Test of Supply-Side Variables, Journal of Business Research, 41, 161-174. Gallagher, D., Ting, L. and Palmer, A. (2008), A journey into the unknown; taking the fear out of structural equation modeling with AOMS for the first-time user, The Marketing Review, Vol, 8 No. 3, pp.

93

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
255-27.

www.iiste.org

Hunt, Shelby D. (2000), General Theory of Competition: Too Eclectic or Not Eclectic Enough? Too Incremental or Not Incremental Enough? Too Neoclassical or Not Neoclassical Enough? Journal of Macromarketing, 20 (1), 7781. Hu & Bentler (1999), Cut-off criteria for fit indexes in covariance structure analysis: Coventional criteria versus new alternatives, Structural Equation Modeling, 6(1), 1-55. Ja-Shen Chen, Hung Tai Tsou and Astrid Ya-Hui Huang (2009), Service Delivery Innovation: Antecedents and Impact on Firm Perfomance, Journal of Service Research, 12 (1), 36-55 Kalaignanam, Kartik, Venkatesh Shankar, and Rajan Varadarajan (2007), Asymmetric New Product Development Alliances: Win-Win or Win-Lose Partnerships? Management Science, 53 (3), 357-374. Kaufman, Allen, Craig H. Wood, and Gregory Theyel (2000), Collaboration and Technology Linkages: A Strategic Supplier Typology, Strategic Management Journal, 21 (6), 649-664. Kleijnen, Mirella, Ko de Ruyter, and Tor W. Andreassen (2005), Image Congruence and the Adoption of Service Innovations,Journal of Service Research, 7 (4), 343-359. Kotwal P.C., Verm Rajeev, Gairola Sanjay, Kumar A., Dugaya D, Rawat T.S. (2006), Bhopal India Process: Operational Strategy and Reporting Formats on IIFM, Bhopal. Lievens, Annouk and Rudy K. Moenaert (2000), New Service Team as Information Processing Systems, Journal of Service Research, 3 (1), 46-65. Lovelock, Christopher and Evert Gummesson (2004), Whither Services Marketing? In Search of a New Paradigm and Fresh Perspectives, Journal of Service Research, 7 (1), 920. Lusch, Robert F., Stephen L. Vargo, and Matthew OBrien (2007), Competing through Service: Insights from Service-Dominant Logic, Journal of Retailing, 83 (1), 5-18. Madhavaram, Sreedhar and Shelby D. Hunt (2008), The Service- Dominant Logic and a Hierarchy of Operant Resources: Developing Masterful Operant Resources and Implications for Marketing Strategy, Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 36 (1), 67-82. Markides, Constantinos (1997), Strategic Innovation, Sloan Management Review, 38 (3), 9-23. Nunnally, Jum C. (1978), Psychometric Theory, 2nd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill. Pavlovski, Christopher J. (2007), Service Delivery Platforms in Practice, IEEE Communications Magazine, 45 (3), 114-121. United Nations (1993), Agenda 21: Earth Summit - The United Nations Programme of Action from Rio, UN, NY. Vargo, Stephen L. and Robert F. Lusch (2008), Why Service? Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 36 (1), 25-38. Criteria and

Indicators for Sustainable Forest Management in India: Training Manual, ISBN: 8179690385,

94

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Verganti, Roberto and Tommaso Buganza (2005), Design Inertia: Designing for Life-Cycle Flexibility in Internet- Based Services, Journal of Product Innovation Management, 22 (3), 223-237. Wiertz, Caroline, Ko de Ruyter, Cherie Keen, and Sandra Streukens (2004), Cooperating for Service Excellence in Multichannel Service Systems: An Empirical Assessment, Journal of Business Research, 57 (4), 424-436. Zaltman, Gerald, Robert Duncan, and Jonny Holbek (1973), Innovation and Organizations. New York: John Wiley. Zhou, Kevin Z., Gerald Y. Gao, Zhilin Yang, and Nan Zhou (2005), Developing Strategic Orientation in China: Antecedents and Consequences of Market and Innovation Orientations, Journal of Business Research, 58 (8), 1049-1058. Zomerdijk, Leonieke G. and Jan de Vries (2007), Structuring Front Office and Back Office Work in Service Delivery Systems, International Journal of Operations & Production Management, 27 (1), 108131. Zeithaml, Berry and Parasuraman (1988), "Communication and Control Processes in the Delivery of Service Quality," Journal of Marketing, 4, pp. 35-48.

95

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Determinants of Technical Efficiency of Rose Cut-Flower Industries in Oromia Region, Ethiopia


Mohammed Aman School of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University P.O.Box +251 138, Dire Dawa, Ethiopia Email: rosemuhe@gmail.com or muhecristy@gmail.com Jema Haji School of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University P.O.Box +251 233, Haramaya, Ethiopia Email: jemmahaji@gmail.com or jema.haji@ekon.slu.se Received: October 11st, 2011 Accepted: October 16th, 2011 Published: October 30th, 2011 Abstract The objective of this study is to measure and identify input use efficiency level of 28 rose cut flower industries in three districts of Oromia Regional state (Ethiopia) using a two stage approach. . In the first stage, a non-parametric (DEA) method was used to determine the relative technical, scale and overall technical efficiencies. In the second stage, a Tobit model was used to identify sources of efficiency differentials among industries. The results obtained indicated that the mean technical, scale and overall technical efficiency indices were estimated to be 92%, %61 and 58%, respectively for the cut flower industries. This Implies, major source of overall technical inefficiencies was scale of operation rather than pure technical inefficiency. Besides, the estimated measures of technical efficiency were positively related with Farming experience, formal schooling years of managers and negatively related with age of farms. No conclusive result was obtained for the relation between size and efficiency. Key words: Technical Efficiency, Scale Efficiency, DEA, Tobit, Rose cut flowers, farming experience, Oromia, Ethiopia. Introduction Diversification of agricultural production is seen as a priority for least developing countries to reduce dependence on primary commodities. The main reason is, despite high dependence on these commodities

96

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

for their livelihood, declining trend of prices for primary agricultural commodities (Humphrey 2006). Accordingly, floriculture sector is chosen for enhancing farm incomes and reducing poverty in developing countries. In particular, African countries have a comparative advantage in rose flower varieties production. Fewer economies of scale and labour-intensive nature of production in cut flower industries are major sources comparative advantage for these countries (Labaste 2005). Due to suitable climatic conditions and natural resources; high level of support by the government; favorable investment laws and incentives; proximity to the global market (mainly Europe) and availability of abundant and cheap labour, Ethiopia is the second largest producer of rose cut flowers in Africa following Kenya (Habte 2007). Moreover, the cut-flower industry in Ethiopia has emerged as one of the biggest sources of foreign exchange earning in recent years. This is mainly because of increased demand for cut-flowers, in the world market, by countries like Netherlands, Germany, Italy, United States, United Kingdom and Switzerland (Belwal & Chala 2007). Despite above opportunities, the high costs of technology, knowledge intensity of production, lack of access to capital, strict market regulations and standards; and demanding infrastructural requirements along with non existence of diversity in cut flower exports i.e. more than 80 % are a single rose variety, made the country not to benefit much (Melese 2007). To achieve simultaneous cost reduction and higher yield level of rose cut flowers, improving the resource use efficiency of these industries is relevant. And hence, this study is designed to estimate technical efficiency level and to identify its main determinants in the production of rose cut flowers in Awash Melkassa, Bishoftu and Ziway districts, respectively. These study areas are chosen due to relative similarity in terms of their geographic characteristics, market conditions, production practices and type of rose cut flowers grown. In particular, this study tries to answer following questions; what is the existing level of efficiency of rose cut flower industries in the study areas? Is there any room for improvement in the level of efficiency for rose cut flower industries? What are the main causes for the existing level of efficiency? What are the main possible solutions to improve the existing level of efficiency in rose cut flowers production? By what level will input(s) be reduced to obtain the existing yield level of rose cut flower stems? The rationales for this study are, identifying the technical efficiency level of the rose cut flower industries, will help business owners as to what extent they can reduce scarce resource use while maintaining current yield level of rose cut flower stems. Moreover, due to recent development of the sector in Ethiopia, checking for technical efficiency of these farms will also help policy makers in future policy design. Materials and Methods Sources and Types of Data Primary data on the industry features, characteristics and production processes are collected through an interview with farm managers using a semi-structured questionnaire from the 28 rose cut flower industries. Whereas, the secondary cross sectional data on input and output for one growing season (45 days) were collected from each daily input use records in order to calculate the variables required for the empirical analysis. The data used in this study was drawn from a survey conducted from December 7, 2010-January, 2010/11, in the three districts.

97

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
Methods of Data Analysis Given decision making units (DMUs) producing and as input matrix (X) and according to Coelli et al. (1998)is: Subject to

www.iiste.org

products (outputs) using

inputs, input and output , the linear

vectors may be represented by

, respectively. For each DMU, all data may be written in terms of as output matrix ( ). Under the assumption of

programming model for measuring the technical efficiency of rose cut flower farms can be given as follows

Where, Vector of rose cut flower stems by the Vector of inputs of the - Rose cut flower stems output matrix - Rose cut flower production input matrix If industry for for cut flower industries. rose cut farms. . industry. model is with rose cut flower industry.

- The input oriented technical efficiency score having value Vector of weights which defines the linear combination of peers of the is only suitable when all

, the industry will be technically efficient; otherwise inefficient. And work at optimum scale. Otherwise,

The specification of

measures of technical efficiency can be mistaken for scale efficiency. Therefore, the also named as pure technical efficiency, as it is free of scale effects. Thus, technical efficiency in DEA model could be obtained from following linear programming: Subject to And Where, defined in the is a convexity constraint ( model. and is an

reformulated by imposing a convexity constraint. Technical efficiency measure obtained with VRS model is

vector of ones) and other variables are as models, scale inefficiency is

When there is a difference in efficiency score values between Grosskopf 1994). Scale efficiency values for each analyzed scores for technical efficiency with Returns to Scale Returns to scale and

confirmed, indicating that the return to scale is variable, i.e. it can be increasing or decreasing (Fre & can be obtained by the ratio between the are scale operating with Decreasing . If the ratio value equals to 1, it indicates

efficient and a value less than 1 imply scale inefficiency. Furthermore, are assumed to operate under sub-optimal conditions.

is operating under super-optimal condition while those operating with increasing

98

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

After efficiency scores are obtained, to identify the determinants of efficiency, a Tobit model is used for the second-stage relationship between efficiency measures and suspected correlates of inefficiency (Binam et al. 2003; Irizoz et al. 2003; Chavas et al. 2005; Barnes 2006). The reason for using Tobit model for DEA efficiency scores is the bounded nature of efficiency level between 0 and 1. In this case, estimation with OLS would lead to biased parameter estimates (Green 1991; Dhungana et al. 2004). Rather a two-limit Tobit regression is estimated using commonly used statistical software STATA version 10. Definition of Variables The dependent variable, in first stage, is given by total number of rose cut flower stems produced. While, the independent variables included in this stage are: land measured by total hectare of land under greenhouse, the total labour (total number of temporary and permanent), water (the total amount of water (m3) used in the greenhouse rose cut flower farms), the rose plant seedlings (estimated by the total number of rose flower plant seedlings stems used by the farms.), nitrate, sulphate and acid fertilizers measured by (kg) used. In the second stage, however, the dependent variable is the technical efficiency score level of the rose cut flower industries. Then this dependent variable is regressed over the following farm specific socioeconomic variables. Average area per greenhouses; location of the farm in KM (distance from the Bole International airport); Ownership (measured by dummy values of 1 if the rose cut flower farm is domestically owned and 0 if owned by foreign investors.); Age of the farm (years since the establishment of the rose cut flower farm); Managers education level (formal schooling years spent by the farm managers) and Managers farming experience (total years of farming experience by the farm managers in same or related farming). The output and inputs data, from the twenty-eight rose cut flower industries, are used to estimate the technical efficiency levels in the production of rose cut flowers by using DEAP version 2.1 with an input orientation option i.e. since the industries are targeted at minimization of input use. Results and Discussion Descriptive statistics The mean land size holding, under greenhouses, in the study areas was 19.17 hectares, with minimum and maximum sizes of 4.98 and 42 hectares, respectively. While, the mean employment level was 536 workers. The mean amount of nitrate, sulphate and acid fertilizers used in greenhouses were 12.82 kg, 26.46 kg and 1.98 kg, respectively. Furthermore, the mean, water, rose flower plant seedlings and cut flower yield levels were 47,300 m3, 1,066,500 and 9,671,800 stems, respectively. Efficiency (DEA) Results In this section, district as well as industry level technical efficiency results are discussed. For the sake of comparison, technical efficiency indices are estimated both under level and type of returns to scale. The district level technical efficiency results indicate that, industries at Awash Melkassa, Bishoftu and Ziway districts could reduce their input use by 24%, 64% and 22% without any loss of rose cut flower stems. While, the mean technical efficiencies, using , were 100, 90 and 94 percent for Awash Melkassa, and along with scale efficiency

99

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
Bishoftu and Ziway districts, respectively (Table 1).

www.iiste.org

Table 1. Descriptive statistics of the technical efficiency scores of districts Case Districts N Mean S.dev Awash Melkassa 1 0.76 CRS Bishoftu 13 0.36 0.22 Ziway 14 0.78 0.34 Total 28 0.58 0.35 Awash Melkassa 1 1.00 VRS Bishoftu 13 0.90 0.11 Ziway 14 0.94 0.10 Total 28 0.92 0.11 Source: Author survey, 2011.

Min 0.76 0.14 0.15 0.14 1.00 0.71 0.64 0.64

Max 0.76 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00

Range 0.00 0.86 0.85 0.86 0.00 0.29 0.36 0.36

Furthermore, results obtained indicate statistically significant difference in mean technical efficiency level for rose cut flower industries in case of CRS i.e. farms in Ziway district were performing well followed by farms in Awash Melkasa and Bishoftu districts. However, the difference was not statistically significant in case of VRS. This may be due to similar technologies of production used by rose cut flower industries. Frequency distribution of the technical efficiency scores in both CRS and VRS are given in Table 2. Accordingly 8 industries under CRS and 16 under VRS are technically efficient and the remaining technically inefficient. Table 2. Frequency distribution of technical efficiency scores (VRS, CRS and SE) Frequency of Technical Efficiency TE scores CRS Percent VRS Percent 1.00 8 28.57 16 57.14 0.91- 0.99 2 7.14 2 7.14 0.81- 0.90 1 3.57 5 17.86 0.71- 0.80 1 3.57 4 14.28 0.61- 0.70 1 3.57 0.51- 0.60 0.41- 0.50 3 10.71 0.31- 0.40 5 17.86 0.21- 0.30 4 14.28 0.11- 0.20 4 14.28 Mean 0.58 0.92 Minimum 0.14 0.64 Maximum 1.00 1.00 S.dev 0.35 0.11 Source: Author survey, 2011. Returns to Scale of Industries The majority,19 (67.85%), of scale inefficient rose cut flower industries were operating under IRS with only one farm operating under CRS. Those operating under IRS are small industries that need to increase

SE 8 3 1 1 2 6 5 2 0.61 0.19 1.00 0.33

Percent 28.57 10.71 3.57 3.57 7.14 21.43 17.86 7.14

100

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

their size of operation. While, those operating under DRS are large industries operating above their optimal scale and thus could be better-off by reducing their size of operation. Accordingly, most of the scale inefficient industries, in the three districts, need to expand their size of holding to efficiently utilize their resources (Table 3).

Table 3. Efficiency and returns to scale distribution of rose cut flower industries Technical Efficiency Returns to Scale CRS CRS SE IRS CRS Industries Efficient 8 16 8 Inefficient 20 12 20 Total 28 28 28 19 8 Mean 0.58 0.92 0.61 Source: Own (Authors) calculation

DRS

The mean SE was 0.61 This result imply that , the average size of the greenhouse rose cut flower industries in the study areas is far from the optimal scale and an additional 39 % productivity gain could be feasible, provided they adjusted their farms operation to an optimal scale. The causes of inefficiency for the industries could be either inappropriate scale or misallocation of resources. Inappropriate scale suggests that industries are not taking advantage of economies of scale in rose cut flower production process. While, misallocation of resource refers to inefficient input combination. As shown in Table 3, the mean SE and TE (VRS) score were 0.61 and 0.92, respectively. This relatively low scale efficiency mean value indicates the main cause of technical inefficiency, for the rose cut flowers industries, is inappropriate scale (scale inefficiency) rather than misallocation of resources (pure technical inefficiency). In this study, input slacks are also estimated. The input slacks, using the VRS technical efficiency measure (pure technical efficiency), indicate excess use of that input(s) relative to other peer farms. The mean slack values for land, labour, water, nitrate, sulphate and acid fertilizers and rose plant seedling inputs are 0.76 hectares, 478 workers,1,810 m3,1.3 kg,1.76 kg,0.22 kg and 130041 stems, respectively. Among fertilizers, smallest mean input slack value is obtained for acids followed by nitrates. The reason is that, acid fertilizers are used to clean the drip pipes and less frequently applied than the two fertilizers. The rose cut flower industries can reduce costs, incurred on inputs, by the amount of slacks without reducing production level of rose cut flower stems. Determinants of Technical Efficiency In order to examine the effect of relevant technological, farm specific and socio-economic factors on technical efficiency of rose cut flower farms, the input oriented VRS technical efficiency scores are regressed on the selected explanatory and farm specific variables using a two-limit Tobit model since efficiency scores are bounded between 0 and 1 (Table 4).

101

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Table 4. Determinants of technical efficiency in rose cut flowers production The log likelihood estimates The Robust standard estimates Variables Parameters Efficiency effect Parameters Efficiency effect Constant( ) b0 -0.976 b0 -0.976 (0.667) (0.258) b1 -0.020 b1 -0.020 (0.023) (0.016) b8 -0.004 b8 -0.004 (0.012) (0.009) b9 0.259 b9 0.259 (0.101) (0.093) b10 -0.009* b10 -0.009** (0.035) (0.022) b11 0.104** b11 0.103*** (0.039) (0.028) b12 0.048** b12 0.048*** (0.023) (0.014) Log likelihood 0.937 Log 0.937 Pseudo likelihood Sigma 0.133 0.133 *** Significant at 1%; ** significant at 5%; * significant at 10%. Standard errors were shown in parenthesis, (x1= Average land area, x8 =location, x9 = ownership, x10 = age of industry, x11= managers education and x12= managers experience). The result obtained for age of the industry shows a negative and significant effect on technical efficiency of rose cut flower production implying older rose cut flower farms are less technically efficient than new ones. While, the formal education schooling years and experience in same or related business of farm managers has positive and significant effect on technical efficiency level of the farms. Furthermore, the marginal effects for the determinants of technical efficiency were also estimated. And hence, for a unit percentage increase in years rose cut flower farms, technical efficiency decreases by 1 %. While, a one percent additional formal schooling years of the farm mangers will improve technical efficiency of the industry by 10.3 %. Finally, a one percent additional farming experience of the farm manager will improve technical efficiency by 4.8 % (Table 5). Table 5. Marginal effects of efficiency variables after Tobit regression The log likelihood estimates The Robust standard estimates Variables Parameters dy/dx Parameters b1 -0.020 b1 (0.023) b8 -0.004 b8 (0.012) b9 0.259 b9 (0.101)

dy/dx -0.020 (0.016) -0.004 (0.009) 0.259 (0.093)

102

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
b10 b11 b12 Source: authors own calculation Conclusion

www.iiste.org

-0.01* (0.035) 0.103*** (0.039) 0.048** (0.023)

b10 b11 b12

-0.01* (0.022) 0.103*** (0.028) 0.048*** (0.014)

Results obtained indicated that there is a room to improve technical efficiency level of rose cut flower industries in the study areas. For instance, the mean scale efficiency value of 0.61 implying, on average, rose cut flower industries in the three study districts are not operating at their optimal farm size. Among the factors that are assumed to affect technical efficiency level, experience in same or related farming activities as well as more years of formal schooling by the farm manager increased technical efficiency level Whereas, age of the farm, along with rose cut flowers grown inside, decreased the technical efficiency level. As far as marginal gain in technical efficiency is concerned, formal years of schooling dominates that of farm manager farming experience in same or related farming activities. References Barnes, A.P. (2006), Does multi-functionality affect technical efficiency? A non-parametric analysis of the Scottish dairy industry, Journal of Environmental Management 80,287-294. Belwal, R., & Chala, M. (2007), Catalysts and barriers to cut flowers export: A case study of Ethiopian floriculture industry, International Journal of Emerging Markets 3(2), 216-235. Binam, JN., Sylla, K., Diarra, I., & Nyambi G. (2003), Factors affecting technical efficiency among coffee farmers in Cote dIvoire: Evidence from the centre west region, African Development Review 15, 66-76. Chavas, J-P., Petrie, R., & Roth, M. (2005), Farm household production efficiency: Evidence from the Gambia, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 87(1), 160-179. Coelli, T.J., Rao, D.S.P., ODonnell, C.J., & Battese, G.E. (1998), An introduction to productivity and efficiency analysis (2nd edition), Springer Science, New York. Dhungana, B.R., Nuthall, P.L., & Nartea, G.V. (2004), Measuring the economic inefficiency of Nepalese rice farms using data envelopment analysis, The Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 48 (2), 347-369. Fre, R., Grosskopf, S., & Lovell, C.A.K. (1994), Productivity frontiers, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Green, W. (1991), LIMDEP: Users manual and reference guide, New York: Econometric software, Inc. Habte, S. (2007), Ethiopia cut flower export industry and international market: Investment opportunity profile in Ethiopia. Humphrey, J. (2006), Horticulture: Responding to challenges of poverty reduction and global competition, Acta Horticulture 69(9), 1938. Irizoz, B., Rapn, M., & Zabaleta, I. (2003), Assessing the technical efficiency of horticultural production in Navarra, Spain Agricultural Systems78, 387-403.

103

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Labaste, P. (2005), The European horticulture market. Opportunities for Sub- Saharan African exporters. Working Paper NO. 63, Washington: The World Bank. Melese, A. (2007), Triple role of the Dutch in the growth of the cut-flower industry in Ethiopia. Unpublished Thesis for partial fulfillment of masters of arts in development studies, The Hague, The Netherlands.

List of Tables Table Page

Table 1. Summary Statistics of Study Variables........................................72 Table 2. Tests for Serial Correlation, ARCH and Normality.........................73 Table 3. Unit Root Tests of Variables of the Model.....................................73 Table 4. Bivariate GARCH Estimations of Output Growth and Inflation......73 Table 5. Variance Decompositions............................................................74

104

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Appendices Appendix Table A 1.Name and location of DMUs (rose cut flower farms) DMUs Name of the rose cut flower farm District (location ) 1 AQ Roses Plc Ziway 2 Exp. Incorporated Chibo Flowers Ziway 3 Sher flowers 8 Ziway 4 Braam Flowers PLC Ziway 5 Ziway Roses PLC Ziway 6 Sher Ethiopia PLC Ziway 7 Rainbow Colors PLC Bishoftu 8 Yassin Legesse J. Flower Farm Bishoftu 9 Dugda Floriculture Dev't PLC Bishoftu 10 Joytech PLC Bishoftu 11 Bukito Agro Industry Bishoftu 12 Friendship Flowers Bishoftu 13 ZK Flower Bishoftu 14 Eyasu Sirak Workineh Flowers PLC Bishoftu 15 Olij Flowers PLC Bishoftu 16 Minaye Flowers PLC Bishoftu 17 Roshanara Rose PLC Bishoftu 18 Super Arsity Flower PLC Awash Melkasa 19 Sher flowers 1 Ziway 20 Sher flowers 2 Ziway 21 Sher flowers 3 Ziway 22 Sher flowers 4 Ziway 23 Experience Flowers PLC Ziway 24 Evergreen Roses PLC Bishoftu 25 Zubka General Business Flower Farm Plc Bishoftu 26 Sher flowers 5 Ziway 27 Sher flowers 6 Ziway 28 Sher flowers 7 Ziway

105

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Socio-Economic Impact through Self Help Groups


D.Amutha Asst.Professor of Economics, St.Marys College (Autonomous), Tuticorin Email: amuthajoe@gmail.com Received: October 14th, 2011 Accepted: October 19th, 2011 Published: October 30th, 2011 Abstract The overall objective of the present study is to analysis the economic empowerment of women though SHGs in three villages of Tuticorin District of Tamilnadu. This study is compiled with the help of the primary data covered only in a six month period (2011). Totally 238 respondents were selected from 18 SHGs of three villages by using simple random sampling method. Empowerment signifies increased participation in decision-making and it is this process through which people feel themselves to be capable of making decisions and the right to do so. Womens participation in decision-making in family is important indicator for measuring their empowerment. The analysis shows that 66 percent beneficiaries reported decisions are being taken by their husbands, yet, more than 34 percent respondents accepted that they do participate in decision-making process. Thus, the socio-economic conditions of women have demonstrated that their status has improved since the joining of SHGs and availing microfinance. The result of chisquare- test revealed that there is significant difference between participation in decision-making in family and SHG women members in Tuticorin District. Keywords: Self-Help Groups, women empowerment, percentage analysis, averages, chi-square tests 1. Introduction Empowerment can serve as a powerful instrument for women to achieve upward social and economic mobility and power and status in society. Womens empowerment would be able to develop self-esteem, confidence, realize their potential and enhance their collective bargaining power. A SHG is a small economically homogeneous affinity group of the rural poor voluntarily coming together to save small amount regularly, which are deposited in a common fund to meet members emergency needs and to provide collateral free loans decided by the group. (Abhaskumar Jha 2000). They have been recognized as useful tool to help the poor and as an alternative mechanism to meet the urgent credit needs of poor through thrift (V. M. Rao 2003) SHG is a media for the development of saving habit among the women (S. Rajamohan 2003). SHGs enhance the equality of status of women as participants, decision-makers and beneficiaries in the democratic, economic, social and cultural spheres of life. (Ritu Jain 2003). The basic principles of the SHGs are group approach, mutual trust, organization of small and manageable groups, group cohesiveness, sprit of thrift, demand based lending, collateral free, women friendly loan, peer group pressure in repayment, skill training capacity building and empowerment (N.Lalitha). Some estimates put these at currently 2.5 million SHGs in India. (Economic Survey of India, p.67). In Tamil Nadu the SHGs were started in 1989 at Dharmapuri District. At present 1.40 lakh groups is a function with 23.83 lakh members.

106

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Many men also eager to form SHGs, at present. Tuticorin District having 19 town panchayats formed 1230 SHGs, and their achievement is 259%. In the process, it aims to commission women with multiform forms of power; hence a study was conducted on empowerment of women by SHGs in Tuticorin District, Tamil Nadu. 1.1 Objectives The main objectives of the study are mentioned below:

To study the socio economic background of the members of Self Help Groups of Tuticorin District To know the reasons for joining SHGs. To examine the activities of Self Help Groups in the study area. To evaluate the political and entrepreneurial empowerment of SHG members.

1.2 Methodology The present study has covered three villages from Tuticorin District viz, Meelavittan, Mullakkadu and Korampallam. These three villages were selected for this because of the SHGs in these villages is functioning in a very successful manner. This study is compiled with the help of the primary data covered in only six month period (2011). The primary data collected with the help of specially prepared interview schedule. Totally 238 respondents were selected from 18 SHGs of three villages by using simple random sampling method. The sample size was 1/3 of the total members of the SHGs. This is purely a descriptive study. Percentage analysis, averages, standard deviation, variance, chi-square tests, Cramers V and probability analysis were used for the analysis. 2. Discussion and analysis 2.1 Age Age is an important factor in determining the empowerment of SHG members. In the present study an effort has been made to know the age group of the respondents. In the study area, 238 respondents in three villages from Tuticorin District viz, Meelavittan, Mullakkadu and Korampallam were selected for the study and average number of the respondents in Tuticorin District study areas was about 48 members and standard deviation was about 16. Table 1 Age wise classification of the respondents Particulars(years) Frequency Percentage Results 31-40 41-50 51-60 61 and Above Total 39 162 33 4 238 16.4 68.1 13.9 1.6 100.0 Mean (Average):59.5 Standard deviation: 70.02143 Variance (Standard deviation): 4903 Population Standard deviation: 60.64033 14.2632460.64033 Variance (Population Standard deviation):3677.25

107

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
Source: Primary data

www.iiste.org

The table 1 shows the age wise classification done into four different categories. From the table we find that the respondents mainly fall under the age group of 41-50 where the highest frequency occur i.e. 162 and in total sample size it constitutes to 68.1% followed by the age group of 31-40 and its frequency is 39 which constitute 16.4% in the total sample, followed by the age group of 51-60 which the frequency is 33 and its percentage of the total sample size is 13.9%. This indication would be relevant to the study because most of the earning members in a family would be in the age group of 41-50. 2.2 Community The caste system was introduced in ancient India on the basis of occupation. Even now to some extent people of a particular caste or community stick on to a particular trade. Even though the caste behaviour can be moulded with the help of education, exposure and multi-media development, it plays its own role relating to empowerment of SHG members. Table 2 Community-wise Classification of the respondents Particulars Frequency Backward Classes Most Backward Classes MBC SC/ST Total Source: Primary data From the table 2 it is understood that the respondents are mainly from the SC/ST community which is 55.1% of the total respondents. Following this next stands the backward class community with 85 members and 35.7% of the total sample size. Here most backward class is only a meager amount in the sample i.e. 22 in numbers and 9.2% in total percentage. 2.3 Religion The religion of the family is a major influence on the empowerment of SHG members. Table 3 Religion wise Classification of the Respondents Particulars Frequency Percentage Hindu Muslim Christian Total Source: Primary data The table 3 reveals that 86.1% of the total respondents belong to the Hindu religion and the actual number is 205 of the total 238 samples selected. The remaining 13.1% are Christians. This might be about the fact that the field area chosen should be a Hindu religion dominated area. 2.4 Occupation 205 2 31 238 86.1 0.8 13.1 100.0 85 22 131 238 Percentage 35.7 9.2 55.1 100.0

108

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

The SHG members were engaged in various occupations such as agriculture operations and private jobs. The occupation of the members helps them to avail themselves of credit from the banks and invest it in their irrespective occupations to earn more. Table 4 Occupation of the Respondents Particulars Frequency Percentage Unemployed Agriculture Industry Collie Total 9 221 3 5 238 Source: Primary data From table 4 we conclude that more number of the respondents is engaged in agriculture for their means for livelihood i.e. 221 respondents are agriculture earning people. 2.5 Reasons for joining SHGs The major aim of SHG is to promote savings, generate income and credit for the productive and consumptive purposes. This is true because in the study area the sample women joined the SHGs for getting loan and promoting their savings and income, in addition to attaining of social status. Table 5 Reasons for joining SHGs Reasons Family Income Bored at home To give good life to children Total Source: Primary data (Mean: 79.33333; Standard deviation: 107.15565) The table 5 reveals that 85.3 percent of women stated that the most important motivating factor to join the SHG was to supplement their family income. It also reveals that there is definite growing awareness in society and women in particular that if the family has to maintain a reasonable standard of living, women should supplement to family income with whatever skill they have 8.8 and 5.9 percent of them stated that they join the SHG was bored at home and to provide good life for their children, respectively. 2.6 Satisfactions with Family The satisfaction of respondents with family members means equal status, participation and powers of decision making of women in household level. The satisfaction of respondents with family members has been reported to be quite high. Frequency 203 21 14 238 Percentage 85.3 8.8 5.9 100.0 3.8 92.9 1.2 2.1 100.0 Results Mean (Average): 59.5 Standard deviation: 107.69556 Variance (Standard deviation): 11598.33333 Population Standard deviation: 93.26709 Variance (Population Standard deviation): 8698.75

109

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
Table 6 Satisfactions with Family Satisfaction Meelavittan Very Happy Not Happy Total Source: Primary data 58(60.4) 38(39.6) 96(100.0)

www.iiste.org

Mullakkadu 65(79.3) 17(20.7) 82(100.0)

Korampallam 39(65) 21(35) 60(100.0)

Total 162 (68.1) 76 (31.9) 238 (100.0)

(2=7.58, P=0.022596, df=2, Cramers V=0.1785), Significant at 1% probability level. As shown in table 6 most of them were found satisfied (68%) with the family members, while a significant proportion was reported to be burdened (32%). The chi-square analysis result (2=7.58, P=0.022596), shows no significant relationship of satisfaction of respondents with family members and SHG members of group in Tuticorin District. 2.7 Activities of SHG SHGs have created positive attitude of community towards functioning of SHGs, micro-financing as well as being effective on social problems. Table 7 Activities of SHG Activities of SHGs Expands services area Communication skills& marketing techniques updated Contact with personnel from government & public organizations NGOs& other knowledge of how to get things done in public life Increase in self confidence and risk bearing capacity Total Source: Primary data (Mean: 47.6; Standard deviation: 15.94679; Variance: 254.3) Generally SHGs include various activities. The important activities are contact with personnel from government and public organizations (26.5%) and NGOs and other knowledge of how to get things done in public life (24.3%) and average number of the respondents in Tuticorin District study area was about 48 members and standard deviation was about 16. 2.8 Decisions Making in Family Empowerment signifies increased participation in decision-making and it is this process through which people feel themselves to be capable of making decisions and the right to do so. Womens participation in decision-making in family is important indicator for measuring their empowerment. Table 8 Decisions Making in Family Decision Making Meelavittan Mullakkadu Korampallam Total Frequency 54 24 63 58 39 238 Percentage 22.6 10.1 26.5 24.3 16.4 100.0

110

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011
Husband Yourself Total Source: Primary data 49(54.4) 41(45.6) 90(100.0) 72(83.7) 14(16.3) 86(100.0)

www.iiste.org

36(58.1) 26(41.9) 62(100.0)

157 (65.9) 81 (34.1) 238 (100.0)

(2=19.12, P=0.000070, df=2, Cramers V=0.2834), Significant at 5% probability level It is obvious from table 8 that 66 percent beneficiaries reported that decisions are being taken by their husbands, yet, more than 34 percent respondents accepted that they do participate in decision-making process. Thus, the socio-economic conditions of women have demonstrated that their status has improved since the joining of SHGs and availing microfinance. The result of chi-square- test (2=19.12, P=0.000070), revealed that there is significant difference between participation in decision-making in family and SHG women members in Tuticorin District. 2.9 Political Empowerment Participation in Panchayatraj institution, understanding the political environment and accessing political power provide empowerment. So the opinion of the respondents were collected and shown in the following table.

Table 9 Political Empowerment Particulars Participation in Panchayatraj Institution Understand the Political Environment Total Source: Primary data

Meelavittan 68(76.4) 21(23.6) 89(100.0)

Mullakkadu 80(90.9) 8(9.1) 88(100.0)

Korampallam 23(37.7) 38(62.3) 61(100.0)

Total 171 (71.8) 67 (28.2) 238 (100.0)

(2=51.88, P=<0.0001, df=2, Cramers V=0.4669), Significant at 1% probability level Participation in Panchayatraj institution and understanding the political environment provide empowerment. So the opinion of the respondents were collected and shown in the following table. 72% respondent were expressed that participation in Panchaytraj institution and 28% respondents were of the view that understanding the political environment showed significant difference (P < 0.001). 2.10 Entrepreneurial Empowerment Entrepreneurs are those persons who seek to generate value, through the creation or expansion of economic activity by identifying and exploiting new products, process or markets. Entrepreneurial activity is the enterprising human action in pursuit of the generation of value, through the creation or expansion of economic activity, by identifying and exploiting new products, process or markets. Entrepreneurial activity

111

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

includes the entry of new products, the creation of new products or service, and the innovation associated with different business activated. Entrepreneurial activity can therefore be associated with organic as well as acquisitive decision. Table 10 Entrepreneurial Empowerment Particulars Meelavittan Increase desire to learn more professional skills Intensifies desire to earn and better living Total Source: Primary data (2=85.36, P=<0.0001, df=2, Cramers V=0.5989), Significant at 1% probability level From the table, 82% respondents were of the view that SHG intensifies desire to earn more and make better living and only 19 percent of women expressed that SHG increases desire to learn more professional skills and the difference was statistically significant (2=85.36, P=<0.0001). 3. Conclusion SHGs started functioning all over Tamilnadu, in some areas they are functioning effectively whereas in other areas they face problems. Since SHGs help women to achieve economic empowerment, these policy measures can contribute a lot to the nation. To conclude, the economic activities of SHGs in Tuticorin District are quite successful. References Abhaskumar Jha (2004), Lending to the Poor: Designs for Credit, EPW, Vol. XXXV, No.8 and 9. Chiranjeevulu T. (2003), Empowering Women through Self Help Groups Experiences in Experiment, Kurukshetra, March. Chopra Kanchan (2004), Social Capital and Development Processes Role of Formal and Informal Institutions , Economic and Political Weekly, July, 13. Economic Survey of India, 2007-08. Jeyanthi Gayari, R (2002), SHGs in Kanyakumari District, M.Phil., dissertation submitted to Alagappa University, Karaikudi, T.N. Jeyaraman, R. et al., (2004), Role of Self help Groups in Fisher Women Development, Peninsular Economist, Vol. XII, No.2, pp. 197-200. K. Usha (2003), Gender, Equality and Development, Yojana Keishnaraj, Maithreyi (2005), Growth and rural Poverty, Economic and Political Weekly, September 21. Lalitha, N. Women Thrift and Credit Groups- Breaking the Barriers at the Gross Roots, Peninsular Economist, Vol. XII No. 2, pp. 188-195 Manimekalai, N. et. al., Gross-root Women Entreprenurship through SHGs, Peninsular Economist Vol. XII, No.2, pp. 181-187 Rajamohan, S. (2003) , Activities of Self Help Groups in Virudhunagar District-A Study, TNJC, pp. 25-29 17(10.2) 149(89.8) 166(100.0) Mullakkadu 4(9.1) 40(90.9) 44(100.0) Korampallam 23(82.1) 5(17.9) 28(100.0) Total 44 (18.5) 194 (81.5) 238 (100.0)

112

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online) Vol.2, No.6, 2011

www.iiste.org

Rao, V.M. (2003), Women Self Help Groups, Profiles from Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka, Kurukshetra, Vol. 50, N0.6, pp. 26-32 Ritu Jain, (2003), Socio-Economic Impact through Self Help Groups, Yojana, Vol. 47, No.7, pp.11-12 Sabyasachi Das, (2003), Self Help Groups and Micro Credit Synbergic Integration, Kurushetra Vol. 51, No.10, pp. 25-28 Sreeramulu, G (2006), Empowerment of Women through Self-Help Group, Eastern Book Corporation. Vandana K. Jena, (2007), Literacy for Womens Empowerment, Indian Journal of Population Education, IAEA, New Delhi, No.38, July-Sep. www.expressindia.com www.flyhighonline.com www.indianngos.com www.knowledgeallianz.com www.microfinancegateway.org

113

You might also like