You are on page 1of 17

Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1 – 17

Introduction

Diversity and integration of science and technology policies


Pedro Conceição *, Manuel V. Heitor
Center for Innovation, Technology and Policy Research, IN+, Instituto Superior Técnico, Lisbon, Portugal
Received 25 April 2006

Abstract

This paper discusses recent conceptual approaches to technical change, based on an emerging diversity of
policies and increasing binstitutional specializationQ and clarification of the role of the private and public incentives
to support S&T. This fact is reflected in the trend in developed economies towards increasing private investment in
science and technology and we argue for the need to promote public policies in modern societies fostering
competence building.
This broad concept has motivated the work behind the present special issue, which was launched during the 6th
International Conference on Technology Policy and Innovation (ICTPI), hold in Monterey, Mexico, in the summer
of 2003. Under the broad designation of bConnecting People, Ideas, and Resources across CommunitiesQ the
Conference brought together a range of experts to discuss technology, policy and management in a context much
influenced by a dynamic of change and a necessary balance between the creation and diffusion of knowledge.
Thus, this special issue includes a set of extended and revised contributions to the Monterey conference that are
largely grounded on empirical experiences of different regional and national contexts. The aim of this introductory
paper is to set the stage for these contributions, with an original contribution on possible views for emerging
science and technology policies.
D 2006 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction: relying on science and technology policy?

Why the focus on science and technology policy? As we emphasized in earlier papers, learning can
occur in many shapes and forms, some of which are informal and other are formal [1]. The institutions

* Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: pedro.conceicao@undp.org (P. Conceição)8 mheitor@ist.utl.pt (M.V. Heitor).

0040-1625/$ - see front matter D 2006 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2006.05.001
2 P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17

and organizations that comprise the national and regional systems of science and technology attempt
largely to formalize and accelerate the learning process for individuals, firms, and nations. Thus, by
looking at this particular set of organizations and their networks, and institutions, we could be able to
suggest routes for policy that can positively influence the conditions for inclusive development through
learning.
The challenges for policy in order to move towards inclusive development and wealth generation are
really twofold. First, what can be done at the regional and national level to start and sustain learning
networks and trajectories that can lead to wealth creation? Second, how can the overall global learning
processes be made more inclusive, so that fewer countries are excluded, extending the reach of the
learning networks globally?
At the national level, it is increasingly clear that innovation is not a direct consequence of R&D. In the
academic literature, the lack of validity of the linear model of innovation has been repeated ad nausea,
but the fact remains that it still informs much of the policy rationale for investing in R&D. There is no
question that the ideas that result from formalized knowledge exploration activities lead, in the long-run,
to innovations, but to expect this to be so in the short run is misguided both for firms and governments.
Kortum and Lerner [2], for example, show that venture capital is probably much more effective in
promoting innovation than R&D at the firm level.
This does not mean that firms and governments should stop doing R&D, but rather that they should
do it for the right reasons. And there are many, from promoting human capital, to extending the frontier
of knowledge. But in terms of public policy, the realization that innovation and R&D are not as
connected as once thought is particularly important. This realization means the firms may lack even
more incentives to perform their own R&D as previously thought, and thus require a stronger
intervention of the public sector. This may be particularly important for late industrializing countries,
with scientific and technological systems not yet fully developed and matured. Often these countries
show very low levels of private commitments to R&D, with disproportionate high government
expenditures in R&D.
In a previous paper we have shown that the structure and financing of science and technology
activities has undergone a change characterized by a shift from relying and supporting public science to a
stronger emphasis on bmarket-basedQ incentives for science, technology and innovation [3]. Given the
strong economic performance of the United States over the 1990s, this shift has influenced policies in
most OECD countries, and especially in Europe. We noted that, from an analytical perspective, the
continuation of this shift all the way to a point in which there are only private incentives is not desirable.
In fact, for many authors, the trend as it exists presently is already reason for concern, since rather than
what theory prescribes–that there should be a mix of public and private incentives to science, technology
and innovation–we may have reached a situation where incentives in the United States are too biased
towards the private side of the mix. In fact, the United States has historically pursued a wide range of
approaches to encourage research and to build research infrastructure. New approaches have been
adopted over time as the nature of the research/innovation endeavor evolved. The infrastructure is today
quite diverse and robust with multiple performers. Similarly, the set of incentives to encourage research
is diverse. Given the high uncertainty surrounding scientific research and innovation, this robust research
infrastructure system minimizes the risk of poor targeting of research priorities, and the mix of public
and private incentives strengthens this robustness. It is clear, in fact, that along with private incentives,
public policy is needed to mobilize investment of social resources in new technologies and to insure the
health of the overall enterprise.
P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17 3

It is a brushQ to understand, and to copy, the U.S. system as being too driven by private incentives for
S&T. bBlanketQ recommendations to enhance property rights or to limit public resource allocation, based
on the U.S. experience, may be misguided. Even if there is a clear shift towards more private incentives
in the United States, there is a long history of past investments and a current division of labour or
specialization that cannot be replicated in systems with a lower scale and complexity. The key message
from the U.S. history is that of a diversity of policies and increasing binstitutional specializationQ and
clarification of the role of the private and public incentives to support S&T. With the hindsight gained
from the discussion above, we can also bexplainQ the increased need of public intervention for science
and technology policies, as resulting from the non-rival character of software.
In this paper we argue that it is crucial not only to make available financial resources (namely public
resources), but also to do so in a way that provides the right incentives for S&T organizations to hook up
in learning networks that can generate localized social capital and endogenous growth dynamics. That
way is definitely not unique and depends on local conditions, roots and trajectories, which raise the
question of inclusive development [4].
We will start by analysing human resources developments over the last century that are associated
with technical change and, then, we will continue by discussing the pattern of innovation studies and
policies that have emerged during the last decades. The analysis is oriented towards the development of
engineering world-wide and of its increasing complexity, as reflected on the increasing non-linearity of
innovation, but it considers complementary and broader approaches that have called our attention for the
need to emphasize the development of human resources and organizational and institutional capabilities
[5].

2. Building technical competences for knowledge accumulation

It is clear from the literature that the welfare of individuals, organizations and countries is based,
particularly since the 1st industrial revolution, on the creation, diffusion, and use of technology. During
the last decades of the 20th century, this reality was reflected in the trend in most developed economies
to promote investments in high technology, research and development, and in technical education, as
well as investments in education and culture.
In this context, Fig. 1 compares the share of university degrees in various OECD countries by the end
of the 20th century, illustrating the relative weakness of late industrializing countries in terms of
technical qualifications (considering both engineering and natural sciences). Fig. 2 compares the total
number of students in the higher education system in a group of small European countries, while Fig. 3
shows the percentage of engineering graduates in the active population aged between 25 and 64 in
several OECD countries throughout the 20th century. These indicators are clearly limited in scope, but
do represent the international promotion of the scientific and technological base as a principle to guide
developed countries.
According to Romer [7], the role of public policies for science and technology training is particularly
critical for the economic growth over the long-run. These policies have accounted for the fast increase in
the number of engineers and scientists in the United States from the postwar period to the 1970s. In fact,
the study of the relationships between knowledge creation and economic development is an increasingly
important component of research on public policies that seek to stimulate growth. It is legitimate to argue
about changes to the traditional way of thinking about the economic growth, and to question the role
4 P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17

Fig. 1. National share of university degrees among different fields (1997). Adapted from [6].

played in that process by the technical education and science and technology systems. In short, these
reflections are based on a new conceptual approach to economic development, in that the knowledge
accumulation appears as a fundamental engine of the development process.
For many authors, the idea of knowledge-based economies is still a concept and more than a reality
that can be objectively characterized. This characterization has been based essentially on stylized facts,
like the growing incorporation of knowledge in physical products, the increase in the value associated
with ideas vis-à-vis material goods, and the strong importance of services. Traditionally, economic
growth has been explained as resulting from the growth of labour and capital factors, and of
technological change. It is important, however, to rethink the way these factors occur in the process of
economic development.
Regarding the contribution of labour, the evidence is that the quantitative increase in the population is
insufficient to account for the economic growth verified. This is because the developed economies
increasingly produce intangible factors, creating employment, mainly in the service sector, where
education and professional qualifications are requested. Thus, for the growth and employment creation,
it is crucial to increase human capital so that the access to more and better skills, namely through
education, can be promoted.
As far as the contribution of capital is concerned, the accumulation of intangible assets has gained
importance vis-à-vis physical capital. Thus, the importance of knowledge does not only appear through
the contribution of technological change, which has led to the need to rethink the traditional patterns of
P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17 5

Fig. 2. Total number of students in the higher education system for the period 1960–2001 in a selected group of small European
countries. Adapted from [1].

explaining economic growth. For instance, the new growth theories include many of these efforts,
suggesting that knowledge accumulation can be understood as learning and is the most important factor
to explain the process of economic development at long run.

Fig. 3. Percentage of graduated engineers in active population aged between 25 and 64 years old in a selected group of OECD
countries. Adapted from [1].
6 P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17

What does this discussion have to do with technical change and the role of technical education and of
research in the economy? To introduce this question, it is important to consider, in the first place, the
traditional perspective of the economic growth, for which growth results from the accumulation of the
work and capital factors, as well as of the technological change. The introduction of the technology
factor, that is due to Solow [8,9], proved to be essential for the empirical explanation of the measured
growth levels. The simple accumulation of the work and capital factors has never been enough. But
technology always appeared as being external to the economic process, an exogenous component, as
mentioned in the specialized literature.
According to the new theories of the economic growth the perspective is completely different. The
accumulation of capital, or, in the new nomenclature, of objects, continues to be essential. But the only
source of continued growth production is knowledge: new ideas to produce new objects and to organize
the existing objects in an increasingly efficient way, on one hand. On the other hand, new and improved
skills allow the implementation of ideas and the use of objects. For example, Romer [10] has a simple
principle: new ideas and new and better skills, that is, more knowledge, are really responsible for
productivity and efficiency gains, resulting in economic growth. As a matter of fact, mankind has been
constrained since the beginning of civilization by the natural resources and energy with which our planet
was gifted. Human development only results from the knowledge that is generated and accumulated,
allowing the rearrangement of these resources in an increasingly productive manner.
Thus, in the new growth theories, knowledge, in first place, is not limited to technology, and, in
second place, it is not exogenous. It corresponds, alternatively, to new ideas and skills, not only in the
technological field, but also in the social, legal, political, and administrative fields, among others.
If it is true that knowledge accumulation accounts for the largest contribution to growth, it is now
important to briefly discuss how that accumulation happens. In other words, knowledge accumulation
means to learn, not in the strict sense of an individual learning, but in a wider context, where one can
speak about organizational, national and regional learning.
The formalization of the economic development process in the new growth theories follows the model
originally proposed by Arrow [11]. It is important to briefly focus on the analysis of Arrow since it
contains the essence of the foundation of economic development as a learning process. Instead of
following the orthodoxy at the time, which attributed the inexplicable growth component according to
the accumulation of the work and capital factors to technological change, Arrow argued that the
experience in the capital use led to an increase in knowledge used in the production. In a more prosaic
way, Arrow formalized in a relatively simple model the idea that the workers of a company learn with
the use of production means, increasing the company’s productivity.
Therefore, learning, i.e., knowledge accumulation, appears as the engine of efficiency increases,
resulting in the economic growth. It is interesting to notice that Arrow chose an informal way of
learning, learning by doing, to support his thinking. In this model, knowledge is entirely accumulated
under the form of skills. The contribution of the new theories of the economic growth was, precisely, to
extend this thinking to other learning types, as well as the accumulation of ideas, starting from the
moment that Romer [12] demonstrated the generality of the Arrow’s arguments.
Two other models of new theories have been pointing out the formal institutional mechanisms that
exist in our society to accelerate the learning process, namely education and research. The models that
depend on education follow Lucas’ seminal work [13], while Romer [14] and Grossman and Helpman
[15] are the canonical references for the models that have, as an endogenous growth source, research and
innovation.
P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17 7

Pasinetti [16] articulated in a very clear way the idea that learning is the source of growth, having
observed that: bSince man is able to learn, advancement occurs because the next society has always a
better departure point than the previousQ.
In this context, Pasinetti considers that the human capacity to learn is the key-factor for economic
growth, a perspective that is the foundation for the new growth theories. Nevertheless, according to
Pasinetti, the sources and growth mechanisms are different from those considered by the new theorists of
economic growth.
Analysis shows that some of the more considered authors, who are linked to the new economic
growth theories, analysed knowledge accumulation under the form of skills, education being a formal
learning process. Additionally, there were also developed models where the accumulation of ideas stems
from the effort in research, another formal process of learning. In this context, two aspects should be
pointed out.
Firstly, in the early 1990s the focus was on the study of the accumulation of ideas through R&D, a
tendency that has been reinforced in recent works. There are, at least, two reasons for this. On one hand,
the study of the informal learning process is more complex and less likely of being tested empirically.
This leaves room for reflection about the accumulation of ideas through R&D, since studies on the
education role have a considerable past, bearing in mind the theories of the human capital in the 1960s.
On the other hand, the truly remarkable modern day fact is the growing codification of knowledge, and
the potential that the digital economy bor the information societyQ reserves for us.
Secondly, there has been a recent interest in analysing the economic implications of the resulting
learning processes of social interaction, mainly under the scope of the binformation society.Q Actually,
this aspect introduces a new vision for the education system, namely regarding the radical change of the
magisterial teaching towards an announced learning, which is directly associated with continuous
training (lifelong), and to the need to manage different demands and a multifaceted public. Additionally,
the fact that informal processes of learning are being shared by a diversified spectrum of institutions
makes it possible to open new perspectives to the science and technology system and to create and
disseminate knowledge.

3. Learning from innovation studies and policies

At the onset of the 20th century few could have guessed the importance that the then nascent
technologies would have in the improvement of the quality of life over the ensuing century. As we
enter the 21st century the promise of further improvements based on new and deeper applications of
technology, and engineering systems in general, is a reason for optimism. While it is difficult to
forecast the exact shape and form that new technologies will assume, it is safe to say that there are a
number of challenges to which technical competences can provide, at least partially, a response. The
vision supporting this book is based on an identification of some of those challenges that, although
related to technology, must be understood in a context in which the integration of a diversified social
context and economic fabric in an increasingly open and interconnected world cannot be ignored. The
assumption is that several now disjointed disciplines must join efforts to provide new solutions to
mobilize people, ideas, and tools to help to catalyse the strong progress in information and
communication technologies needed to secure the necessary creativity for a sustainable future
worldwide. This chapter discusses these challenges in terms of what we know today from successive
8 P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17

science, technology and innovation studies, partly devoted to improve our understanding of ways to
accelerated forms of breliable knowledgeQ [17].

1.1. Understanding technological innovation: from the Manhattan Project to the systemic understanding
of innovation

Under a context of not only increasing complexity, but also uncertainty, it is well known that the
systematic coordination of S&T at an international level, and the consequent development of science,
technology and innovation policies are a result of the Second World War and, in particular, of the
Manhattan Project, that has materialized the use of nuclear physics [18–20]. Science was removed from
university and public laboratories and exposed to society, primarily to develop military technology for
immediate application. The creation of the National Science Foundation, in 1950 in the United States of
America following Vanevar Bush’s influential report launched immediately after the end of the war
marked the role of public funding to university R&D [21]. In fact, Bush noted that: Historical
development has given the sanction of tradition to the prominent role played by universities in the
progress of pure science. [. . .] Several factors combine to emphasize the appropriateness of universities
for research.
With the bcold warQ and the brace for the spaceQ, this process increased substantially, with the national
budgets for the science and technology reaching very significant figures, especially in the United States,
with public-funded R&D programs for different technologies [22]. As Salomon [23] referred, after the
Second World War, first for strategic reasons, and then, on behalf of the economic growth and
competitiveness, science became, irreversibly, a subject of the State.
If the 1950s and 1960s were characterized by a widespread growth in economical terms, that in fact
has allowed financing the expansion of education and S&T systems, the 1970s, on the other hand,
witnessed an effective attenuation of the economic growth level and, in particular, a decrease in
productivity growth often designated by productivity slowdown [24]. This attenuation had, together with
other factors, deep implications on the development of education and S&T systems, namely through
studies that demonstrated no direct correlation between the resources allocated to R&D activities and
economic results. Nevertheless, the 1970s attested fast scientific and technological transformations,
resulting in new and important technologies that could have even have improved the economic
performance, accompanying the regeneration of obsolete technologies. The perplexity that resulted from
this apparent contradiction was named productivity slowdown paradox [25].
An important consequence of the effort to justify this paradox was a deep alteration in the perception
of the relationships between science and technology and the economy. In fact, until the early 1970s, the
dominant understanding was that technology was generated in a system external to the economy, which
made inventions that would come into the economic system at a later date, corresponding to an
innovation. The explanatory mechanisms of those processes were linear, of the pipeline type, leading to
technology-push models (in that a new technology provides commercial explorations) and market-pull
(in that the perception of market needs drives the R&D effort). These were called linear models of
innovation.
Thus, during the 1970s the conscience that it was necessary to rethink the role of S&T in a way
beyond considering technology a closed box (bblack boxQ, in the terminology of Rosenberg) has
emerged. The political implications of these perceptions led to the favourable management of S&T
systems, considering that it was necessary to decide on scientific and technological investments adapted
P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17 9

to the resolution of specific problems. As a result, developed countries, namely at the OECD level, have
integrated S&T policies in the remaining economic policies, clearly seeking to innovate and promote
economic development.
In the 1980s, the reflection on the relationship between technology and economic and social
development has new details. The new theories of economic growth and the descriptions of the
dynamics of technological change and innovation not only have broadened new horizons, but also
uncertainties, in the way science and technology can be effectively managed and implemented. Within
a broad set of different approaches, the OECD program designed to explain the relationships between
the economy and technology considers technology endogenous to the economy, as it is generated and
disseminated through a complex fabric of relationships and interactions between companies,
universities and laboratories, resulting in innovation [26]. Thus, the linear models of the 1960s gave
place to the understanding of innovation as a complex, non-structured process involving institutions of
the education and the S&T systems and companies, under which R&D activities determine, and are
determined by the market, in a way that was first acknowledged and modelled by Kline and
Rosenberg [27] through the so-called binteractive model of innovationQ (or bchain-linked model of
innovationQ). From this point, innovation is depicted as a multi-layer process with multiple feedbacks
between different activities and functional units of the firm. Innovation does not flow linearly from
R&D and does not result only from knowledge generated within the firm. The 1990s reinforce this
notion, but requiring a more comprehensive understanding of other external effects associated with the
processes of worldwide economic integration (i.e., bglobalizationQ) and of the competitiveness
imperative.
During the 1980s and 1990s, the bEuropean schoolQ equally developed the more sophisticated
approaches to innovation with the approaches led by Rosenberg and others across the Atlantic. Freeman
and Soete [28] summarize the main conclusion of this school, and Dosi [29] provides an integrative
review of the main differences between these perspectives and traditional neoclassical approaches in
economics. The fundamental difference, at the microeconomic level, is associated with the rejection of
the representative production function. Nelson and Winter [30] attempted to provide an epistemological
alternative to microeconomic foundations of neoclassical modelling.
Mytelka and Smith [31] consider the co-evolving process of policy making and theory building, and
note the way the linear perspective still informs much of today’s public perceptions about innovation, as
well as policy design and implementation. The reliance on simple and direct indicators such as
expenditure of R&D by the private sector reflects the dominance of the linear perspective. We do not
question the importance of these and other indicators, we are merely asserting that they provide an
incomplete description of the innovation process and are tied to the linear perspective.

1.2. Extending the conceptual understanding of innovation

During the 1990s several attempts have been established to improve our understanding of the
increased complexity associated with innovation and technical change. Romer [32] recognizes the
importance of what he calls appreciative theories of growth and innovation (following the introduction
of the term by Nelson and Winter) in helping more formal approaches to better describe the richness of
the innovation process. Somehow, the link has been hard to accomplish, possibly due to insurmountable
epistemological differences between scholars in the neoclassical tradition and others of more
appreciative nature. In fact, Romer [14] constructs his theory of endogenous growth drawing on the
10 P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17

non-rival nature of ideas. Dasgupta and David [33] advance new ideas about the economics of science
building also on the same principles associated with the special characteristics of knowledge.
Using the economic characteristics of knowledge is useful not only as a modelling tool, allowing the
development of new conceptual approaches, but also as a guide for policy [34]. And, in a series of
papers, we have explored the implications of the non-rival character of ideas and the rival character of
tacit knowledge to advance policies associated with higher education policy [35,36].
Beyond the studies about the economics of knowledge, an important part of recent research on
innovation has concentrated on institutional and organizational issues. In fact, enterprise organization
has become central to the policy debate on the sources of European competitiveness, leading to the
promotion of many forms of organizational change. As noted by Lorenz [37], this has derived from the
growing recognition that ICT investments alone generally fail to deliver improved enterprise
performance, requiring adequate human practices, among a complex set of other interrelations. As a
result, the need for organizational innovation has promoted in recent years a large amount of works
contesting a traditional, neo-classical understanding of the firm and the economy [38]. The emerging
knowledge perspective is concerned with the role of technological change and firm behaviour in
economic growth. The foundations of this approach can be found in the work of Schumpeter [39], but its
main development and application were done by Nelson and Winter [30]. In their approach, the firm is
understood essentially as a repository of knowledge, which is translated into routines that guide
organizational action. Building on these perspectives and on earlier work in organizational theory that
emphasized the mechanisms for the growth of firms, a knowledge based vision of the firm has been
under development in the last decade, offering new insights for strategy and management theory [40]. It
includes natural systems and institutional theory while embracing global perspectives. Also, it
encourages multidisciplinary perspectives to better explore the meaning of competitive advantage in
developing, acquiring, and using knowledge for enhanced products and processes and in better
understanding the interaction between organizations and the economy in which they are embedded.
In terms of the discussion above, it is interesting to note that we can identify at least three different
ways of delimiting the systemic view of innovation [41], namely: (i) the innovation system as rooted in
R&D; (ii) the innovation system as rooted in the production system; and (iii) the innovation system as
rooted in production and in human resources. Lundvall [42] uses this latter and broader approach to
analyse the interaction between technical change, organizational change and competence building in the
case of Denmark and successfully concludes that the general economic climate in terms of the
transformation pressure and the intensity of competition has a major impact on what firms do by way of
technical innovation and organizational change. His analysis strongly supports the views expressed by
Andreasen et al. [43] in terms of the need to focus European policy on stimulating organizational change
in European firms. However, it is known that the Danish type of innovation system is intense in its use of
bnational social capitalQ and before it can be considered as a benchmark, one must account for the
question of social cohesion and its complex relationships with competence building and innovative
capacity.

1.3. The emergence of studies on innovation, competence building and economic equality

Following the analysis in the previous paragraphs, it is clear that a topic of increased awareness for
innovation researchers has been derived from the need to better understand the link between competence
(skills, education), and innovation (technological change). Carneiro [44] refers that bInstead of requiring
P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17 11

a skill, . . . employers are seeking competence, a mix, specific to each individual, of skill in the strict
sense of the term, acquired through technical and vocational training, of social behaviour, of an aptitude
for teamwork, and of initiative and a readiness to take risksQ. Many instances can be given about the
importance of building competence. Carneiro chooses a few, from the resurgence of the bhuman capitalQ
literature–which has percolated to the language of everyday life–to the very idea of the knowledge-based
economy. Carneiro also explores the implications of the importance of competence building to the
individual and to the dynamics of innovation and presents the idea that it is important to nurture
vocational identities. Vocational identities include, but are more than just, the individual knowledge base
and the portfolio of competencies. These include attitudes revealing a preference for learning, in which
bcompetence buildingQ considers also aspects such as the strengthening of identity and of a foundation of
emotional stability and of self-esteem. Thus, the idea of competence building is, in this context, viewed
in a much more comprehensive and deeper way, encompassing the individual in several dimensions. The
link with innovation is made through the distinction between adaptive and generative learning, which are
connected with the Schumpeterian cycle of creative destruction.
In this context it has become a bcommonplaceQ to assume that technological change is (or has
become) skill-biased, in the sense that it requires people with high skills [45]. Specifically, digital
computers and, more generically, information technologies, are considered the btrend breaking
technologyQ that is responsible for the inequality increases [46].
Alternatives to the skill-biased technological change include the perspective advanced by Bresnahan
[47], who rejects the complementarity between computers and the human capital (or skills) of individual
computer users. Instead, Bresnahan proposes an organizational complementarity between information
technologies and telecommunications (ICTs) and highly skilled workers. In Bresnahan’s model, ICTs,
instead of improving the productivity of individual workers, change the organizational structure of firms,
reducing the needs for back-office workers, and increasing the demand for front-office workers and
managers.
Thus, skill-biased technological change has been advanced as an explanation for rising levels of
income inequality. This explanation is grounded on the assumption that wages are the result of market
clearing via the competitive pricing of the capabilities of people. Different capabilities are associated
with different levels of skill, education, and seniority in the work force. High skill/education/experience
is associated with a higher marginal product of labour and commands higher wages than low skill/
education/experience. The evolution of the difference between the prices of skill, the relevant issue in
studying changes in inequality, depends on the interaction between shifts in the relative demand for more
skilled labour over less skilled workers and changes the relative supply of skilled labour.
There is, however, a second class of explanations, not necessarily excluding the labour market
perspective outlined above, that puts much more emphasis on the role of institutions. Specifically,
changes in the institutions that constrain the definition of wages override competitive forces in the
dynamic evolution of income associated with rising inequality. These institutional changes include the
weakening of unions–which erode the bargaining power of low paid workers–changes in pay norms
(more contingent employment and pay), and the decline in the real value of the minimum wage, which,
can constitute an important redistributive tool [48].
A standard division of OECD countries according to these two classes of explanations places the
United States, and also the United Kingdom in the 1980s, in the realm of the labour market category, and
the remaining OECD countries in the wage-setting institutions class [49]. The reason, it is argued, is that
the labour market in the United States and the United Kingdom after the 1980s, is much more free from
12 P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17

the strength of collective, centralized bargaining than the remaining OECD countries. However, even for
the OECD countries other than the United States and the United Kingdom, the skill supply and demand
hypothesis has been gaining momentum and thus we will spend some more time analysing this
hypothesis.
There are two dimensions to the skill supply and demand story. The first concerns the validity of the
assumption that labour market mechanisms are dominant in driving the dynamics of inequality.
Assuming that the labour market provides a good framework for analysis, the second dimension is
related with the ultimate causes that originate the labour market responses that generate inequality. At a
very fundamental level, some scholars reject totally the existence of the validity of considering the
existence of a labour market rewarding skill and human capital. Some of the critiques of the human
capital theory and the returns to education occur almost at the epistemological level. In fact, many
sociologists oppose the mainstream economics theory of human capital, arguing that cultural and
institutional factors are much more important in determining wages. Some authors have also argued that
sociological and psychological factors, rather than economic factors associated with supply and demand
for qualified labour, are dominant in setting wages.
However, if one is ready to accept the existence of a labour market where wages reward, at least
partially, productivity and skill, Katz and Murphy [50] provide strong evidence that supply and
demand go a long way in explaining the patterns in the evolution of inequality. Most of the recent
studies on inequality that focus on a single-country longitudinal analysis of the evolution of the
dispersion of income follow Katz and Murphy. Examples of the same methodology applied to other
single country studies include Schmitt [51] for the United Kingdom, and Edin and Holmlund [52] for
Sweden. Blau and Kahn [53] apply a similar procedure to a cross-section of OECD countries for a
single year.
This discussion not only clearly highlights the link between competence (skills, education) and
innovation (technological change), but also shows the need to bring to our attention the relevance of
social cohesion (economic inequality), as recently discussed in the volume edited by Conceição et al. [5].
Today it is well known that it is through the diffusion process that technological innovations are
translated into wide economic impact, as more and more people and firms consume and use the new
products or processes. And if we accept that this increasingly generalized usage of technological
innovations fuels not only increases in well being, but also the conditions to generate further
innovations, then one cannot escape the importance of demand conditions for economic and
technological prosperity. In fact, historians of economic evolution have shown that demand conditions
were crucial in the process of early industrialization in the United States.
Rosenberg [54] describes the demand conditions that were conducive to the earliest stages of
industrialization in the 19th century. In an economy that was primarily agricultural (in 1810, 80% of
active Americans were in agriculture), the most important resource was arable land, which was plentiful.
This was, indeed, the most important source of wealth for economically active Americans, and the
availability of land ensured a fairly equal distribution of this resource. This, in turn, meant that food
prices were relatively low, allowing, for the same level of income, a higher margin left to buy non-food
products.
This scenario is in stark contrast with the situation in Europe, where poor peasants and farm labourers
had virtually no income beyond that needed for subsistence needs. The American conditions fueled also
a rise in fertility that was translated into a large population growth that could go and occupy even more
of the still available fertile land, in a virtuous cycle of development. Therefore, the low level of economic
P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17 13

inequality, coupled with a relatively high level of income per capita, generated the conditions that
allowed for a demand of mass-manufactured goods.
Related anecdotal evidence is provided by Rosenberg making use of Henry Ford’s strategy in the
early 20th century: bThus, out of the social and geographic conditions of land-abundant America
emerged a set of tastes and preferences highly congenial to a technology capable of producing large
quantities of standardized, low-priced goods. These circumstances even left their indelible imprint on the
American automobile in the early years of the 20th century. The Ford Model T was designed in a manner
which strongly resembled the horse and buggy, and the primary buyers were farmers for whom a cheap
car offered a unique opportunity for overcoming rural isolationQ.
Therefore, demand conditions were important determinants in the diffusion of new technologies. In
fact, in Rosenberg’s argument, they were crucial to creating a new industrial system out of an agricultural
society. An important component of the demand conditions was a relatively high level of income per
capita and, equally crucial, a relatively egalitarian distribution of the marginal income available beyond
the one needed for subsistence. Inspired by this analysis of the interaction between inequality and
technology, we are interested in understanding whether, with the current wave of technological
innovations, there is also a relationship between levels of inequality at the country level and the rates of
diffusion of technology.
The argument we are advancing here is that social cohesion, beyond the issues associated with ethical
judgement and justice, can be of importance to efficiency as well. Galbraith [55] proposes an
interpretation of the economic success of the United States over the 1990s that is associated, precisely,
with this view.
For Galbraith, the reasons for the success of the American economy can be associated with the
creation of a more equitable society, in which access to education is more generalized and where income
is more equitably distributed than in Europe. The comparison between the distribution of income across
Europe and across the United States is based on taking Europe as a whole. That is, instead of comparing
the United States with individual European countries, Galbraith et al. takes into account the large
differences that exist across European countries [56].
In Galbraith’s view, the United States has made a large effort over time to create a more equitable
country through the reinforcing of the role and services provided by the U.S. Federal government, as
the state governments become less and less relevant, especially in the determination of
macroeconomic policies. In particular, the role played by the U.S. Federal government in terms of
social policy has been crucial in reducing geographic inequities. Additionally, an impetus should be
given to the creation of large, publicly funded European universities in the less developed zones of
Europe, mimicking the land grant act of the United States in the mid 19th century, which led to the
creation of focal points of development, especially in terms of innovation, dispersed around the United
States. The major threat to social cohesion in Europe is, according to Galbraith, the relatively high
level of unemployment [5].

4. Introducing this special issue

The analysis above shows that it is legitimate to question the traditional way of viewing the role of
science and technology policy and to argue for the need to promote public investment in competence
building, together with a diversified mix of mechanisms to foster science and technology. This broad
14 P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17

concept has motivated this special issue, which integrates a set of new contributions addressing
complementary aspects of relevance towards improved understanding of the process of technical change.
Miller and Clarke, in the following paper, analyse the hidden value of air transportation infrastructure
and argue that countries must invest in air transportation infrastructure to ensure their ability to meet
current and future demand for aviation services. The authors use system dynamics to model different
strategies for infrastructure delivery. These strategies are defined by three variables: the amount of
capacity increase, the time to deliver the capacity and the congestion threshold that triggers the need for
capacity delivery. Monte Carlo simulation is used to take into account multiple sources of uncertainty.
The model shows that a strategy of capacity delivery based on small increments and short response times
can yield more benefits than strategies that consider large capacity increases and long response times.
Furthermore, in the specific airport example considered, it was found that a congestion threshold of 75%
should be the trigger for capacity enlargements if strategies based on small capacity increments and 1 or
5 years to increase capacity are considered. The lesson for decision-makers is that congestion delays
must be addressed with foresight.
Michael Sable, in the third paper, discusses the impact of the biotechnology industry on local
economic development in the Boston and San Diego metropolitan areas and shows that, although high-
tech industries such as biotechnology are coveted as drivers of economic development, the local
development impact of these clusters of regional innovation is not entirely positive. This is especially
true with regard to the impact upon the low and semi-skilled populations. In some regions, the new
growth generated by high-tech clusters has converted relatively inexpensive open space into haphazard
commercial and industrial use that has contributed to sprawl, transportation congestion, lack of
affordable housing, and gentrification.
Nuno Oliveira, in the fourth paper, presents another case study on obstacles to the growth of
biotechnology. He take a closer look at the case of Portugal, a country where the industry has long been
at an embryonic stage and argues that generalist, top-down measures to stimulate general technological
development may not be appropriate to foster a sector composed of many unique characteristics.
Evidence from several countries suggests that there is a group of specific factors which all have to be in
place simultaneously to allow the emergence of a biotech industry.
Thurik and Baptista, in the fifth paper, discuss the effect of entrepreneurship on unemployment
and show that the industrial transformation from a managed to an entrepreneurial economy varies
widely across Western countries. As an example, they provide some empirical evidence supporting
the view that Portugal has been a relative outlier in regard to the effects of entrepreneurship on
unemployment when compared with the OECD average. Although the nature of entrepreneurship
may be different in the Portuguese case, due to a high proportion of bmicro-businessesQ created for
subsistence which have little impact on growth and employment, this factor does not seem to be the
primary reason for the observed discrepancies. The differences between observed levels of
unemployment for Portugal and those predicted by a model based on OECD data seem to be
mostly associated with macroeconomic fluctuations associated with European business cycles and EU
bcohesionQ funding, as well as with adjustment costs to new technology adoption which lead to
productivity slowdowns, thus increasing the time lag for the effect of entrepreneurship on
employment beyond the OECD average.
Maranto-Vargas and Gomez-Tagle, in the sixth paper, analyse the development of internal resources
and capabilities as sources of differentiation of SME under increased global competition in Mexico. The
authors found statistical evidence to suggest that business performance measured by growth rate,
P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17 15

efficiency, productivity and shareholder’s financial returns, is positively related with the development of
internal capabilities such as soft technology (methods and processes that support the firm) and hard
technology (externally acquired equipment, in-house development of machinery and innovation in raw
materials) and a strategy of continuous improvement, innovation and change. Results of this research
support the propositions that the development of a geographical region or country should be an
interaction between a number of constituents, namely government policies, the firms themselves and
universities and research centers among others that align their strategies towards the development of geo-
economic regions.
The final paper, by Moutinho and Heitor, considers the co-evolution of urban environments and
information and communication technologies in terms of the social and cultural shaping of information
technologies and related uncertainties for their application to regional and urban contexts. The analysis is
based on observations in different digital cities and regions with the ultimate goal of increasing regional
competitiveness, by promoting public awareness and participation in decision-making processes. It is
argued that the territory is a basic infrastructure that justifies and invites for the construction of several
layers of information, but above all for communication infrastructures and digital contents well arranged
with local contexts. The analysis led the authors to suggest that while the role of public policies needs to
be re-examined, the cultural and social shaping of information technologies requires the specific
development of human-centered systems to support community building activities. This calls for the
need to combine flexible infrastructures and adequate incentives with institutions, to foster the necessary
context for digital cities to succeed.

References

[1] P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor, Innovation for All? Learning from the Portuguese Path to Technical Change and the Dynamics
of Innovation, Praeger, Westport, 2005.
[2] S. Kortum, J. Lerner, Does Venture Capital Spur Innovation? NBER Working Paper 6846, National Bureau of Economic
Research, Cambridge, MA, 1998.
[3] P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor, G. Sirilli, R. Wilson, The dSwing of the PendulumT from public to market support for science
and technology: is the U.S. leading the way? Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 71 (6) (2004) 553 – 578.
[4] P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor, F. Veloso, Infrastructures, incentives and institutions: fostering distributed knowledge bases for
the learning society, Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 70 (7) (2003) 583 – 617.
[5] P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor, B.-Å. Lundvall (Eds.), Innovation, Competence Building, and Social Cohesion in Europe—
Towards a Learning Society, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, 2003.
[6] National Science Board, Science and Engineering Indicators—2000, National Science Foundation, Arlington, VA,
2000.
[7] P. Romer, Should the Government Subsidize Supply or Demand in the Market for Scientists and Engineers? NBER
Working Paper 7723, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, 2000.
[8] R.M. Solow, A contribution to the theory of economic growth, Q. J. Econ. 70 (1) (1956) 65 – 94.
[9] R.M. Solow, Technical change and the aggregate production function, Rev. Econ. Stat. 39 (1957) 312 – 320 (August).
[10] P. Romer, The origins of endogenous growth, J. Econ. Perspect. 8 (1) (1994) 3 – 22.
[11] K. Arrow, The economic implications of learning by doing, Rev. Econ. Stud. 29 (3) (1962) 155 – 173.
[12] P. Romer, Increasing returns and long-run growth, J. Polit. Econ. 98 (5) (1986) 1002 – 1037.
[13] R.E. Lucas, On the mechanics of economic development, J. Monet. Econ. 22 (1) (1988) 3 – 42.
[14] P. Romer, Endogenous technological growth, J. Polit. Econ. 98 (5) (1990) s71 – s102.
[15] G.M. Grossman, E. Helpman, Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1991.
[16] L. Pasinetti, Structural Change and Economic Growth, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, MA, 1981.
16 P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17

[17] J. Ziman, Reliable Knowledge: An Exploration of the Grounds for Belief in Science, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK, 1991.
[18] C. Freeman, The learning economy and international inequality, in: D. Archibugi, B.-Å. Lundvall (Eds.), The Globalizing
Learning Economy: Major Socio-Economic Trends and European Innovation Policy, Oxford University Press, Oxford,
2001, pp. 147 – 162.
[19] N. Rosenberg, Knowledge and innovation for economic development: should universities be economic institutions? in: P.
Conceição, D.V. Gibson, M.V. Heitor, G. Sirilli, F. Veloso (Eds.), Knowledge for Inclusive Development, Quorum Books,
Westport, CT, 2002, pp. 35 – 47.
[20] Landes, 2003.
[21] V. Bush, Science—The Endless Frontier, United States Government Printing Office, Washington, DC, 1945.
[22] P. David, B. Hall, A. Toole, Is public R&D a complement or substitute for private R&D? A review of the econometric
evidence, Res. Policy 29 (4–5) (2000) 497 – 529.
[23] J.-J. Salomon, Modern science and technology, in: J.-J. Salomon, F. Sagasti, C. Sachs-Jeantet (Eds.), The Uncertain Quest:
Science, Technology and Development, United Nations University Press, Tokyo, 1994.
[24] Nelson, 1990.
[25] OECD, Technology in a Changing World, OECD, Paris, 1991.
[26] OECD, Technology and the Economy—The Key Relationships, OECD, Paris, 1992.
[27] S.J. Kline, N. Rosenberg, An overview of innovation, in: R. Landau, N. Rosenberg (Eds.), The Positive Sum Strategy:
Harnessing Technology for Economic Growth, The National Academy Press, Washington, DC, 1986.
[28] C. Freeman, L. Soete, The Economics of Industrial Innovation, third edition, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1997.
[29] G. Dosi, Sources, procedures and microeconomic effects of innovation, J. Econ. Lit. 26 (3) (1988) 1120 – 1171.
[30] R.R. Nelson, S.G. Winter, An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press,
Cambridge, MA, 1982.
[31] L. Mytelka, K. Smith, Interactions between policy learning and innovation theory, in: P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor, B.-Å.
Lundvall (Eds.), Innovation, Competence Building, and Social Cohesion in Europe—Towards a Learning Society, Edward
Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, 2003.
[32] P. Romer, Idea gaps and object gaps in economic development, J. Monet. Econ. 32 (3) (1993) 543 – 573.
[33] P. Dasgupta, P. David, Toward a new economics of science, Res. Policy 23 (5) (1994) 487 – 521.
[34] R.R. Nelson, P. Romer, Science, economic growth, and public policy, in: B.L.R. Smith, C.E. Barfield (Eds.), Technology,
R&D, and the Economy, Brookings Institution Press, Washington, DC, 1996.
[35] P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor, On the role of the university in the knowledge economy, Sci. Public Policy 26 (1) (1999)
37 – 51.
[36] P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor, Universities in the learning economy: balancing institutional integrity with organizational
diversity, in: D. Archibugi, B.-Å. Lundvall (Eds.), The Globalizing Learning Economy: Major Socio-Economic Trends
and European Innovation Policy, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2001, pp. 83 – 107.
[37] E. Lorenz, Innovation and organisational change, in: P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor, B.-Å. Lundvall (Eds.), Innovation,
Competence Building, and Social Cohesion in Europe—Towards a Learning Society, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK,
2003.
[38] K.M. Eisenhardt, F.M. Santos, Knowledge-based view: a new theory of strategy? in: A. Pettigrew, H. Thomas, R.
Whittington (Eds.), Handbook of Strategy and Management, Sage, London, 2002, pp. 139 – 164.
[39] J.A. Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, Harper and Row, New York, 1942.
[40] D. Teece, G. Pisano, A. Shuen, Dynamic capabilities and strategic management, Strateg. Manage. J. 18 (7) (1997) 509 – 533.
[41] B.-Å. Lundvall, J.L. Christensen, Broadening the analysis of innovation systems—competition, organisational change and
employment dynamics in the Danish model, in: P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor, B.-Å. Lundvall (Eds.), Innovation,
Competence Building, and Social Cohesion in Europe—Towards a Learning Society, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK,
2003.
[42] B.-Å. Lundvall, Innovation, Growth and Social Cohesion—The Danish Model, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, 2002.
[43] L. Andreasen, B. Coriat, F. den Hertog, R. Kaplinsky (Eds.), Europe’s Next Step: Organisational Innovation, Competition
and Employment, Frank Cass, London, 1995.
[44] R. Carneiro, On knowledge and learning for the New Millennium, in: P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor, B.-Å. Lundvall (Eds.),
Innovation, Competence Building, and Social Cohesion in Europe—Towards a Learning Society, Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham, UK, 2003.
P. Conceição, M.V. Heitor / Technological Forecasting & Social Change 74 (2007) 1–17 17

[45] A. Krueger, How computers have changed the wage structure? Evidence from micro data, Q. J. Econ. 108 (1) (1993)
33 – 60.
[46] D. Autor, L. Katz, A. Krueger, Computing Inequality: Have Computers Changed the Labor Market? NBER Working Paper
5956, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, 1997.
[47] T. Bresnahan, Computerisation and wage dispersion: an analytical reinterpretation, Econ. J. 109 (456) (1999) 390 – 415.
[48] R. Freeman, The minimum wage as a redistributive tool, Econ. J. 106 (436) (1996) 639 – 649.
[49] F. Blau, L. Kahn, International differences in male wage inequality: institutions versus market forces, J. Polit. Econ. 104
(4) (1996) 791 – 837.
[50] L. Katz, K. Murphy, Changes in relative wages, 1963–1987: supply and demand factors, Q. J. Econ. 107 (1) (1992)
35 – 78.
[51] J. Schmitt, The changing structure of male earnings in Britain 1974–1988, in: R. Freeman, L. Katz (Eds.), Differences and
Changes in Wage Structures, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, 1995.
[52] P. Edin, B. Holmlund, The Swedish wage structure: the rise and fall of solidarity wage policy? in: R. Freeman, L. Katz
(Eds.), Differences and Changes in Wage Structures, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, 1995.
[53] Blau and Kahn (1996).
[54] N. Rosenberg, Exploring the Black Box: Technology, Economics and History, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,
MA, 1994.
[55] J.K. Galbraith, European unemployment: what is the solution? Presented in the Research Seminar Towards a Learning
Society—Innovation and Competence Building with Social Cohesion for Europe, Guincho, Lisboa, 28–30 May, Available
at http://in3.dem.ist.utl.pt/learning2000/papers/01_3.pdf, 2000.
[56] J.K. Galbraith, P. Conceição, P. Ferreira, Inequality and unemployment in Europe: the American cure, New Left Rev. 237
(1999) 28 – 51 (September/October).

Pedro Conceição is Assistant Professor at the Instituto Superior Tecnico in Lisbon, Portugal, at the Center for Innovation,
Technology and Policy Research, http://in3.dem.ist.utl.pt/, and a Senior Research Fellow at the IC2 Institute, The University of
Texas at Austin, TX. He is currently at the United Nations Development Office, UNDP, in New York.

Manuel Heitor is Full Professor at the Instituto Superior Tecnico in Lisbon, Portugal and Director of the Center for Innovation,
Technology and Policy Research, http://in3.dem.ist.utl.pt/, and a Senior Research Fellow at the IC2 Institute, The University of
Texas at Austin, TX.

You might also like