You are on page 1of 13

Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479

Policy learning and innovation theory: an interactive


and co-evolving process
Lynn K. Mytelka∗ , Keith Smith
United Nations University, INTECH, Keizer Karelplein 19, 6211 Maastricht, The Netherlands
Received 27 September 2001; received in revised form 16 October 2001; accepted 16 November 2001

Abstract
This paper explores links between the development of innovation theory since the late 1970s, and the evolution of innovation
policy ideas, primarily in the 1990s. The argument is that there is a close connection between theory and policy, so that theory
and policy learning can be seen as an integrated, co-evolving and interactive process. We analyse the theory-policy learning link
in terms of two phases. We suggest that the complex economic crisis of the 1970s created an opening for rival analyses of events.
During the 1980s, the development of evolutionary theories (pioneered by Nelson and Winter) and of empirically-based theories
of the innovation process (pioneered by Nathan Rosenberg) created a framework in which policy agencies could consider
heterodox ideas concerning objectives and instruments of public policy. By the early 1990s policy-makers, particularly in
Europe, came to see RTD and innovation policies not just as important arenas of action in themselves, but as instruments
towards more wide ranging policy objectives. The policy agencies involved, though hierarchical, were characterised by
relatively open structures that permitted a degree of intellectual diversity: so organisations like the OECD and the European
Commission played a central role, whereas the World Bank, for example, did not. Increasing policy interest stimulated a
second phase of research in the 1990s, sponsored both nationally and by various EU programmes, in which expanding the
innovation-oriented knowledge base became a significant objective for policy-makers. The paper argues that the theory-policy
link has been central to the intellectual development of this field, which would have been impossible within the constraints of
existing disciplinary structures and university funding systems. At the same time the analytical achievements have permitted
a wide expansion in the conceptualization of policy targets and in the design of instruments available to policy-makers. In a
sense, this is itself an evolutionary story: of a crisis and a conjunctural niche that permitted the creation and (so far) survival
of a set of diverse and certainly non-conventional ideas.
© 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
Keywords: Public policy; Policy-makers; Learning; Innovation policy; Innovation theory

1. Introduction ing. This revision has been powerfully influenced by


the work of Richard Nelson and Sidney Winter, whose
The development of innovation theory over the past Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change proposed
20 years has involved a major reformulation, with the idea that innovation is shaped by crisis-driven
innovation no longer seen primarily as a process of search programmes by firms. As existing procedures
discovery (that is, of new scientific or technological falter in the face of shifting economic or technologi-
principles) but rather as a non-linear process of learn- cal conditions, firms began the search for alternatives,
∗ Corresponding author. in experimental learning processes. A major theme in
E-mail address: mytelka@intech.unu.edu (L.K. Mytelka). innovation research subsequently has been exploration

0048-7333/02/$ – see front matter © 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 0 4 8 - 7 3 3 3 ( 0 2 ) 0 0 0 7 6 - 8
1468 L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479

of the nature and characteristics of such learning, social science in American society as “ambiguous,
across firms, sectors, regions and national systems. precarious and critically important”. It was ambigu-
A related theoretical development was the idea that ous and precarious because people, to the extent that
learning occurs in specific institutional contexts: that they had views on the social sciences at all, often
is, in systemic environments shaped inter alia by reg- demonised them. Just a year before his paper was
ulation, law, political cultures, and the ‘rules of the published, the Conference of Small Business Organi-
game’ of economic institutions. These environments sations had passed a resolution “condemning the per-
of course include policy institutions and actions. But version of our educational system through so-called
policy structures are not developed once and for all. social science courses”, while the Illinois State leg-
Although they exhibit inertia, they also have dy- islature in its attack on the University of Chicago as
namic aspects, and this dynamism often results from subversive, singled out professors in the social sci-
learning—from improved understanding of the agents, ences (Redfield, 1950, p. 31). Such perspectives have
interactions and patterns that are the objects of policy. endured into recent years—in 1980, the then British
A central component of understanding the dynamics Minister for Higher Education, Sir Keith Joseph,
of innovation as a whole should therefore include the required the name of the Social Science Research
nature and effects of learning within policy systems. Council to be changed on the grounds that there was
There can be little doubt that there has been signif- no such thing as a social science.
icant change within innovation-related policy arenas Yet the role of social science, like science more
during the last 20 years. This has been a matter both generally, is also critically important, as Redfield ar-
of the objectives and instruments of policy. In terms of gued, because it provides the tools “to make order of
objectives, innovation policy has come to be seen as a experience”, to get “practical things done better than
central instrument for achieving outcomes that lie well they would be done through common knowledge”
beyond the field of RTD or innovation alone. The con- and to assess “the probable consequences of one
cepts and instruments of policy have also shifted, with course of action rather than another” (Redfield, 1950,
non-linear models of innovation and the ’innovation pp. 33–36). Not, of course, that people are eager
system’ concept playing a central role in policy to confront uncomfortable facts or to be told of the
discourse, and with a wide range of new policy in- possible negative consequences of their policies or
struments directed at networking, clustering, and per- actions; and therein lies the potentially subversive
sonnel mobility. We argue that this complex process role that social science can, and does, play in society.
of change can best be understood as policy learning. Essentially, this is because all new knowledge is in
The questions we address concern the drivers and some ways subversive, which is why intellectuals are
mechanisms of such learning. The argument in this pa- always somewhat marginal.
per is that the process of policy learning cannot be sep- There is, thus, a contradiction between the role of
arated from the development of the field of innovation the intellectual as a contributor to public debate and,
research itself. The scale and scope of such research in the words of Edward Said, as “someone whose
has expanded greatly during the past two decades. place it is publicly to raise embarrassing questions, to
Theory and policy are best seen as co-evolving: so confront orthodoxy and dogma” (Said, 1996, p. 11).
this is a process of interactive learning, in which a so- “In underlining the intellectual’s role as outsider”, he
cial science field, and a policy arena, have been jointly wrote in Representations of the Intellectual, “I have
and interactively shaped. A primary driver of this has had in mind how powerless one often feels in the
been the long-term impact of the economic crisis of face of an overwhelmingly powerful network of social
the 1970s. authorities—the media, the government and corpora-
tions . . . who crowd out the possibilities for achieving
any change. To deliberately not belong to these au-
2. Social sciences and public policy thorities is in many ways not to be able to effect direct
change” (Said, 1996, pp. xvi-xvii). But this, in turn,
In a short article published in 1950, Robert Redfield, raises interesting questions as to how ideas can enter
an American anthropologist, described the place of and survive in the public sphere.
L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479 1469

We suggest that being an “outsider” has not always theoretical underpinnings for a stream of future policy
been a disadvantage. This can be illustrated by ex- instruments; it was this policy dimension that proved
amining the role that social scientists have played in crucial to the acceptance of his framework.1
bridging the gap between innovation theory and in- Several decades later, crises and the insufficiencies
novation policy over the past three decades. This role of existing theory would once again open opportuni-
has taken the form of an interaction between hetero- ties for dissenting views. The unemployment-inflation
dox social scientists, and policy-makers seeking new crisis of the 1970s had long-lasting impacts, since the
perspectives in the context of a serious and persis- desperate monetary-based anti-inflation policies of the
tent economic crisis. Within evolutionary approaches, 1980s did little to affect unemployment, growth and
learning is often seen as a response to a more or less productivity problems. For policy-makers, this was in
critical problem, a problem that generates search with part a crisis of understanding. As Nelson and Winter
uncertain outcomes. In this context, learning requires argued, existing theory had “neither the breadth nor
time, and consists of reappraisals and modifications— the strength to provide much guidance regarding the
an evolutionary process in fact. Policy learning, which variables that are plausible to change” (Nelson and
is after all a central part of economic functioning, Winter, 1977, pp. 38–40). But opportunity alone does
should not be separated from other modes of economic not suffice to explain the emergence of innovation at
learning, and can be seen in this way. Our argument the centre of intellectual debates over growth, com-
is that the crisis of the 1970s generated a ‘niche’ in petitiveness and equity and of institutions and innova-
which heterodox analysts and officials within the less tion systems as conceptual tools for policy making in
hierarchically-structured organisations could interact the 1980s and 1990s. A number of other factors con-
around problem-oriented analyses, and that this is cen- tributed to this process.
tral both to policy development and innovation analy- First, the ability of social scientists to influence
sis. In this case, policy positions and innovation theory policy making with regard to technological innovation
co-evolve. resulted from a clear trespassing of the boundaries be-
To single out technological innovation as the focus tween academia and organisations. Over a sustained
of this paper is not to deny the many other cases in period of time, a growing number of “outsiders” do-
which social scientists have played such a role in re- ing research on different aspects of what has been
cent times, particularly through interactions with the termed the “new innovation paradigm”,2 worked
policy and business worlds. Macroeconomic policy is closely with a small number of international organ-
perhaps the best-known example. In 1936, when John isations and contributed to the evolution of their
Maynard Keynes published his General Theory of research programmes and to a learning process that
Employment, Interest and Money, theorists and policy
makers were searching desperately for an explanation 1 Raul Prebisch played a similar role in bridging the gap between

of the depth and length of the Great Depression. Many structuralist theories and trade and industrialisation policies in the
credit Keynes with revolutionising both economics 1950s and 1960s. Towards the end of the 1940s, Prebisch began to
develop his main hypotheses concerning the factors that accounted
and politics: the former by providing a powerful the- for the balance of payments disequilibria and deteriorating terms
oretical justification for deficit spending and demand of trade faced by developing countries in the periphery and for
management as a way out of the depression; and the the persistent gaps in income between centre and periphery. When
latter by influencing new policy initiatives through his Prebisch became Executive Secretary of the newly created UN
membership of various high-level government com- Economic Commission for Latin America (ECLA) in 1950, these
explanations formed the basis of ECLA’s structuralist approach
missions in the United Kingdom, consultations with to trade and industrialisation and influenced the industrialisation
government authorities in the US and participation policies of Latin American countries over the next two decades.
in the formative meetings of institutions such as the In 1963, Prebisch became the first Secretary General of UNCTAD
IMF and the World Bank (Hall, 1989; Salant, 1989). from which vantage point he sought to influence trade negotiations
Although many of the policies advocated by Keynes at the international level. (ECLA, 1951; UNCTAD, 1964).
2 These included industrial economists, economic historians, eco-
in his General Theory had been proposed earlier by nomic geographers, political economists and others on the margin
others and had already acquired many adherents in of mainstream economics, such as Bengt-Åke Lundvall, Richard
the US and the UK, it was Keynes who provided the Nelson, Christopher Freeman, Luc Soete and Michael Storper.
1470 L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479

ultimately led to a reformulation of the problem and nevertheless, these were organisations that could tol-
to a reconceptualisation of the search for solutions. erate a degree of intellectual variety. It was into this
Second, although these organisations were not the breach that evolutionary economists, regional geog-
powerful social authorities to which Edward Said raphers and other students of innovation stepped. The
referred, they had become increasingly more impor- next section charts this process through a brief ex-
tant as the locus of consensus-building and/or of amination of the concepts and theoretical approaches
rule-making in dealing with issues raised by the ac- introduced into academic debates and echoed in
celerated pace of technological change and the glob- working documents and publications of the OECD
alising world economy. Among advanced industrial and European Commission a few years later.
countries, these included organisations such as the
OECD and the European Commission, and in North–
South relations, the United Nations Conference on 3. Growth, competitiveness and innovation: the
Trade and Development (UNCTAD) and the UN refocusing of a debate
Economic Commission for Latin America (ECLA).
Such organisations contained elements that came to During the 1950s and 1960s, a set of social con-
see innovation and technological change as central to ventions and economic mechanisms were put in place
welfare and growth problems, and hence innovation- across Europe and North America that ensured the mu-
oriented policies came to be seen as key instruments tual adjustment of mass consumption and mass pro-
for achieving much wider objectives than simply the duction and provided a quasi constancy in profit share
creation of new technologies. with respect to value added. In this way, investment
Why did these particular institutions become the was stimulated, but only so long as demand was buoy-
location of policy innovation? We suggest that in con- ant. By the 1970s, a crisis was in the making when pro-
trast to more hierarchical organisations such as the ductivity increases became more difficult to achieve
IMF and the World Bank, access to policy-making and the growth of demand faltered.
circles and opportunities for influence have been We are still far from a full understanding of the
far greater in these ostensibly weaker siblings over factors that combined to produce this slowdown in
the same period. While in both sets of international productivity growth from the early 1970s. On the
organisations, problems growing out of the twin pro- one hand, there were a number of major system
cesses of globalisation and rapid technological change shocks: the collapse of the Bretton Woods system
were being placed squarely on the agenda, more hi- (itself stemming from a complex financial crisis),
erarchical organisations retained the macroeconomic the two OPEC oil price shocks of 1973/1974 and
perspective and broadly neo-classical conceptual ap- 1978, and general political instability (including
proaches with which they were most familiar.3 By the effects of prolonged war). On the other hand,
contrast, faced with the paradoxes of productivity there were economic and technological factors that
growth in the 1970s, the challenge of competitive- attracted little attention at the time, though increas-
ness in the 1980s and the problem of equity in the ing attention in subsequent decades (Aglietta, 1976;
1990s, other—perhaps more internally differentiated Boyer, 1988; Piore and Sable, 1984; Freeman and
or consensual—organisations, such as the OECD and Perez, 1988). The argument there was that on the
the European Community, contained niches in which production side, imbalances in capacity utilisation
conceptual diversity was possible. Although such between highly specialised mass-production machin-
diversity was often the object of internal conflict, ery, rigidities in supplier-client relationships and
management structures as well as labour problems
3 Despite extensive criticisms of the IMF/ World Bank structural all played a role in slowing down the diffusion of
adjustment programmes, the IMF response to the Asian financial productivity-enhancing techniques, both material and
crisis carried forward its traditional approach. Even the presence immaterial. On the consumption side, the crisis of the
of an “outsider”, Joseph Stiglitz, as Chief Economist of the World
Bank brought little by way of change in conceptual frameworks
1970s led to slower growth in domestic purchasing
or policy approaches in this institution and virtually no ability to power and a segmentation of markets into income and
influence practices in the World Bank’s sister institution, the IMF. product categories within which price and income
L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479 1471

elasticities of demand differed. Market saturation in part of the residual.5 (Abramowitz, 1971). Its acqui-
many of the consumer durables that had been the sition was assumed to result from a quasi-automatic
staple fare of large corporations also occurred and process of learning-by-doing. Over the next several
was exacerbated by rising imports of standardised, decades, statistical efforts focused unsuccessfully on
mass-produced products from low-wage countries reducing the residual by rendering knowledge more
(Mytelka, 1987). tangible. Labour was thus, differentiated by skill level
Although the responses by economists to this crisis and industries classified by research and development
were primarily macroeconomic in character, the crisis (R&D) intensity.6 But the underlying assumptions—
of the 1970s also led to serious questioning of earlier concerning knowledge as a public good and innovation
approaches to the analysis of growth. In a 1981 sym- as a process that involved a direct and automatic link
posium on the consequences of new technologies for between research and development expenditures, inno-
economic growth, structural change and employment, vation, productivity gains and commercial success—
Christopher Freeman (1982, p. 1) pointed to the im- remained unchallenged. Empirical research, however,
portance that economic theorists such as Adam Smith, began to cast serious doubt on both the theoretical
Karl Marx and Joseph Schumpeter attached to inno- and practical usefulness of these linear “research to
vation as an engine of economic growth. But these in- competitiveness-in-the-market” models.
sights were not part of mainstream growth theory at At its simplest, the development of innovation stud-
that time—from the 1950s, the broad conception of in- ies as a field rests on a rejection of the neo-classical
novation as a process of technological and organisation growth model, a rejection of implicit neo-classical
change that these theorists shared had been supplanted ideas concerning knowledge, and a rejection of the lin-
by a narrower approach to technological change within ear model of innovation. Something that has attracted
a series of macroeconomic growth models. As Richard far less attention is the fact that much empirical in-
Nelson cogently argued, the models of the 1950s and novation research has also challenged the innovation
1960s clearly showed their limitations in dealing with ideas of Schumpeter. The development of the field
the paradox of productivity growth that became ap- could be argued to result primarily from two bodies
parent in the 1970s (Nelson, 1981) and the challenge of work. During the late 1970s and early 1980s, there
of competitiveness in the 1980s. This was partly be- emerged a well-articulated evolutionary critique of
cause of the static, allocative assumptions upon which neo-classicism, in the shape of Nelson and Winter’s
these models were based. But it was also the result Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change (1982).
of a dual view of “technology”, seen either as knowl- This provided a coherent micro-based alternative to
edge embodied in capital and intermediate goods, or the dominant neo-classical paradigm.
as exogenous knowledge creation, with knowledge it- Of equal importance, and over roughly the same
self seen as akin to information, and therefore a public time period, were a series of papers and books
good. by Nathan Rosenberg, that significantly shifted the
This simplification allowed technology to be assim- ground in the understanding of innovation, and that
ilated to any other good or service that could be bought have had a powerful albeit indirect effect on policy
and sold in a market. Information, on the other hand, thinking across countries. In Perspectives on Techno-
was regarded, as freely accessible and non-rival, in logy (1976) and Inside the Black Box: Technology and
the sense that many people could use that information Economics (1982), Rosenberg addressed an astonish-
at the same time without diminishing it. As a pub- ingly wide range of innovation issues. These included
lic good, its transfer was believed to be costless. On
the one hand, this provided a rationale for public pro- 5 Abramowitz (1971) found that barely half of the actual growth

vision or subsidy of research, since the public good in output could be explained by the growth of inputs in terms
characteristics of technological information implied a of capital and labour. The residual was classified as unexplained
total factor productivity.
market failure.4 On the other hand, in growth account- 6 For an excellent review of the earlier economic literature flow-
ing, knowledge, too intangible to be measured, formed ing from the initial work of Moses Abramowitz, see Nelson (1981).
In a more recent article Nelson has carried forward his critiques
4 The classic statement of this point was Arrow, (1962). to deal with the ‘new’ growth theorists (Nelson, 1998).
1472 L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479

a critique of neo-classical concepts of technology reconceptualised as a learning organisation embed-


and of Schumpeter’s invention-innovation-diffusion ded within a broader institutional context (Lundvall,
schema, a broad set of industry studies (woodwork- 1988). By focusing on the knowledge, learning and in-
ing, machine tools, aircraft, electronics, chemicals), teractivity among actors that gives rise to “systems of
important work on the economic role of science (and innovation” (Lundvall, 1992, 1995; Freeman, 1988),
its relation to technology), and some more or less the new innovation paradigm drew attention to the “na-
unique work on factors shaping the direction of spe- tional or local environments where organisational and
cific lines of technical advance. Throughout this work institutional developments have produced conditions
is the rejection of both neo-classical and Schum- conducive to the growth of interactive mechanisms on
peterian notions of linearity. For example, Rosenberg which innovation and the diffusion of technology are
stressed the importance of the fact that innovations, based” (OECD, 1992a, p. 238). The process of inno-
when introduced to the market, invariably require vation thus came to be seen as both path dependent,
major post-innovation improvements, and it is these locationally specific and institutionally shaped.7
that shape adoption. This undermines the distinction Among these diverse concepts, and from a policy
between innovation and diffusion, while positively perspective, the notion of the ‘national system of
emphasising the need for learning feedbacks between innovation’ has had by far the greatest impact, indeed
marketing, production and development as a basis an astonishing take-up. Despite the fact that the notion
for the wider process of innovation. This sustained of system had in fact been widely present in the work
research program deserves specific mention, because of innovation theorists such as Rosenberg, technology
it gave rise to a deceptively simple model of the historians such as Thomas Hughes, the regulation
innovation process that has had a powerful impact school in France, in technology systems analysis
on policy-makers—the so called ‘chain link’ model (Carlsson, 1995), the decisive “systems” impact on
(Kline and Rosenberg, 1986). Some of its applications policy thinking came via the work of Bengt-Ake
will be mentioned below. Lundvall (1992) and Richard Nelson (1993). The dif-
These pioneering contributions were followed by ference between these volumes can probably best be
a very substantial research programme and literature summed up in terms of two approaches to national
during the past 20 years. At the risk of oversimplify- systems, described by Lundvall himself. According
ing considerably, we could sum up some of the results to Lundvall a distinction can be made between a nar-
of this literature, and its policy conclusions, around its row and a broad definition of an innovation system
robust and generally accepted conclusions concerning respectively:
innovation and its effects. Framed by an evolution-
The narrow definition would include organisa-
ary economics perspective, rejecting all notions of
tions and institutions involved in searching and
optimal decision-making and hence optimality prop-
exploring—such as R&D departments, technologi-
erties in the economic system, non-linear models of
cal institutes and universities. The broad definition
the innovation process were developed. Based on the
. . . includes all parts and aspects of the economic
interactive effect between variables as opposed to
structure and the institutional set-up affecting
the impact that any single variable might have in ex-
learning as well as searching and exploring—the
plaining the process of innovation and diffusion, they
production system, the marketing system and the
involve feedback loops between: (i) research; (ii) the
system of finance present themselves as subsystems
existing body of scientific and technological knowl-
in which learning takes place.8
edge; (iii) the potential market; (iv) invention; and
(v) the various steps in the production process (Kline Nelson’s National Innovation Systems essentially
and Rosenberg, 1986; OECD, 1992a). These models followed the narrow definition. In National Systems
emphasised the uncertainties and unpredictable nature of Innovation, Lundvall and his collaborators focused
of the innovation process (Rosenberg, 1976, 1982)
and stressed the dynamic impact of innovation clus- 7 Although as Saxenian (1994) and Storper (1999) have argued,
ters as opposed to single innovations (Freeman and these localities are not restricted to national spaces.
Perez, 1988). Within these approaches, the firm was 8 Lundvall op. cit. 1992, p. 12.
L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479 1473

much more on a conceptual account of the charac- countries that emerged in the 1980s. Somewhat simi-
teristics and effects of learning. Their definition of a lar problems were associated with the new approaches
system was as follows: to industrial economics. These approaches introduced
far richer concepts of technology, and of the strate-
. . . a system of innovation is constituted by ele-
gic environments of firm decision-making. But they
ments and relationships which interact in the pro-
retained the notion of optimal decision-making by
duction, diffusion and use of new and economically
modelling within a game-theoretic context that re-
useful, knowledge . . . a national system encom-
placed optimal choice within well-defined choice sets
passes elements and relationships, either located
with selection of optimal strategies. Some of the key
within or rooted inside the borders of a national
elements that had emerged from empirical innovation
state.9
research, such as radical uncertainty, interactivity, and
In the Lundvall framework, innovation is conceptu- clustering issues, never made an appearance.
alised as learning, since innovation is—by definition—
novelty in the capabilities and knowledges which
make up technology. It sought to understand the nature 4. Linking innovation theory and innovation
and dynamics of learning via three basic concepts: policy: the emergence of new conceptual
the organised market, interactive learning, and the in- approaches to policy
stitutional framework. What this approach essentially
did was to place the empirical work on innovation During the 1980s and 1990s, the OECD, the Euro-
within a conceptual framework that enabled sympa- pean Commission and UN agencies are such as UNC-
thetic policy-makers to challenge (or simply ignore) TAD and ECLA took the new innovation paradigm
the neo-classical approach to economic and policy increasingly on board. In part, this involved such
analysis. organisations taking a wider perspective on the role
This is not to say that the economic mainstream of innovation policy, and in part it involved changed
was not changing. This period also saw the emergence conceptualisations of the nature of innovation and of
of the ‘new growth theory’ and the ‘new industrial appropriate policy instruments.
economics’. New growth theories have attempted to The process of change began in the 1970s as the
move away from the earlier linear perspective, to conventional views of the Brook’s report on Science,
endogenise the knowledge-creation process and to re- Growth and Society (OECD, 1971) were supplanted
lax neo-classical assumptions of perfect competition, by a new conceptualisation of the innovation process.
perfect information and identical levels of technology A key document in this process was Technical Change
(Verspagen, 1992; Romer, 1994). But a fundamental and Economic Policy (OECD, 1980), which was prob-
problem is that the conception of technology within ably the first major policy document to challenge the
these models remains very thin and stylised (Mytelka, macroeconomic interpretations of the 1970s crisis, and
1999, pp. 16–17). Such models did not deal well with to emphasise the role of technological factors in poten-
the uncertainties and dynamics that characterised tial solutions to the crisis. The group that produced this
changes in production and competition then underway; report was a high-powered one, and included a number
notably, the increasing knowledge-intensity of produc- of figures who were already central to the emerging
tion and the diffusion of innovation-based competition field of innovation studies, including Richard Nelson,
as markets liberalised around the globe. They proved Christopher Freeman and Keith Pavitt. The report
unable to incorporate, as the NSI notions did, a variety looked well beyond the specifics of the energy crisis
of ways of understanding the innovation process itself. of the 1970s, developing a critique of conventional
But while the new growth theories have yet to generate growth theory. It looked to the impacts of new tech-
useful guidelines for policy, they have made impor- nologies in ways that have themselves become part
tant contributions to academic debates about the role of the conventional wisdom in subsequent decades:
of innovation in the competitiveness of firms and of
. . . electronics is the major research-based sec-
9 Lundvall, op. cit. 1992, p. 2. tor which has maintained, and even increased its
1474 L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479

innovative vitality. The principal feature has been productivity slowdown with papers on technology and
innovation in the manufacture and design of elec- growth, radical innovations and paradigm shifts in
tronic components. The years from 1975/1976 on the growth process, networks and innovation, system
have seen what has come to be known as a “micro- effects and diffusion. Extensive indicator work within
electronic revolution”. . . . such radical innovations TEP included the Oslo Manual, which was explicitly
are bound to have pervasive effects in many sectors based on the Kline-Rosenberg model of innovation as
where improved methods of calculation, communi- its conceptual core, and which attempted to expand
cation, control and the storage and manipulation of the direct measure of innovation and of non-R&D
information are necessary or possible. The diffu- innovation inputs (OECD, 1992a; OECD, 1997).
sion of electronics throughout other manufacturing By far the clearest statement of the new approaches
and service industries will result in an economy in came, however, in the final report from TEP, Techno-
which one technology influences innovation almost logy and the Economy: The Key Relationships (OECD,
everywhere(OECD, 1980, p. 48). 1992b), a document piloted through OECD by Robert
Chabbal, Francois Chesnais, Lundvall, Paul David,
This process of analytical change led on to the Luc Soete and other economists in the evolutionary
Sundquist Report (OECD, 1988) which took the and institutional economics mode. This document also
need for an integrated overall approach to techno- opened up with the Kline-Rosenberg model as its ana-
logical, economic and social issues as its conclusion lytical framework (OECD, 1992b, p. 25). But it intro-
and stressed that technological change is a “social duced into the policy discussion a wide range of other
process, not an event, and should be viewed not in concepts from innovation studies—networking and
static, but in dynamic terms” (OECD, 1988, p. 11). clustering, strategic partnering, spillovers, the impor-
Such developments occurred within the Directorate tance of tacit knowledge. Less tangible in the report,
for Science Technology and Industry (DSTI) of the but of greater long-term significance in policy discus-
OECD. DSTI had been established in the early 1960s, sions, was the concept of national innovation systems,
and had had considerable success in promoting tech- derived from the recently published books by Lundvall
nology issues (for example, around the concept of and Nelson on this topic. “When the outcome of this
the ‘technology gap’), and in fostering the systematic programme was summed up in Montreal in 1991, the
collection of R&D data (in the late 1960s producing concept, National systems of Innovation, was given a
the “Frascati Manual” that became the basic standard prominent place in the conclusions” (Lundvall, 1992,
for R&D data collection within OECD countries). p. 5). The dramatic breakthrough represented by the
While the OECD’s Economics Department tended to TEP Report in the consideration it gives to linkages
be rather orthodox in its views, DSTI had a place for within national innovation systems (OECD, 1992a)
the heterodox, and such important figures in innova- was carried through in subsequent OECD policy stud-
tion studies as Christopher Freeman and Keith Pavitt ies such as the 1994 Jobs Study and the policy recom-
worked within it. mendations related to learning in the knowledge-based
This background within DSTI ultimately formed economy contained in its sequels, the 1996 Techno-
the basis for a 3-year work programme known as logy, Productivity and Job Creation report (OECD,
TEP (the Technology–Economy Programme) which 1996), and the 1998 Technology, Productivity and Job
ran from 1989 to 1992. The TEP programme was a Creation: Best Policy Practices. It has in fact become
loosely co-ordinated set of conferences, workshops, a core concept within policy discussion related to in-
and data development exercises, accompanied by a novation, both at the OECD, in the EU and to a lesser
rather vigorous process of report production. These extent in the technology and investment policy studies
had the effect of importing, for the first time, the at UNCTAD and the analyses of structural adjustment
new ideas circulating in the innovation studies en- policies and their impact on industry in Latin America
vironment, into OECD documents and publications. carried out at the United Nations Economic Commi-
For example, the major conference report Technology ssion for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC).
and Productivity (OECD, 1991) combined extensive By the last of the OECD studies mentioned above,
econometric and other quantitative analysis of the the transition away from a linear approach to growth
L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479 1475

and competitiveness based on the stimulation of re- (RTD) programmes were designed and implemented
search and development and its transfer to the produc- in the early 1980s when seminal works in innova-
tive sector was conceptually complete. The problem tion theory were only beginning to appear (Nelson
itself had been reformulation to include the distribu- and Winter, 1982; Dosi et al., 1988). With the in-
tional issues resulting from a process of innovation formation technology revolution already underway
and technological change and the nature of the solu- and evidence of Europe’s declining market share
tion was conceptually more holistic: accumulating, RTD programmes under the first and
second framework programmes were thus, designed
Today’s rapid technological change coupled with
more for competitiveness than for innovation. This in-
the restructuring underway in OECD economies
cluded well-known programmes such as the European
leads some to associate technology with unem-
Strategic Programme for Research and Development
ployment and social distress. However technology
on Information Technologies (ESPRIT) whose main
per se is not the culprit. Its economy-wide em-
goals were: (i) to promote intra-European industrial
ployment impact is likely to be positive provided
co-operation through pre-competitive R&D; (ii) to
that the mechanisms for translating technology into
thereby furnish European industry with the basic tech-
jobs are not impaired by deficiencies in training
nologies that it needed to bolster its competitiveness
and innovation systems and rigidities in product,
through the 1990s; and (iii) to develop European stan-
labour and financial markets . . . wide-ranging and
dards (Cadiou, 1996; Commission of the European
coherent policy reforms (will be needed) . . . to
Communities, 1987) and the Basic Research in Indus-
enhance the contribution of technology to growth,
trial Technologies (BRITE) programme, also aimed
productivity and jobs . . . innovation and technol-
at enhancing competitiveness.
ogy diffusion policies themselves continue to be
Well into the 1990s, Community RTD programmes,
too piecemeal, with insufficient consideration of
including the Community Programme in Education
the linkages within national innovation systems.
and Training for Technology (COMETT), the SPRINT
(OECD, 1998, p. 7).
Specific Projects Action Line which sought to pro-
Directly operational studies such as the OECD mote technology transfer across sectors and regions in
Science Policy Reviews, however, failed to make Europe, and the Value programme, set up to diffuse
the transition to an innovation focus. Designed “to the results of European RTD projects, were aimed at
produce a friendly but independent and critical as- achieving competitiveness by pumping up the supply
sessment of each country’s performance against an of research and technological skills and somewhat be-
international comparative yardstick, (in practice they) latedly by stimulating demand for these outputs.
concentrated mainly on the formal R&D system and But it was precisely within somewhat ’linear’ pro-
technical education” (Freeman, 1995, p. 12). But their grammes such as these, and SPRINT, within DG-XIII
legacy provided a learning experience for UNCTAD (now DG-Enterprise), that new approaches to con-
in the design of its Science, Technology and Inno- ceptualising innovation and hence re-conceptualising
vation Policy (STIP) Reviews (UNCTAD, 1999a,b). policy approaches emerged. SPRINT was aimed at
These latter studies were explicitly organised around innovation and technology transfer, but it also incor-
the national innovation systems concept. porated an analysis programme, the ’European Inno-
A similar, if slower, process of conceptual change vation Monitoring System’ (EIMS), which became
took place within the EU. Neither industrial policy a focus for innovation studies across a wide field of
nor research and development policy were among the applications. EIMS also became the initiator, together
areas covered in the 1967 Treaty of Rome. By the with Eurostat, of the ‘Community Innovation Survey’,
early 1980s, however, both had found a place among which was based on the conceptual and statistical
the European Commission’s directorates (Guzzetti, work initiated by the OECDs TEP programme—so
1995, pp. 1971–1983). Cumbersome rule-making pro- there was a also a general interplay between some of
cedures within the EU were responsible, in part, for the agencies that were open to the ideas of the new
this slowness. But it is also important to remember innovation theory. This programme is a good exam-
that the first research and technology development ple of a niche area in which heterodox approaches
1476 L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479

took root, supported and encouraged by small num- a major role in this transformation at both the design
bers of policy makers and administrators seeking stage and in undertaking the monitoring and evalua-
new approaches and tolerant of the complexities and tion that provided feedback into the policy process.
messiness of empirical innovation research. This kind of interactivity in a sense reflects the inter-
These EU programmes—and earlier initiatives such activity of the chain-link model, with feedbacks pro-
as the late 1980s to early 1990s programmes MON- viding a key dynamics to the overall process; once
ITOR (on evaluation) and FAST (on forecasting and again, this would suggest that innovative learning and
technology assessment) provided both research sup- policy learning have fruitful analogies, and cannot be
port and a meeting place for European innovation re- fully separated from one another.
searchers. As such, they played an important role in Such processes began to emerge onto a wider stage
the evolution of the field, both giving it intellectual over the 1990s. In the early 1990s, RTD issues be-
credibility and financial support that were crucial to gan to play a more significant role both in policy pro-
some research institutions. This process arguably can nouncements, and in the organisation of policy-related
be seen as an example of precisely the type of inter- research in the European Commission. With regard to
active and feedback-based learning modelled within the former, the Maastricht Treaty, for example, specif-
innovation theory itself. On the one hand there was ically mentioned the role of R&D policy in industrial
a supply of new ideas emanating from a vibrant but change, and regional cohesion; and this theme was re-
very small intellectual community. On the other there peated in the EU White Paper on Unemployment. Sta-
was a demand for policy solutions to growth and eq- tistical indicators collected by the OECD and the EU
uity issues at regional, national and European levels. were slowly developed or redesigned to give effect to
But most importantly, there were continuous feed- the insights flowing from innovation theory and the
back loops in the form of monitoring and evaluation Framework Programmes, the overall R&D programme
projects, analysis and development of the results of budget within which ‘packages’ dealing with the ma-
innovation survey data, and a continuous dialogue be- jor European-level scientific and technological RTD
tween research and policy-makers in regional authori- effort were organised, became one of the few growing
ties and relevant EU agencies. Continuous interaction areas.
and feedback had an important impact on both inno- With regard to the latter, a really major impulse
vation theory and the world of policy ideas. to the development of innovation research in support
But it was not until the focus shifted to regional de- of policy came with the ‘Targeted Socio-Economic
velopment policies that the kind of interactions that Research’ (TSER) programme in the fourth frame-
theory suggested were critical for innovation, became work programme (1995–1999), and the follow-up
more fully integrated into EU programmes. This was ‘Improving Human Potential’ programme in the fifth
reflected in the participatory methodologies used to framework programme. Here the initiatives lay with
capture inputs from the demand-side adopted in the policymakers and administrators. TSER was large,
new regional policies, particularly the set of regional carefully-designed and rather well-prepared by com-
innovation and technology transfer initiatives called mission staff who, in general, were well-informed
RTP, RITTS and RIS (Nauwelaers, 2000). These ac- and rather widely-read within the field. In effect, they
tions differed significantly from the more traditional took on board the new innovation theories, identified
RTD policies, from efforts to transfer technology to the gaps and weaknesses, and sought to research some
smaller firms and less-favoured regions and from ear- of the key unresolved problems. Projects emerged on
lier uses to which structural funds were put. To some a wide range of topics: these were usually multi-year
extent, therefore, the equity issue played the role of projects, with a wide range of partners across Europe,
a demand-side factor in pulling forward conceptual and were well-funded (for an overview of some key
change. Over time, and in parallel with the OECD, first-round projects, see Archibugi and Lundvall,
the problem was reformulated from competitiveness 2001). They included such topics as:
to innovation and equity, the inter-relatedness of poli-
cies was given greater consideration and the process • innovation in service industries;
itself became more interactive. Social scientists played • innovation systems and European integration;
L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479 1477

• new innovation statistics and data; of international organisations such as the OECD and
• S&T policies in transition countries; the European Commission, became the locus for ex-
• institutional restructuring in transition countries; ploratory thinking around the issue of technological
• public participation in environmental policy; change. Dissenting theorists slowly reformulated the
• modelling sustainable growth in Europe; problem as one of learning and innovation and contex-
• universities and technology transfer on the periph- tualised it in terms of innovation systems and institu-
ery of Europe; tions. Passage through international organisations then
• economic analysis of technology, economic integra- served to legitimise these concepts and to promote
tion and employment; them as focusing devices in national policy making.
• strategic analysis: policy intelligence and foresight; In this process, and despite their “outsider” status,
• regional innovation systems and policy; social scientists working within the new innovation
• multimedia and social learning. paradigm have been extraordinarily successful in
building a constituency for innovation systems ap-
This kind of wide-ranging support has continued, proaches and in the design and redesign of innovation
and has produced a very substantial change in the policies. By emphasising the contextually specific
character of innovation research in Europe (Bartzokas, nature of innovation processes, they brought theory
2001). Every significant institution working in the in- closer to policy, but have not entirely bridged the
novation field in Europe has participated, and virtually gap. Nor has the emphasis on a holistic and differ-
every significant researcher. The level of networking entiated approach implicit in the innovation system
and contact between researchers has multiplied dra- literature made the task of its use in the development
matically, as have the number of journals and the vol- of policy instruments any easier. Evolutionary the-
ume of publication. So these EU-backed projects have ory, for example, “would predict that different actors
provided a major dynamic impetus to innovation stud- would do different things. They would see opportu-
ies, as well as providing a practical level of support nities differently. They would rank differently those
without which some key institutions in the area might that all saw” (Nelson, 1996, p. 125). We would thus,
not have survived. This ought to be seen as a recipro- expect national governments to tailor new policy in-
cal movement out of the impact that innovation theo- struments to the particular habits and practices of ac-
rists had on policy in the 1980s and early 1990s; the tors whose behaviour policy is designed to influence.
EU programmes really represent and interactive mix Only where stakeholders at the regional level have
of concepts and policy approaches. been able to shape policies directly through participa-
tory processes are there small signs of movement in
this direction. For the most part, policy makers have
5. Co-evolution of theory and policy; the gaps been hard pressed to deal with the complex reality
that remain that innovation systems approaches represent.
The absence of a unified theory that relates
Innovation theories emerged in a period of dramatic innovation to growth and distribution and links
change. Expectations were diminishing after a sus- macro-approaches to the micro level has slowed the
tained period of post-war growth. Technological rup- application of innovation theory to policy areas be-
tures were underway but their impact on productivity yond the narrow confines of education or research and
was far from being felt. Imports from low-wage coun- technology development policy. Similarly, the lack of
tries were increasing and, coupled with new patterns new measurement tools has limited the translation of
of investment and organisational change, created fur- innovation theory into effective policy instruments.
ther economic dislocation as regions declined and un- This contrasts with the impact of Keynes’ theory
employment rose. Existing theory could not deal with which was reinforced by the concurrent development
these changes and the paradoxes to which they gave of national accounting statistics that made it possible
rise. While national governments in the developed to quantify the analytical categories of the General
world initially fell back upon neo-protectionist solu- Theory, to estimate empirically the functional rela-
tions and then embraced liberalisation, a small number tionships between them and to apply the theory to
1478 L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479

the resolution of policy problems (Patinkin, 1976). and advance, something which will require a clear
Concurrent developments to measure innovation have recognition of existing limits and weaknesses, and a
been undertaken in the 1990s. Paul David, Richard clear willingness to seek to overcome those limits.
Nelson, Begt-Ake Lundvall (who in fact made the
transition from researcher to deputy director of DSTI
in OECD between 1993 and 1995) and Luc Soete Acknowledgements
were among those who played a role in efforts at the
OECD and in the EU to build an empirical base for The authors would like to thank Ad Notten, Re-
the analysis of innovation. But these efforts have yet search Librarian at UNU/INTECH for the assistance
to provide the tools, for example, to test the OECD’s he provided in researching materials for this paper.
conceptually interesting hypothesis that a system’s An earlier version of this paper was presented to the
innovative capacity is related to the extensiveness DRUID ‘Nelson and Winter’ Conference, Aalborg,
and efficiency with which it distributes and absorbs 12–15 June 2001, we would like to thank partici-
knowledge (David and Foray, 1995).10 As this paper pants, particularly Pascal Petit and Anne Rickne, and
has shown, although innovation theory has made con- an anonymous referee for comments.
siderable conceptual inroads, there is still a way to go
before the links between innovation and other poli-
cies are well established and the ability to measure References
the results becomes a reality.
The story we have sought to tell here is itself an Abramowitz, M., 1971. Resource and output trends in the United
evolutionary one. Learning in this field has been in- States since 1870. In: Rosenberg, N. (Ed.), The Economics of
teractive, with a strong co-evolution of policy ideas Technological Change. Pelican, London, pp. 320–343.
Aglietta, M., 1976. Regulation et crise du capitalisme, Calmann
and theoretical and empirical studies of a new field.
Levy, Paris.
As with other processes of economic evolution, this Arrow, K.J., 1962. Economic welfare and the allocation of
has been problem driven, indeed crisis driven. Despite resources for invention. In: Nelson, R. (Ed.), The Rate and
the now-dissipated euphoria associated with the ‘new direction of Inventive Activity, The Economics of Technological
economy’ of recent years, the past three decades have Change. Pelican, Harmondsworth, 1974, pp. 164–181.
been a time of economic turbulence, with sustained Bartzokas, A., 2001. Policy relevance and theory development
in innovation studies. Enterprise and Innovation Management
problems of unemployment and productivity growth. Studies 2 (1), 1–18.
This has created a niche for new ideas, and the inter- Boyer, R., 1988. Technical change and the theory of regulation.
action of policy needs and intellectual endeavour has In: Dosi, G., et al. (Eds.), Technical Change and Economic
created a space in which the new field could grow. Theory, Pinter Publishers, United Kingdom, pp. 67–94.
Simultaneously, and probably for similar reasons, the Cadiou, J.M., 1996. Esprit, un premier bilan, Bulletin de Liaison
de la Recherche en informatique et automatique, No. 105.
mainstream of economics has declined, and that dis-
Carlsson, B. (Ed.), 1995. Technological Systems and Economic
cipline now faces its own crisis of declining student Performance: the Case of Factory Automation. Kluwer
numbers and diminished policy credibility. It is of Academic Publishers, Dordrecht.
course impossible to say how this situation will evolve. Commission of the European Communities, 1987. Esprit the Ernst
In our view, much will depend on the ability of inno- Phase, Progress and Results, Brussels.
vation studies to remain an area of intellectual vitality David, P., Foray, D., 1995. Accessing and Expanding the Science
and Technology Knowledge Base, STI Review, 16.
Dosi, G., Freeman, C., Nelson, R., Silverberg, G., Soete, L., 1988.
10 The tendency, therefore, has been to recreate linearity in formal Technical Change and Economic Theory. Pinter Publishers,
models and to rely on the indicators used by more conventional United Kingdom.
approaches. Thus, attempts to operationalise the distribution power ECLA, 1951. Problemas Teoricos y Practicos del Crecimiento
of innovation systems, i.e. “the proportion of knowledge ready Economico. UN Economic Commission for Latin America,
for distribution”, use output measures such as publications and Santiago.
patents, common to other approaches and measure the absorptive Freeman, C., 1982. Innovation as an Engine of Economic Growth.
capacities of firms, as elsewhere, by quantitative indicators such In: Giersch, H. (Ed.), Emerging Technologies: Consequences
as the amount of in-house R&D (in value or numbers of scientific for Economic Growth, Structural Change and Employment.
and technical employment) and the cost of technology licensing. J.C.B. Bohr, Tubingen, pp. 1–27.
L.K. Mytelka, K. Smith / Research Policy 31 (2002) 1467–1479 1479

Freeman, C., 1988. Japan: a new national system of innovation? OECD, 1971. Science, Growth and Society (Brooks Report).
In: Dosi, G., et al. (Eds.), Technical Change and Economic OECD, Paris.
Theory. Pinter Publishers, United Kingdom, pp. 330–348. OECD, 1980. Technical Change and Economic Policy. OECD,
Freeman, C., 1995. The national system of innovation in Paris.
historical perspective. Cambridge Journal of Economics 19 (1), OECD, 1988. New Technologies in the 1990s: A Socio-economic
5–24. Strategy (Sundqvist Report). OECD, Paris.
Freeman, C., Perez, C., 1988. Structural crises of adjustment: OECD, 1992a. Proposed Guidelines for Collecting and Interpreting
business cycles and investment behaviour. In: Dosi, G., Innovation Data (Oslo Manual). OECD, Paris.
et al. (Eds.), Technical Change and Economic Theory. Pinter OECD, 1992b. Technology and the Economy: The Key Rela-
Publishers, United Kingdom, pp. 38–66. tionships. OECD, Paris.
Guzzetti, L., 1995. A Brief History of European Union Research OECD, 1996. Technology, Productivity and Job Creation. OECD,
Policy, Science Research Development, Studies 5, October. Paris.
European Commission, Brussels. OECD, 1998. Technology, Productivity and Job Creation: Best
Hall, P., 1989. Conclusion: the politics of Keynesian ideas, Policy Practices. OECD, Paris.
in: Hall, P. (Ed.), The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Patinkin, D., 1976. Keynes and econometrics: on the interaction
Keynesianism Across Nations. Princeton University Press, between the macroeconomic revolutions of the inter-war period.
Princeton, pp. 361–392. Econometrica 44, 1091–1123.
Kline, S., Rosenberg, N., 1986. An overview of innovation. Piore, M.J., Sable, C., 1984. The Second Industrial Divide. Basic
In: Landau, R. (Ed.), The Positive Sum Strategy. Harnessing Books, New York.
Technology for Economic Growth, pp. 275–306. Redfield, R., 1950. Social science in our society. Phylon 11 (1),
Lundvall, B.-Å., 1988. Innovation as an interactive process: from 31–41.
user-producer interaction to the national system of innovation. Romer, P.M., 1994. The origins of endogenous growth. Journal of
In: Dosi, G., et al. (Eds.), Technical Change and Economic Economic Perspectives 8 (1), 3–22.
Theory. Pinter Publishers, United Kingdom, pp. 349–369. Rosenberg, N., 1976. The direction of technological change:
Lundvall, B.-Å. (Ed.), 1992. National Systems of Innovation. inducement mechanisms and focusing devices. In: Rosenberg,
Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning. Pinter N. (Ed.), Perspectives on Technology. Cambridge University
Publishers, London. Press, Cambridge, pp. 108–125.
Lundvall, B.-Å., 1995. The Social Dimension of the Learning Rosenberg, N., 1976. Perspectives on Technology. Cambridge
Economy, Danish Research Unit for Industrial Dynamics University Press, Cambridge.
Working Paper No. 96-1. Aalborg University, Denmark. Rosenberg, N., 1982. Inside the Black Box: Technology and
Mytelka, L.K., 1987. The evolution of knowledge production Economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
strategies within multinational firms. In: Caporaso, J. (Ed.), Said, E.W., 1996. Representations of the Intellectual. Vintage
A Changing International Division of Labour, International Books, New York.
Political Economy Yearbook, Vol. 1. Lynne Reiner, Boulder, Salant, W.S., 1989. The spread of Keynesian doctrines and
Colorado, pp. 43–70. practices in the United States. In: Hall, P. (Ed.), The Political
Mytelka, L. (Ed.), 1999. Competition, Innovation and Competi- Power of Economic Ideas Keynesianism Across Nations.
tiveness in Developing Countries. OECD Development Centre, Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp. 27–252.
Paris. Saxenian, A., 1994. Regional Advantage, Culture and Competition
Nauwelaers, C., 2000. Policy Learning for Innovation in Euro- in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Harvard University Press,
pean Regions paper prepared for RESTPOR 20000, 2–7, Cambridge, MA.
Kashikojima. Storper, M., 1999. The Regional World: Territorial Development
Nelson, R., 1981. Research on productivity growth and productivity in a Global Economy. The Guilford Press, New York.
differences: dead ends and new departures. Journal of Economic UNCTAD, 1964. Towards a New Trade Policy for Development.
Literature, XIX, September, 1029–1064. Report of the Secretary-General of the United Nations Con-
Nelson, R., 1993. National Innovation Systems. A Comparative ference on Trade and Development, United Nations, New York.
Analysis. Oxford University Press, NY. UNCTAD, 1999a. The Science, Technology and Innovation Policy
Nelson, R., 1996. The Sources of Economic Growth. Harvard Review: Colombia, UNCTAD, New York and Geneva.
University Press, Cambridge, MA. UNCTAD, 1999b. The Science, Technology and Innovation Policy
Nelson, R., Winter, S., 1977. In search of a Useful Theory of Review: Jamaica, UNCTAD, New York and Geneva.
Innovation, Research Policy, Summer, Vol. 6, pp. 36–76. Verspagen, B., 1992. Endogenous innovation in neo-classical
Nelson, R., Winter, S., 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic growth models: a survey. Journal of Macroeconomics 14 (4),
Change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. 631–662.

You might also like