You are on page 1of 16

10th Global Conference of Actuaries Shapes of Yield Curve: Principal Component Analysis & Vector Auto Regressive approach

By Subhash Chandra Abstract Most economists agree that two major factors affect the shape of the yield curve: investors expectations for future interest rates and certain risk premiums that investors require holding long-term bonds. Because the yield curve can reflect both investors expectations for interest rates and the impact of risk premiums for longer-term bonds, interpreting the yield curve can be complicated. Economists and fixed-income portfolio managers put great effort into trying to understand exactly what forces are driving yields at any given time and at any given point on the yield curve. The way in which these forces simultaneously work to shape the yield curve can be understood. The main objective of this paper is to throw some light on the shape and cause of shapes of yield using Principal Component Analysis. Three factors have been identified, which are almost 99% responsible for the change and shift in the shape of yield curve. A Vector Auto Regressive approach has been applied to those factors, which explains and estimates the shape of yield curve * . 1. Introduction Managing portfolios of financial instruments is in essence managing the tradeoff between risk and return. Optimization is a well suited and frequently used tool to manage this tradeoff. Financial risks arise due to the stochastic nature of some underlying market parameters such as interest rates. So, it is necessary to include stochastic parameters in optimization for portfolio managing, turning portfolio optimization in to stochastic optimization or stochastic programming. A vital part of stochastic programming in portfolio management is scenario generation. Monetary policy makers and observers pay special attention to the shape of the yield curve as an indicator of the impact of current and future monetary policy on the economy. However, drawing inferences from the yield curve is much like reading tea leaves if one does not have the proper tools for yield-curve analysis. The objective is therefore to construct a model capable of capturing the interest rates in order to generate interest rate scenarios. 1.1 What is yield? Yield refers to the annual return on an investment. The yield on a bond is based on both the purchase price of the bond and the interest, or coupon, payments received. There are two ways of looking at bond yields: current yield and yield to maturity.

Current yield is the annual return earned on the price paid for a bond. It is calculated by dividing the bond's annual coupon interest payments by its purchase price. For example, if an investor bought a bond with a coupon rate of 6% at par, and full face value of Rs.1,000, the interest payment over a year would be Rs.60. That would produce a current yield of 6%. When a bond is purchased at full face value, the current yield is the same as the coupon rate. However, if the same bond were purchased at less than face value, or at a discount price, of Rs.900, the current yield would be higher at 6.6%). Yield to maturity reflects the total return an investor receives by holding the bond until it matures. A bonds yield to maturity reflects all of the interest payments from the time of

* It is important to emphasise that the purpose of the model is not to produce superior yield curve predictions, i.e. predictions that in any sense are assumed to out-perform the market and thereby may serve as a basis for tactical investment decisions aimed at outperforming a given benchmark strategy. Rather it is a tool, which supports the investment process related to strategic asset allocation decisions.

270

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


purchase until maturity, including interest on interest. Equally important, it also includes any appreciation or depreciation in the price of the bond. Yield to call is calculated the same way as yield to maturity, but assumes that a bond will be called, or repurchased by the issuer before its maturity date, and that the investor will be paid face value on the call date. Because yield to maturity (or yield to call) reflects the total return on a bond from purchase to maturity (or the call date), it is generally more meaningful for investors than current yield. By examining yields to maturity, investors can compare bonds with varying characteristics, such as different maturities, coupon rates or credit quality. 1.2 What is yield curve? The simplest Fig.1 Yield Curve kind of bond is called a zerocoupon 9.0% bond. A zero-coupon bond (also known as a discount bond) makes a 8.5% single payment on its maturity date. By contrast, a coupon bond makes periodic 8.0% interest payments (called coupon payments) prior to its maturity when it 7.5% 30-Mar-2007 also makes a final payment that 28-Sep-2007 represents repayment of principal. A 7.0% coupon bond may be thought as a 10 15 20 25 30 of 0 5 portfolio of zero-coupon bonds. The yield Maturity (Yr.) curve is a line graph that plots the relationship between yields to maturity and time to maturity for bonds of the same asset class and credit quality. The line begins with the spot interest rate, which is the rate for the shortest maturity, and extends out in time, say, to 30 years. Investors use the yield curve as a reference point for forecasting interest rates, pricing bonds and creating strategies for boosting total returns. The yield curve has also become a reliable leading indicator of economic activity. Fig.1 shows two yield curves for two different dates. 1.3 Various shapes of yield curve? Yield curves can have various characteristics depending on economic circumstances at a given point in time. An upward sloping curve with increasing but marginally diminishing increases in the level of rates, for increasing maturities, is commonly referred to as a normal shaped yield curve. The reason for this naming is due to the fact that this is the shape of a yield curve considered to be normal for economically balanced conditions. Other types of yield curves include a flat yield curve where the yields are constant for all maturities. A humped shaped yield curve has short and long term yields of almost equal magnitude, different from Fig.2: Various shapes of Yield Curve the medium term yields which are consequently either higher or lower. An 8.5 inverted yield curve is converted invert normal shaped curve, i.e., a downward 8.0 sloping yield curve with decreasing but marginally diminishing decreases in yields. In Inverted 7.5 Fig.2 all four types of yield curve have been Humped Normal shown as an example.
Yield (%) Flat 7.0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 Maturity (Yr.)

1.4 What determines the shape of yield curve? Most economists agree that two major factors affect the slope of the yield curve: investors expectations for future interest rates and certain risk premiums that investors require holding long-term bonds. 271

Yield

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


Three widely followed theories have evolved that attempt to explain these factors in detail: The Pure Expectations Theory holds that the slope of the yield curve reflects only investors expectations for future short-term interest rates. Much of the time, investors expect interest rates to rise in the future, which accounts for the usual upward slope of the yield curve. The Liquidity Preference Theory, an offshoot of the Pure Expectations Theory, asserts that long-term interest rates not only reflect investors assumptions about future interest rates but also include a premium for holding long-term bonds, called the term premium or the liquidity premium. This premium compensates investors for the added risk of having their money tied up for a longer period, including the greater price uncertainty. Because of the term premium, long-term bond yields tend to be higher than short-term yields, and the yield curve slopes upward. Another variation on the Pure Expectations Theory, the Preferred Habitat Theory states that in addition to interest rate expectations, investors have distinct investment horizons and require a meaningful premium to buy bonds with maturities outside their preferred maturity, or habitat. Proponents of this theory believe that short-term investors are more prevalent in the fixed-income market and therefore, longer-term rates tend to be higher than short-term rates.

Because the yield curve can reflect both investors expectations for interest rates and the impact of risk premiums for longer-term bonds, interpreting the yield curve can be complicated. Economists and fixed-income portfolio managers put great effort into trying to understand exactly what forces are driving yields at any given time and at any given point on the yield curve. 2. Available Data Historical data for Indian G-security returns has been taken for all the analysis. Time period chosen is from January 2001 to December 2007. Though daily data was available but here weekly observation has been taken because of non availability of rates for some of the maturity years. Also, data was not available for all the maturity years from January 2001. Some adjustment has been done in F ig.2.1: S hort, Medium & L ong term Y ield that C urve respect. 12 15yL ongTerm Some proxy 4yMediumTerm
10

Y ield (% )

1yS hortTerm

8 6 4 2 J a n01 A pr01 J ul01 O ct01 J a n02 A pr02 J ul02 O ct02 J a n03 A pr03 J ul03 O ct03 J a n04 A pr04 J ul04 O ct04 J a n05 A pr05 J ul05 O ct05 J a n06 A pr06 J ul06 O ct06 J a n07 A pr07 J ul07 O ct07

Dates
observations have been taken. As for example, say, for 3 year maturity observation for one 21st February 2001 is not available. So, as a proxy, observation from nearest maturity year rate has been taken. The data set covers 363 dates with 1 year to 15 year maturity. Because of 272

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


unavailability of observations for more than 15 year maturity rates, the highest maturity year taken is 15 year. However, the same analysis can be done for higher maturity years too provided data is available. Fig.2.1 displays the yield to maturity for three of the maturity years, viz. 1 year, 4 year and 15 year. In terms of maturities, 1 year maturity rate has been considered as Short-term rate, 4 year maturity as Medium-term and 15 year as Long-term rate. It can be observed that movements of the rates on various dates are most same for the three types of yield to maturity with some differences. 3. Factors, which decides the Shape of Yield Curve 3.1 Level, Slope & Curvature- Researchers in finance have studied the yield curve statistically and have found that shifts or changes in the shape of the yield curve are attributable to a few unobservable. Specifically, empirical studies Fig.3: Effect of Level Factor reveal that more than 95% of the 9.0 movements of various bond yields are captured by three factors, which are often 8.5 called "level," "slope," and "curvature". The names describe how the yield curve shifts or 8.0 changes shape in response to a shock. As an example, Fig.3 illustrates the influence of a Normal 7.5 shock to the "level" factor on the yield curve. Level Factor The solid line is the original yield curve, and 7.0 the dashed line is the yield curve after the 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 shock. A "level" shock changes the interest Maturity (Yr.) rates of all maturities by almost identical amounts, inducing a parallel shift that changes the level of the whole yield curve. Fig.4 shows the influence of the "slope" factor on yield curve. The shock to the "slope" factor increases short-term interest rates by much larger amounts than the long-term interest rates, so that the yield curve becomes less steep and its slope decreases. Fig.5 shows the response of the yield curve to a shock to the "curvature" factor. The main Fig.4: Effect of Slop Factor effects of the shock focus on medium9.0 term interest rates, and consequently the yield curve becomes 8.5 more "hump-shaped" than before. Various models have been developed 8.0 and estimated to characterize the Normal movement of these 7.5 Slop Factor unobservable factors and thereby that of the yield curve by financial 7.0 economists and bond traders in asset0 5 10 15 20 25 30 pricing exercises. Few of these models, Maturity (Yr.) however, provide any insight about what these factors are, about the identification of Fig.5: Effect of Curvature Factor the underlying forces that drive their 9.0 movements, or about their responses to macroeconomic variables.
Yield (%)

8.5 Yield (%) 8.0 7.5 7.0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 Maturity (Yr.)


Normal Curvature Factor

Yield (%)

273

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


3.2 Identifying the factors- The aim of factor analysis is, as said before, to account for the variance of observed data in terms of much smaller number of variables or factors. To perform the factor analysis i.e. to recognize the factors we apply a related method called principal component analysis (PCA). The PCA is simply a way to re-express a set of variables, possibly resulting in more convenient representation. PCA is essentially an orthogonal linear transformation of n individuals sets of p observed variables; xij , i = 1, 2, . . . , n and j = 1, 2, . . . , p, into an equal number of new sets of variables; yij = y1, y2, . . . , yp along with coefficients aij , where i and j are indexes for n and p respectively. In this paper the historical yield curves are the n individual sets, containing p variables of different maturities each. Note the following relationships: Each y is a linear combination of the xs i.e. yi = ai1x1+ai2x2+ +aipxp The sum of the squares of the coefficients aij is unity. Of all possible linear combinations uncorrelated with y1, y2 has the greatest variance. Similarly y3 has the greatest variance of all linear combinations of xi uncorrelated with y1 and y2, etc. The new combinations yi express the variances in a decreasing order so consequently the PCA can be used to recognize the most significant factors i.e. the factors describing the highest ratios of the variance. The method is perfectly general and the only assumption necessary to make is that the variables which the PCA is applied on are relevant to the analysis being conducted. Furthermore it should be noticed that the PCA use no underlying model and henceforth it is not possible to test any hypothesis about the outcome. Principal Component Method has been implemented on data set of various time periods (as mentioned in section 2) in order to recognize the key factors for Indian Yield curve. In Table1, eigen values (when time period selected was 2001-2005) along with

Table1:
Eigenvalue % of Var. Cum. %

PC 1 PC 2 PC 3 28.807 0.264 0.198 98.076 0.898 0.673 98.076 98.974 99.647

PC 4 0.042 0.144 99.791

PC 5 0.018 0.061 99.853

PC 6 0.009 0.032 99.885

PC 7 PC 8 0.007 0.007 0.025 0.025 99.910 99.934

percentage of explanation are shown. Cumulative percentage is also included in Table1. It can be noticed that PC1 (factor1) alone is able to explain more than 98% variation and all the three factors together are explaining 99.6% variations. Annexure A1.1 illustrates

Table2: Coefficients
(2001-2005) PC 1 1yr 0.275 2yr 0.226 3yr 0.223 4yr 0.228 5yr 0.234 6yr 0.243 7yr 0.248 PC 2 -0.714 0.088 0.236 0.321 0.313 0.270 0.195 PC 3 -0.545 -0.356 -0.308 -0.233 -0.196 -0.118 -0.049

274

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


such eigen values, individual cumulative explanation periods selected. It has been time period case and 2001factor alone is able to explain shock in all rest of the except 2001-2007 time period cases, three factors together variation. 8yr 9yr 10yr 11yr 12yr 13yr 14yr 15yr 0.267 0.264 0.271 0.271 0.273 0.283 0.279 0.276 0.061 0.030 -0.268 0.035 -0.046 -0.156 -0.079 -0.070 0.085 0.162 0.123 0.215 0.138 0.248 0.300 0.328 variation explanation and percentage for various time noted that except for 2001 2007 time period case, first almost 98% variation due to a maturity year rates. However, case, in all other time period are explaining more than 99%

In Table 2, coefficient of first three most significant factors, when time period chosen was 20012005 have been shown. Column heading in the table are the three most significant factors, whereas row heading are various maturity year. Values inside Table 2 are coefficient of factors, which explain variation in the respective row headings yield. As for example, in case when there is a shock on rates then for 10th row (10yr), PC1 (loading factor1) makes 0.271% variations in 10year bond rate due to the shock; PC2 (loading factor2) explains -0.268% variations in 10year bond rate due to the shock; & PC3 (loading factor3) explains 0.123% variations in 10year bond rate due to the shock. Fig.6 is an example for one particular set of time period (2001-2005). Annexure A1.2 illustrates the plots of first three loading factors for various time periods. It has been observed that first factor (PC1) is almost constant for all the maturity years. However, 2nd factor and 3rd factor are varying with various shapes. Fig.6 shows the three factor loadings corresponding to the three largest principal components in Table 2. The loadings we recognize as the shift, steepness and convexity factors identified by Litterman & Scheinkman. From looking at Fig.6 it can be observed that the first factor forms almost a horizontal line over the whole time period, excluding approximately the first two years. This corresponds to a change of slope for the first two years and a parallel shift for the rest of the maturity horizon. The horizontal line is dominant for the rest of the term structure and hence the factor is recognized as the level factor. The second factor can be interpreted F ig . 6: T hree Mos t S ig nific ant P rinc ipal C omponent as the curvature factor since positive F ac tors (Weekly: J an2001-D ec 2005) F actor1 changes in it cause a decrease in yield 1.0 F actor2 0.8 for bonds with short and long F cator3 0.6 maturities but cause an increase in 0.4 0.2 yield for medium length maturities. 0.0 The third factor is the slope, which 0.2 corresponds to a change of the slope 0.4 0.6 for the whole term structure accounts 0.8 for 0.673% of the total variation. It 1.0 can be seen from the plot that the slope is decreasing as a function of Ma turity maturity which fits the description of a normal yield curve. This is in accordance to the fact that the yield curve the period investigated was for most parts a normal yield cure with marginally diminishing yields.
F ac tor L oading 10yr 11yr 12yr 13yr 14yr

3.3 Effect of Factors on Rates- A unit change of the ith factor causes a change ajt for each maturity t-year rate. Since the factors are independent of each other we may therefore express the total change of the random variable, rt, by

rt = a jt f j
j =1

Where fj is jth factor, k is the number of factors; ajt is the coefficient, identified by the eigenvector analysis, used to approximate the variance of the portfolio. As an example lets see what effect a unit change (_f1 = 1) of the level factor (j = 1) has on the ten year rate (t = 10). From Table2, we have a1,10 = 0.271. so a unit change in factor 1 causes 0.271 275

15yr

1yr

2yr

3yr

4yr

5yr

6yr

7yr

8yr

9yr

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


change in the ten year rate, which means that if the ten year rate is 5% a unit change in the level factor causes it to become 5.271%. In the same manner a unit changes of three most significance factors ( f 1 = 1) for j = (1, 2, 3), again for ten years means:

r10 = a j10 f j = 0.271 0.268 + 0.123 = 0.126


j =1

Meaning that a 5% ten year rates would become 5.126% if a unit change occurred for all the factors. 4. Choosing the Factors for VAR model The main result from the factor analysis (Principal Component Analysis) was that three factors were to be used to construct the model. But how are the factors recognized in the VAR model? There are two methods for selecting the factors. The 1st method is a naive approach and the 2nd is butterfly method suggested by Christiansen & Lund (2007). The former method is based on taking three positions of the yield curve, a short, medium and long term maturity. The short term rate can be chosen as a proxy for the level factor, the curvature can be chosen as the difference between two yields, a medium maturity yield minus the sort maturity yield. And finally the slope is chosen as two times the medium rate minus the long and short rate. If we note short, medium and long maturity as ys, ym and yl, respectively then the factors can be denoted in the following way level = ys curvature = yl ys slope = 2 ym (ys yl) where we choose the short rate to be the 1 year rate, the medium to be the 4 year and the long to be the 15 year rate (can vary with respect to available data). The 2nd method, butterfly method, is a bit different from nave method. The main difference is that in butterfly approach slope of the yield curve can be chosen differently, namely by using the mechanism of the so called butterfly spread. A butterfly spread is a portfolio which consists of a long position in an intermediate maturity bond (the body of the butterfly) and two short positions of bonds whose maturities straddle the first bond (the wings of the butterfly). Figure below shows a digram of how a butterfly spread looks for a concave (normal) yield curve and the spread s, is given as s = ym (w1*ys + (1 w2)*yl) where the weights w1 and w2 are chosen such that w1ys = w2yl. An example of how the weights are chosen if the maturities are 1, 4 and 15 years would be w1 = (4 1)/(15 1) = 3/14 and weight 2 would become w2 = (154)/(151) = 11/14. The spread shown in the figure is positive and the more concave the yield curve becomes the more positive the spread gets and vice versa. This applies for both normal and inverted yield curves. Equivalently, a negative butterfly spread indicates a convex yield curve.

276

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


By the latter method the level is chosen in the same way as before, by taking the short rate as a proxy, but the curvature is determined differently compared to the former method. The curvature in the latter method is chosen to be the difference between the long and short rate in stead of the difference between the medium and short rate before. That is done in order to keep the correlation between the curvature and the approximation of the slope at a reasonable level, according to Christiansen & Lund (2007). Using the same notation as for the former method level = ys curvature = yl ys slope = ym (w1*ys + (ws)* yl). 5. VAR Model 5.1 Defining- A pth order vector auto regression VAR(p) process can be expressed as

Yt = C + A1Yt 1 + A2Yt 2 + A3Yt 3 + ... + A p Yt p + t


where Yt is an (n 1) vector of time series of random variables, C is an (n 1) vector of constants,

A j is an (n n) matrix of autoregressive coefficients for j = (1, 2, . . . , p) and t is a vector


generalization of Gaussian white noise. Since we intend to formulate a three factor VAR process, we give an example of such a process.

y1,t = c1 + a11 y1,t 1 + a12 y1,t 2 + a13 y1,t 3 + 1,t y 2,t = c 2 + a 21 y 2,t 1 + a 22 y 2,t 2 + a 23 y 2,t 3 + 2,t y 3,t = c3 + a31 y 3,t 1 + a32 y13t 2 + a33 y 3,t 3 + 3,t
In this paper, 2nd method has been applied to select proxy of three factors as described in section 4. Proxy for Factor 1 (level): ys = 1-yr maturity rate Proxy for Factor 2 (curvature): ym = 15-yr maturity rate minus 1-yr maturity rate Proxy for Factor 3 (slope): yl = 4-yr maturity rate minus [ 5.2 Stationary Check For all the three proxies, it has been tested whether they are stationary. It has been found that none of the three proxies are stationary. However, all the three proxies are stationary at their respective 1st difference. A 1st difference for a series, say yt is defined as y t = y t y t 1 . EViews package ahs been used to test the stationarity of the series. Augmented Dicky Fuller (ADF) test has been applied to individual series to test stationarity. Stationary has been decided on the basis of Schwartz Criteria. In Annexure A2, all the stationarity test results have been shown. In Annexure A2.1, it can be seen that neither Level, nor Curvature nor Slope is stationary. For stationary series ADF Test Statistic should be less than critical value. Only proxy for Factor 1 is stationary at 10% level of significance. Annexure A2.2 displays ADF test for 1st order difference series. All the 1st difference series are stationary at all level of significance. Estimation of parameters of VAR model will be done on the basis of these 1st order difference series. 277

3 11 *(1-yr maturity rate) + * (15-yr maturity rate)] 14 14

10th Global Conference of Actuaries

5.3 Lag Selection and Criteria For VAR modeling, how many lags are appropriate needs to be identified. EViews package provides facility to identify the lag selection for VAR modeling. Selection of lag has been performed using Schwartz Criteria. 5.4 Estimation of parameters Using three series identified above viz. ( Level ) t , (Curvature) t , ( Slope) t a VAR model has been set up in EViews and the parameter values have been estimated. The results can be seen in Annexure A3. The final equation of the estimation comes out to be as below VAR MODEL: Substituted Coefficient D_CURV = - 0.16766*D_CURV(-1) + 0.10757*D_LEVEL(-1) - 0.131497*D_SLOPE(-1) +0.00167 D_LEVEL = 0.33085*D_CURV(-1) + 0.0974*D_LEVEL(-1) + 0.32341*D_SLOPE(-1) - 0.004674 D_SLOPE =- 0.09689*D_CURV(-1) - 0.07455*D_LEVEL(-1) - 0.16468*D_SLOPE(-1) + 0.000699 In the above table shown, D_LEVEL represents ( Level ) t , D_CURV represents (Curvature) t & D_SLOPE represents ( Slope) t . From these three equations one can identify the equations for actual series very easily. Since above VAR is of order 1, for actual series of factors VAR is of order 2. The actual series, LEVEL (which was representing Factor 1 of our PCA), CURVATURE (which was representing Factor 2 of our PCA) and SLOPE (which was representing Factor 3 of our PCA) can be found from which one can identify the change in rates using equation given section 3.3. 6. Conclusion Using PCA, one can identify the factors which are responsible for changes in yield curve. Modeling VAR is one of the ways to project the future values so that yield to maturity rates can be understood better. Analyzing the VAR process reveled that a process with lag 2 was suitable for modeling the rates, based on the results of information criteria. Investigating the stability of the VAR (2) process reviled that it was stable for the time frame of interest, but using all the data was not necessarily better. Finally, one can apply Vector Error Correction Model (VECM) to take care the shortfall of VAR model. However, along with this other modeling process can also be applied, like ARCH, GARCH or Regime-Switching models. In these ways, investors can prepare their tools, which support the investment process related to strategic asset allocation decisions Bibliography 1. Blaskowitz, O. & Herwartz, H. (2005), Modeling the FIBOR/EURIBOR Swap Term Structure: An Empirical Approach 2. Christiansen, C. & Lund, J. (2007), Revisiting the shape of the yield curve: The effect of interest rate volatility; Working paper 3. Einarsson, A. (2007) Stochastic Scenario Generation for the Term Structure of Interest Rates

278

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


4. Litterman, R. & Scheinkman, J. (1991), Common factors affecting bond returns, The Journal of Fixed income Annexure A1 A1.1 Explained Variance in terms of Eigen Values and Cumulative Probabilities

2001
PC 1 Eigen value 10.755 % of Var. 95.798 Cum. % 95.798 PC 2 0.362 3.226 99.024 PC 3 0.066 0.584 99.608

2001-2002
PC 1 Eigen value 23.734 % of Var. 97.863 Cum. % 97.863 PC 2 0.398 1.641 99.504 PC 3 0.048 0.197 99.701

2001-2004 2001-2003 PC 1 PC 2 Eigen value 37.834 0.310 % of Var. 98.848 0.811 Cum. % 98.848 99.659 PC 3 0.054 0.141 99.800 PC 1 Eigen value 35.947 % of Var. 98.573 Cum. % 98.573 PC 2 0.243 0.665 99.239 PC 3 0.176 0.482 99.721

Eigen value % of Var. Cum. %

2001-2005 PC 1 PC 2 28.807 0.264 98.076 0.898 98.076 98.974

PC 3 0.198 0.673 99.647

Eigen value % of Var. Cum. %

2001-2006 PC 1 PC 2 24.712 0.255 97.413 1.007 97.413 98.420

PC 3 0.206 0.811 99.231

Eigen value % of Var. Cum. %

2001-2007 PC 1 PC 2 22.088 0.331 96.478 1.444 96.478 97.921

PC 3 0.196 0.858 98.779

279

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


A1.2 Charts of Factor Loadings
T hree Mos t S ig nific ant P rinc ipal C omponent F ac tors (Weekly: J an2001-D ec 2001)
1.0 0.8 0.6 F ac to r L o ad in g 0.4 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1y r 2y r 3y r 4y r 5y r 6y r 7y r 8y r 9y r 10y r 11y r 12y r 13y r 14y r 15y r 1.0

T hree Mos t S ig nific ant P rinc ipal C omponent F ac tors (Weekly: J an2001-D ec 2002)
F acotr1 F actor2 F actor3
F ac to r L o ad in g 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1y r 2y r 3y r 4y r 5y r 6y r 7y r 8y r 9y r 10y r 11y r 12y r 13y r 14y r
14y r
15yr

F actor1 F actor2 F actor3

Ma turity

Ma turity

T hree Mos t S ig nific ant P rinc ipal C omponent F ac tors (Weekly: J an2001-D ec 2003)
1. 0 0. 8 0. 6 F ac tor L oading 0. 4 0. 2 0. 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 10yr 11yr 12yr 13yr 14yr 15yr 1yr 2yr 3yr 4yr 5yr 6yr 7yr 8yr 9yr

T hree Mos t S ig nific ant P rinc ipal C omponent F ac tors (Weekly: J an2001-D ec 2004)
1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1yr 2yr 3yr 4yr 5yr 6yr 7yr 8yr 9yr 10yr 11yr 12yr 13yr

F actor1 F actor2 F actor3


F ac tor L oadin g

F actor1 F actor2 F actor3

Ma turity

Ma turity

T hree Mos t S ig nific ant P rinc ipal C omponent F ac tors (Weekly: J an2001-D ec 2005)
1. 0 0. 8 0. 6 0. 4 0. 2 0. 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 10y r 11y r 12y r 13y r 1y r 2y r 3y r 4y r 5y r 6y r 7y r 8y r 9y r

T hree Mos t S ig nific ant P rinc ipal C omponent F ac tors (Weekly: J an2001-D ec 2006)

14yr

F actor1 F actor2 F cator3


F ac to r L o ad in g

1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 10y r 11y r 12y r 13y r

F cator1 F actor2 F actor3

F ac to r L o ad in g

14y r

15y r

Ma turity

Ma turity

T hree Mos t S ig nific ant P rinc ipal C omponent F ac tors (Weekly: J an2001-D ec 2007)
1. 0 0. 8 F ac tor L oading 0. 6 0. 4 0. 2 0. 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1yr 2yr 3yr 4yr 5yr 6yr 7yr 8yr 9yr 10yr 11yr 12yr 13yr 14yr 15yr

F actor1 F actor2 F cator3

Ma turity

280

15y r

1y r

2y r

3y r

4y r

5y r

6y r

7y r

8y r

9y r

15y r

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


Annexure A2. A2.1 ADF Test for Level ADF Test Statistic -2.581681 1% Critical Value* -3.4506 5% Critical Value -2.8698 10% Critical Value -2.5712

*MacKinnon critical values for rejection of hypothesis of a unit root. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(LEVEL) Method: Least Squares Sample(adjusted): 2/05/2001 12/10/2007 Included observations: 358 after adjusting endpoints Variable LEVEL(-1) D(LEVEL(-1)) D(LEVEL(-2)) D(LEVEL(-3)) D(LEVEL(-4)) C R-squared Coefficient Std. Error -0.020808 -0.211934 -0.074128 -0.038336 0.040937 0.128036 0.065358 0.008060 0.052684 0.053825 0.053841 0.052700 0.054108 t-Statistic -2.581681 -4.022744 -1.377192 -0.712019 0.776787 2.366308 Prob. 0.0102 0.0001 0.1693 0.4769 0.4378 0.0185

Adjusted R-squared 0.052082 S.E. of regression 0.199656 Sum squared resid 14.03161

Log likelihood 71.84038 Durbin-Watson stat 1.993118

Mean dependent var 0.006927 S.D. dependent var 0.205068 Akaike info criterion 0.367823 Schwarz criterion 0.302787 F-statistic 4.922943 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000228

ADF Test Statistic

ADF Test for Curvature -2.920391 1% Critical Value* -3.4515 5% Critical Value -2.8702 10% Critical Value -2.5714

*MacKinnon critical values for rejection of hypothesis of a unit root. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(CURVATURE) Method: Least Squares Sample(adjusted): 2/05/2001 12/10/2007 Included observations: 340 Excluded observations: 18 after adjusting endpoints Variable CURVATURE(-1) D(CURVATURE(-1)) D(CURVATURE(-2)) D(CURVATURE(-3)) D(CURVATURE(-4)) C R-squared Coefficient Std. Error -0.067345 -0.228114 -0.026011 -0.038929 0.067013 0.065308 0.099348 281 0.023060 0.056247 0.057706 0.057717 0.055527 0.024741 t-Statistic -2.920391 -4.055587 -0.450749 -0.674481 1.206842 2.639645 Prob. 0.0037 0.0001 0.6525 0.5005 0.2283 0.0087

Mean dependent var -

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


0.000500 S.D. dependent var 0.199060 Akaike info criterion 0.462710 Schwarz criterion 0.395140 F-statistic 7.368478 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000001

Adjusted R-squared 0.085865 S.E. of regression 0.190322 Sum squared resid 12.09829

Log likelihood 84.66070 Durbin-Watson stat 1.983061

ADF Test Statistic

ADF Test for Slope -1.835333 1% Critical Value* -3.4506 5% Critical Value -2.8698 10% Critical Value -2.5712

*MacKinnon critical values for rejection of hypothesis of a unit root. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(SLOPE) Method: Least Squares Sample(adjusted): 2/05/2001 12/10/2007 Included observations: 358 after adjusting endpoints Variable SLOPE(-1) D(SLOPE(-1)) D(SLOPE(-2)) D(SLOPE(-3)) D(SLOPE(-4)) C Coefficient Std. Error -0.023005 -0.109507 0.077878 -0.025472 -0.035834 -0.012021 0.012535 0.053465 0.053713 0.053808 0.053496 0.009604 t-Statistic -1.835333 -2.048201 1.449882 -0.473396 -0.669849 -1.251693 Prob. 0.0673 0.0413 0.1480 0.6362 0.5034 0.2115

R-squared 0.034313 Adjusted R-squared 0.020596 S.E. of regression 0.099197 Sum squared resid 3.463671

Log likelihood 322.2585 Durbin-Watson stat 1.985449 A2.2

Mean dependent var 0.002431 S.D. dependent var 0.100234 Akaike info criterion 1.766807 Schwarz criterion 1.701770 F-statistic 2.501477 Prob(F-statistic) 0.030385

ADF Test of 1st Order Difference of Level ADF Test Statistic -8.788308 1% Critical Value* -3.4506 5% Critical Value -2.8698 10% Critical Value -2.5712

*MacKinnon critical values for rejection of hypothesis of a unit root. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(D_LEVEL) Method: Least Squares Sample(adjusted): 2/12/2001 12/10/2007 Included observations: 357 after adjusting endpoints Variable D_LEVEL(-1) Coefficient Std. Error -1.271701 0.144704 282 t-Statistic Prob. -8.788308 0.0000

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


D(D_LEVEL(-1)) D(D_LEVEL(-2)) D(D_LEVEL(-3)) D(D_LEVEL(-4)) C R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood Durbin-Watson stat 0.060571 -0.009002 -0.042426 0.003902 -0.009322 0.602647 0.596987 0.201700 14.27964 68.01282 1.989236 0.128642 0.107946 0.083639 0.053261 0.010730 0.470848 -0.083395 -0.507255 0.073270 -0.868757 0.6380 0.9336 0.6123 0.9416 0.3856 -0.000448 0.317721 -0.347411 -0.282239 106.4692 0.000000

Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion F-statistic Prob(F-statistic)

ADF Test of 1st Order Difference of Curvature ADF Test Statistic -9.234520 1% Critical Value* -3.4517 5% Critical Value -2.8703 10% Critical Value -2.5714

*MacKinnon critical values for rejection of hypothesis of a unit root. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(D_CURV) Method: Least Squares Sample(adjusted): 2/12/2001 12/10/2007 Included observations: 336 Excluded observations: 21 after adjusting endpoints Variable D_CURV(-1) D(D_CURV(-1)) D(D_CURV(-2)) D(D_CURV(-3)) D(D_CURV(-4)) C Coefficient Std. Error -1.439551 0.175199 0.114681 0.041954 0.067202 0.000873 0.155888 0.138866 0.115982 0.089965 0.056201 0.010527 t-Statistic -9.234520 1.261644 0.988780 0.466333 1.195749 0.082955 Prob. 0.0000 0.2080 0.3235 0.6413 0.2327 0.9339

R-squared 0.630998 Adjusted R-squared 0.625407 S.E. of regression 0.192942 Sum squared resid 12.28475

Log likelihood 79.10710 Durbin-Watson stat 1.987825

Mean dependent var 0.000506 S.D. dependent var 0.315244 Akaike info criterion 0.435161 Schwarz criterion 0.366999 F-statistic 112.8608 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000000

ADF Test of 1st Order Difference of Slope ADF Test Statistic -8.839290 1% Critical Value* -3.4506 5% Critical Value -2.8698 10% Critical Value -2.5712

*MacKinnon critical values for rejection of hypothesis of a unit root. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(D_SLOPE) 283

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


Method: Least Squares Sample(adjusted): 2/12/2001 12/10/2007 Included observations: 357 after adjusting endpoints Variable D_SLOPE(-1) D(D_SLOPE(-1)) D(D_SLOPE(-2)) D(D_SLOPE(-3)) D(D_SLOPE(-4)) C Coefficient Std. Error -1.134383 0.011501 0.076545 0.037083 -0.009721 0.003360 0.128334 0.113447 0.097503 0.079901 0.053175 0.005251 t-Statistic -8.839290 0.101375 0.785052 0.464104 -0.182803 0.639889 Prob. 0.0000 0.9193 0.4330 0.6429 0.8551 0.5227

R-squared 0.573283 Adjusted R-squared 0.567204 S.E. of regression 0.099078 Sum squared resid 3.445593

Log likelihood 321.7931 Durbin-Watson stat 1.996479 Annexure A3

Mean dependent var 0.000623 S.D. dependent var 0.150604 Akaike info criterion 1.769149 Schwarz criterion 1.703977 F-statistic 94.31187 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000000

Parameter estimation under VAR Sample(adjusted): 1/15/2001 12/10/2007 Included observations: 352 Excluded observations: 9 after adjusting endpoints Standard errors & t-statistics in parentheses D_CURV D_CURV(-1) -0.167660 (0.08885) (-1.88708) 0.107574 (0.09254) (1.16250) -0.131497 (0.11242) (-1.16970) 0.001673 (0.01012) (0.16532) D_LEVEL 0.330859 (0.09078) (3.64466) 0.097427 (0.09455) (1.03043) 0.323407 (0.11486) (2.81556) -0.004674 (0.01034) (-0.45198) 0.086548 0.078673 13.04353 0.193601 10.99075 80.51336 -0.434735 -0.390830 -0.004716 D_SLOPE -0.096887 (0.04623) (-2.09577) -0.074549 (0.04815) (-1.54827) -0.164680 (0.05850) (-2.81528) 0.000699 (0.00527) (0.13269) 0.029830 0.021467 3.382699 0.098592 3.566703 318.0461 -1.784353 -1.740448 0.001026

D_LEVEL(-1)

D_SLOPE(-1)

R-squared 0.078003 Adj. R-squared 0.070055 Sum sq. resids 12.49403 S.E. equation 0.189479 F-statistic 9.813853 Log likelihood 88.08857 Akaike AIC -0.477776 Schwarz SC -0.433871 Mean 0.000369 284

10th Global Conference of Actuaries


dependent S.D. dependent 0.196487

0.201698

0.099668

Determinant Residual 4.10E-06 Covariance Log Likelihood 684.6893 Akaike Information Criteria -3.822098 Schwarz Criteria -3.690384

About the Author: Subhash Chandra Subhash Chandra is Senior Manager, Actuarial in Kotak Mahindra Old Mutual Life Insurance, Mumbai. The views presented in this paper are those of the authors and are not necessarily shared by the organization.

285

You might also like