You are on page 1of 38

Chapter 11 Input Markets and the Allocation of Resources

11.1

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Perfectly Competitive Input Markets


1.

2.

There are two types of input markets: Primary input markets include resources that have not been processed by other firms, such as land, oil and labour. Intermediate input markets are the processed output from other firms, such as iron ingots, hog bellies and rolled steel.
11.2
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Assumptions of Perfectly Competitive Input Markets


1.

2.

3.

4.

Large Numbers-There are a large number of input demanders/suppliers and no individual buys (sells) a significant portion of total quantity traded. Perfect Information-Demanders/suppliers have perfect knowledge of prices and all firms have perfect information of production functions. Input Homogeneity-In any input market, all units of the input are identical. Perfect Mobility of Resources-All inputs are perfectly mobile.
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

11.3

The Supply of Non-Labour Inputs

Renewable resources, such as land, can be used over and over again. Non-Renewable resources, like oil, once used it is gone. In the analysis that follows, it is assumed that the supply of non-labour inputs is perfectly price-elastic.

11.4

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

The Supply of Labour

1.

2.

An individual faces two constraints: The time constraint says that total time available (T) equals work time (h) plus leisure time (x1): h+x1=T The income constraint says that a persons income (x2) is the sum of work income (wage x h) and non-work income (A): X2=wh+A
11.5
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

The Leisure-Income Constraint


The

leisure income constraint: wx1+x2=A+wT The wage (w) is the price of leisure and the slope of the budget constraint. A+wT is full (all work) income. The utility maximizing bundle of leisure/labour is where the indifference curve is tangent to the leisure-income constraint in Figure 11.1
11.6
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.1 The demand for leisure and the supply of labour

11.7

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.2 Leisure as a normal good

11.8

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.3 Income and substitution effects for a wage change

11.9

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Response to a Change in Wage Rate


When leisure is a normal good, the hours of work may increase or decrease in response to a wage increase depending upon whether the income effect is greater than or less than the income effect. When leisure is an inferior good, an increase in wage rate invariably leads to a decrease in leisure hours and an increase in work hours

11.10

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.4 (a & b) The demand for leisure and the supply of labour

11.11

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Firms Demand for One variable Input


The

short-run demand function relates to a scenario where only one input is variable.

11.12

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Input Demand in a One-Good Economy


For

any wage less than the maximum value of the average product, the firms demand function is the downward sloping portion of the marginal product curve. For any wage rate greater than the maximum value of the average product, the firm maximizes profits by hiring no labour.
11.13
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.5 Input demand in a one-good economy

11.14

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Transforming the Product Curves into Revenue Curves


Marginal

Revenue Product is the marginal product from an addition unit of labour times the marginal revenue when the additional output is sold: MRP(z)=MR(y)MP(z) Similarly, average revenue product equals the price of the output times average product of the variable input: ARP(z)=pAP(z)
11.15
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.6 The firms demand for one variable input

11.16

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

The Firms Demand Curve for One Variable Input


For input prices less than the maximum values of ARP, the firms demand function is the downward-sloping portion of MRP. For input prices greater than the maximum value of ARP, the firm will demand none of the variable input. Given an initial positive quantity of the input demanded, an increase in the price of an input, will cause the firm to reduce the quantity demanded of that input.

11.17
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

The Firms Demand Curve for One Variable Input


The

value of the marginal product (MRP) of the variable input (VMPz) is output price time marginal product: VMPz=pMP(z). For a perfect competitor VMP =MRP (since p=MR). For a monopolisy MRP<VMP since MR<P.

11.18

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Input Demand with Many Variable Inputs


In

the long-run all inputs are variable. In the long run, the firms response to an input-price change will via both the substitution effect and the output effect, produce a downward sloping input demand curve

11.19

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.7 The substitution effect of an input price change

11.20

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.8 Comparing long-run and short-run input demand functions

11.21

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Elasticity Rules for Derived Demand


The

response to an input price change in both the short and long run is to demand more (less) of an input as its price fall (rises). The response to a input price change is greater in the long run than in the short run.

11.22

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Equilibrium in a Competitive Market


In the long run, a firm that is a perfect competitor in both its output and input market will chose a input bundle such that for each input: we=MRP(z)=pMP(z)=VMP(z) In long-run equilibrium, a firm that is a perfect competitor in its input markets but a competitor in its output market, will choose an input bundle such that for each input: we=MRP(z)=MR(y)MP(z)<pMP(z)=VMP(z)

11.23
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.9 Equilibrium in a competitive input market

11.24

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Monopsony in Input Markets


A

monopsonist has significant control over what it pays for an input. The relationship between input price (w) and quantity of the input (z) is determined by the market supply function for the input: w=S(w).

11.25

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Monopsony in Input Markets


The

monopsonist buys all units of an input at the same price (average factor cost or AFC). Total factor cost (TFC) is quantity (z) times AFC or price S(z): TFC(z)=zS(z)

11.26

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Monopsony in Input Markets


The

marginal factor cost (MFC) is the rate at which TFC changes as the quantity of output (z) changes. When a monopsonist buys a positive quantity of the input, the MFC exceeds price (w) or average factor cost. The MFC=w+z(slope of supply curve):

11.27

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.11 A monopsonists profit-maximizing decision

11.28

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Profit Maximizing Input Decisions


The

general profit-maximizing rule in an input market is to buy an input up to the point where marginal factor cost is equal to marginal revenue product. For a competitive input market: MRP(z*)=MFC(z*)=w* For a monopsonist: MRP(z*)=MFC(z*)>w*
11.29
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.13 The inefficiency of monopsony

11.30

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.15 Resource allocation summarized

11.31

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

The Firms Demand for Capital Inputs


Since capital is durable, the sum of present values of MRP through time is: MRP=MRP0+[MRP1/(1+i)]++[MRP1/(1+i)D-1] The optimal quantity of capital input is the quantity where the present value of the marginal revenue products over its life is equal to the present value of all costs of this input (p= MRP). The MRP is the firms demand curve for gadgets.

11.32
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.16 The demand for a capital input

11.33

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Human Capital Decisions Over Time


Human

capital-investments in education and training. Human capital production function: R=F(H) Which says additional income (return on human capital investment) (R), is a diminishing function of the quantity of human capital (H).
11.34
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.17 Investing in human capital

11.35

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

From Figure 11.17


Invest

in an additional dollar of human capital if the marginal product (MP) exceeds the rate at which current foregone consumption can generate future consumption (1+i). To maximize the present value of net income, invest in human capital up to the point where MP=(1+i).
11.36
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.18 Another perspective on the human capital investment

11.37

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 11.19 The life-cycle choice

11.38

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

You might also like