You are on page 1of 36

Chapter 15

Introduction to Game Theory

15.1

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Game theory is based on the following modelling assumptions:


There are a few producers (players) in the industry (game). Each player chooses an output or pricing strategy. Each strategy produces a result (payoff) for that player. The payoff for each player is dependent upon the strategy he/she selects and that selected by other players.

15.2
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Game Theory: Basic Definitions


Players-entities

like individuals/firms that make choices. Strategies-the choices made by the players (output/pricing, etc.). Strategy combinations-a list of strategies for each player. Payoff-the outcome (utility, profit, etc.) from selecting a strategy.
15.3
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Game Theory: Basic Definitions


Best

response function-the players best response given the strategies of other players. Equilibrium strategy combination-a strategy combination where every players strategy is the best response to the strategy of all other players.

15.4

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Game Theory: Basic Definitions


Cournot-Nash

equilibrium- An equilibrium strategy combination where there is nothing any individual player can independently do that increases that players payoff. Each players own strategy maximizes that players own payoff.

15.5

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Game Theory: Basic Definitions


Normal

forms-simply represents the outcomes in payoff matrix (connects the outcomes in an obvious way). Extensive form description-a game tree. Each decision point (node) has a number of branches stemming from it; each one indicating a specific decision. At the end of the branch there is another node or a payoff.
15.6
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Game Theory: An example


A

strategy better than all others, regardless of the actions of others, is a dominant strategy. If one strategy is worse than another for some player, regardless of the actions of other players, it is a dominated strategy.

15.7

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 15.1 A movement game

15.8

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

From Figure 15.1


For

player 2, the strategy Middle is dominated by the strategy Right. When you find a dominated strategy, it can be eliminated from the game. Therefore, Figure 15.1 becomes Figure 15.2.

15.9

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 15.2 Game with dominated strategy award

15.10

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

From Figure 15.2


For

player 1, the Up strategy dominates both Middle and Down. For player 1, Up is therefore a dominant strategy. The Middle and Down rows can be eliminated from player 1s strategy. This leaves the game shown in Figure 15.3.
15.11
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 15.3 Game with last dominated strategy

15.12

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

From Figure 15.3


Player

Up. For Player 2, the dominant strategy is to move Left. (Up, Left) or 4,3* is therefore the equilibrium payoff. It is a Nash equilibrium where both players will settle on a strategy and not want to move.
15.13
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

1 has no choice but to move

The Prisoners Dilemma


Figure

15.4 shows payoffs for the two individuals suspected of car theft. The figures represent the jail time in months for Petra and Ryan. What is the equilibrium outcome of this game?

15.14

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 15.4 The prisoners dilemma

15.15

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

From Figure 15.4


An

easy way to find equilibrium is to draw arrows showing the direction of strategy preferences for each player. Horizontal arrows show preferences of player 2, vertical arrows show preferences for player 1. Where the two arrows meet, there is a Nash equilibrium (see Figure 15.5).
15.16
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 15.5 Nash equilibrium in the PD game

15.17

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

From Figure 15.5

1. 2. 3.

The arrows meet where both Petra and Ryan fink (Fink, Fink) and this is the equilibrium for the game. Interesting aspects of the prisoners dilemma:
There are many real life applications. The equilibrium results form a dominant strategy for both players. The equilibrium outcome is not ParetoOptimal (both would be better off if they both remained silent).

15.18

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Coordination Games
Often

situations may have no equilibrium or they may have multiple equilibria. In these situations, other forms of behaviour must arise for a solution to be found.

15.19

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Coordination Games: An Example


Figure

15.8 shows the payoffs for various strategies using Microsoft Word (Deans preference) and Corels WordPerfect (Richards favourite). The figures represent how much better/worse each author is under the various strategies measured in more/less papers written.
15.20
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 15.8 Choosing a word processor

15.21

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

From Figure 15.8


As

indicated by the arrows, there are two equilibria in this game. Therefore the Nash equilibrium is insufficient to identify the actual outcome. There exists a coordination problem when the players must decide on what equilibrium to settle on.
15.22
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

How Do the Players Decide a Strategy in Coordination Games?


There

is no definitive method of solving coordination games, actual outcomes often depend upon: laws, social customs or pre-emptive moves by players before the game. In some cases there simply is no equilibrium.
15.23
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Games of Plain Substitutes and Plain Complements


Games

in which each players payoff diminishes as the values of the other players strategy increases are known as games of plain substitutes. In games of plain substitutes, the players impose negative externalities on each other.
15.24
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Games of Plain Substitutes and Plain Complements


Games

in which each players payoff increases as the values of the other players strategy increases are known as games of plain complements. In games of plain compliments, the players impose positive externalities on each other.
15.25
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Games of Plain Substitutes with Simultaneous Moves


The

cross-effects in the payoff functions are negative. There exists mutual negative externalities. y10 and y20 are the Nash equilibrium values of the strategies. From the Nash equilibrium, y10 is a best response to y20
15.26
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Games of Plain Substitutes with Simultaneous Moves (continued)


Y10 solves the constrained maximization problem: Maximize by choice of y1 and y2 1 (y1, y2) < y2 = y20
Indifference curve 1 (y1, y2) is tangent to the constraint at the Nash equilibrium (y10, y20) in Figure 15.14. Because 1 (y1, y2) decreases as y2 increases, this indifference curve must lie below the line y2 = y20 elsewhere.
15.27
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Games of Plain Substitutes with Simultaneous Moves


For the same reason, the set of strategy combinations that One prefers to the Nash equilibrium lies below this indifference curve, as indicated by the downwardpointing arrows in the figure. For Twos indifference curve through the Nash equilibrium. It must be tangent to the line y1 = y1 at (y10, y20). Elsewhere it must lie to the left of the line y1 = y10 and the set of strategy combinations. Twos preferences to the Nash equilibrium lie to the left of this indifference curve.

15.28
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 15.14 Nash equilibrium for a game of plain substitutes

15.29

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

From Figure 15.14


All

strategy combinations in the Lense of Missed Opportunity are preferred by both players to the Nash equilibrium. When players impose mutual negative externalities on one another, they produce too much and would be better off cutting back on their strategy values.
15.30
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Mixed Strategies and Games of Discoordination


Possible Outcomes Claires Payoff Probability of Each Outcome Zaks Payoff for Each Outcome

(A,A)

pq

(A,B)
(B,A) (B,B)
15.31

0
0 1

p(1- q)
(1- p)q (1- p)(1- q)

1
1 0

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Mixed Strategies and Games of Discoordination


Claires

payoff is the probability weighted average of the payoffs associated with each outcome:

1(p,q)=1(p,q) +0(p(1-q))+0((1-p)q) +1((1-p)(1-q))

Claires

payoff is a linear function of her strategy, p: 1(p,q)=(1-q)+p(2q-1) payoff is a linear function of his strategy, q: 2 (p,q)= p+q(1-2p)
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Zaks

15.32

Mixed Strategies and Games of Discoordination

1.

Claires best response function:


Her payoff increases as P increases if 2q1>0, or if q>1/2 and p=1 is her best response. Her payoff decreases as p increases if 2q - 1<0, or if q<1/2 and p=o is her best response. Her payoff doesnt change as p increases if 2q - 1=0, or of q=1/2, and any value of p is her best response.
2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

2.

3.

15.33

Mixed Strategies and Games of Discoordination

1.

Zaks best response functions:


q=0 is his best response if (1 - 2p)<0, or if p > 1/2. q=1 is his best response if (1 - 2p)>0, or if p < 1/2. Any q in the interval [0,1] is best response if p = 1/2

2.

3.

15.34

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Mixed Strategies and Games of Discoordination


To

find the Nash equilibrium, plot the best response functions and find where they intersect. Nash equilibrium is p0 =1/2 and q0 = 1/2 (see Figure 15.21).

15.35

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

Figure 15.21 Mixed strategy Nash equilibrium

15.36

2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.

You might also like