You are on page 1of 150

Taxes and the

Business of Tobacco
Frank J. Chaloupka, University of Illinois at Chicago
J2J Tobaccos Global Impact Program
Abu Dhabi, UAE, 17 March 2015
1

Overview
Tobacco Taxation

Why tax tobacco products?


Types of tobacco taxes
Tobacco taxes globally
Impact of taxes and prices on tobacco use
Economic impact of tobacco taxes

The Business of Tobacco


Globalization of the tobacco industry
Consequences of globalization

www.tobacconomics.org

Why Tax Tobacco


Products?

Why Tax Tobacco?


"Sugar, rum, and tobacco, are
commodities which are no where
necessaries of life, which are become
objects of almost universal
consumption, and which are
therefore extremely proper subjects
of taxation.
Adam Smith
An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes
of The Wealth of Nations

Why Tax Tobacco?


Efficient revenue generation
Primary motive historically and still true in
many countries today
Very efficient source of revenue given:

Historically low share of tax in price in many


countries
Relatively inelastic demand for tobacco
products
Few producers and few close substitutes
One of many goods/services that satisfies the
Ramsey Rule

Why Tax Tobacco?


This vice brings in one hundred million
francs in taxes every year. I will certainly
forbid it at once as soon as you can
name a virtue that brings in as much
revenue
Napoleon III
7

Federal Cigarette Tax and Tax Revenues


Inflation Adjusted, 1955-2012
$1.05

$17,000

$0.95
$15,000

$0.85
Tax per
Pack (1/14 Dollars)
$0.75

Revenues (Millions of 1/14 Dollars)

$13,000

$0.65
$11,000
$0.55
$0.45

$9,000

$0.35
$7,000
$0.25
$0.15

$5,000
Year
Federal Tax

Tax Revenues
8

Source: Tax Burden on Tobacco, 2013, and authors calculations

Why Tax Tobacco?


To promote public health
Increasingly important motive for higher
tobacco taxes in many high income
countries

Emerging as important factor in some low and


middle income countries

Based on substantial and growing evidence


on the effects of tobacco taxes and prices on
tobacco use

Particularly among young, less educated, and


low income populations

WHO FCTC Article 6


Price and Tax Measures to
Reduce the Demand for
Tobacco
The parties recognize
that price and tax
measures are an effective
and important means of
reducing tobacco
consumption by various
segments of the
population, in particular
young persons.
www.tobacconomics.org

WHO MPOWER
Raise Taxes on Tobacco
We [] have a package of
six policy measures, known
as MPOWER, that can help
countries implement the
provisions in the Convention.
All six measures have a
proven ability to reduce
tobacco use in any resource
setting. But tobacco taxes
are by far the most
effective.
Director General Dr. Margaret Chan,
WHO, 2008
www.tobacconomics.org

Cigarette Price & Adult Smoking Prevalence


Inflation Adjusted, United States, 1970-2013
$6.00
37
$5.50
$5.00

33

Price per Pack (1/14 Dollars)


$4.50

Prevalence
29

$4.00
$3.50

25
$3.00
$2.50

21

$2.00
17

$1.50

Year
Prevalence

Price

Source: Tax Burden on Tobacco, 2013, National Health Interview Survey, and authors calculations

Taxes, Prices and Health: US, 1980-2005

13

Why Tax Tobacco?


Cover the external costs of tobacco
Pigouvian tax
Less frequently used motive
Account for costs resulting from tobacco use
imposed on non-users

Increased health care costs, lost productivity from


diseases/death caused by exposure to tobacco smoke
Increased financial costs related to publicly financed
health care used to treat diseases caused by tobacco
use

Can also include internalities that result from


addiction and time inconsistent preferences

Annual Economic Costs of Smoking (2010) & Cigarette Tax & MSA Revenues (2012),
Billion Dollars

$150.8

$170.6

$109.6

$38.7

$0.0

$20.0

$40.0

$60.0

$80.0

$100.0

$120.0

Source: 2014 Surgeon Generals Report and Tax Burden on Tobacco

$140.0

$160.0

15

$180.0

Why Tax Tobacco?


Differential tax structure to protect domestic
industry/farmers
Turkey 2004 considerably lower tax on cigarettes
using at least 1/3 oriental tobacco
Indonesia lower taxes on kreteks; lower taxes on
small producers
India lower taxes on bidis; no taxes on small bidi
producers
Egypt printing tax on foreign brands

Keep prices low for some products


Particularly those used by the poor

WHOs Best Practices in


Tobacco Taxation
Use tobacco excise tax increases to
achieve the public health goal of
reducing the death and disease caused
by tobacco use
As called for in Article 6 of the WHO FCTC
Additional benefit of generating significant
increases in tobacco tax revenues in short
to medium term
17

Types of Tobacco Taxes

Types of Tobacco Taxes


Variety of tobacco taxes
Taxes on value of tobacco crop
Customs duties on tobacco leaf imports and/or
exports
Customs duties on tobacco product imports and/or
exports
Sales taxes/Value added taxes
Implicit taxes when government monopolizes tobacco
product production and/or distribution
Tobacco excise taxes (or similar taxes)

Types of Tobacco Taxes


Tobacco Excise Taxes
Two types of excises

Specific Taxes: excises based on quantity or weight (e.g. tax


per pack of 20 cigarettes)
Ad Valorem taxes: excises based on value of tobacco
products (e.g. a specific percentage of manufacturers prices
for tobacco products)
Some countries use a mix of specific and ad valorem tobacco
excises, differential taxes for different products of given type,
minimum taxes, etc.
Many countries apply different types of taxes and/or tax rates
on different types of tobacco products (e.g. manufactured
cigarettes vs. bidis)

Excise systems for cigarettes


Number of
countries
186
56
50
60
20

Source: WHO GTCR IV

Total covered
Specific excise only
Ad valorem excise only
Mixture of both excises
No Excise

Types of Cigarette Excise Taxes


by Income Group, 2012
Excise System on Cigarettes
Total
countries

No Excise

Specific &
Ad-valorem

Only AdValorem

Only
Specific

51

28

13

High

51

18

17

Upper
Middle

52

11

19

18

Lower
Middle

32

18

Low

186

20

60

50

56

All
Countries

Source: WHO GTCR IV

Cigarette Tax Structure, Globally, 2012


Type of tax (Total number of countries: 166)
No Excise
(20)

Afghanistan,
Antigua &
Barbuda,
Bahrain, Iran,
Iraq, Kiribati,
Kuwait, Libya,
Maldives,
Marshall
Islands,
Mauritania,
Niue, Oman,
Palau, Qatar,
Saint Lucia,
Saudi Arabia,
Sierra Leone,
Somalia,
United Arab
Emirates

Mix (59)

Ad Valorem (36)

Specific (51)

Uniform (51)

Tiers (8)

Uniform (30)

Tiers (6)

Uniform (32)

Tiers (19)

Austria, Belgium, Bosnia &


Herzegovina, Bulgaria,
Chile, Costa Rica, Croatia,
Cyprus, Czech Republic,
Colombia, Democratic
Republic of Congo,
Denmark, Dominican
Republic, El Salvador,
Egypt, Estonia, Finland,
France, Germany, Greece,
Hungary, Iceland, Ireland,
Israel, Italy, Jordan, Kenya,
Latvia, Lithuania,
Luxembourg, Macedonia,
Malaysia, Malta, Mexico,
Montenegro, Morocco,
Netherlands, Poland,
Portugal, Romania, Russia,
Serbia, Slovakia, Slovenia,
Spain, Sweden,
Switzerland, Turkey*,
Thailand, Tunisia, UK

Andorra,
Brazil, China,
Kyrgyzstan,
Moldova,
Pakistan, Sri
Lanka,
Ukraine

Angola,
Argentina,
Bahamas,
Benin, Bolivia,
Burundi,
Cambodia,
Cameroon,
Ethiopia, Gabon,
Ghana,
Guatemala,
Guinea, GuineaBissau, Guyana,
Laos, Lebanon,
Madagascar,
Niger, Nigeria,
Paraguay,
Rwanda,
Sudan, Syria,
Togo,
Turkmenistan,
Venezuela,
Vietnam, Yemen,
Zambia

Bangladesh,
Burkina
Faso, Ivory
Coast,
Senegal,
Mali,
Myanmar

Albania, Australia,
Azerbaijan,
Barbados,
Botswana, Brunei,
Canada, Cook
Islands, Cuba,
Ecuador, Haiti,
Honduras, Jamaica,
Japan, Lesotho,
Macao, Malawi,
Mauritius, Namibia,
Nicaragua, Norway,
Panama, Peru,
Singapore, South
Africa, South Korea,
Suriname,
Swaziland, Taiwan,
Trinidad & Tobago,
United States,
Uruguay

Algeria,
Armenia,
Belarus,
Belize, Fiji,
Georgia,
Hong Kong,
India,
Indonesia,
Kazakhstan,
Mozambique,
Nepal, New
Zealand,
Papua New
Guinea,
Philippines,
Tajikistan,
Tanzania,
Uganda,
Uzbekistan

Note: The following countries imposed a minimum tax in addition to their statutory rates: the 27 EU countries, Israel, Russia, Switzerland,
Turkey, Turkmenistan and Ukraine; * Turkey's excise system changed from uniform ad valorem to uniform mix in 2013
Source: TMA 2012 and WHO

Different bases for tiered systems


31 (19%) of 165 countries covered have a tiered system
# of
countri
es

Country

Base of tiers

Bangladesh, Mozambique, Philippines, Belarus, Indonesia,


Pakistan

Retail price

Burkina Faso, Senegal

High, standard and low end cigarettes

China

Producer price

Indonesia

Production volume

11

Armenia, Belarus, India, Nepal, Georgia, Kazakhstan,


Kyrgyzstan, Moldova, Papua New Guinea, Tajikistan, Ukraine

filter/non filter

Indonesia, India, Philippines

hand/machine made

Indonesia, Myanmar

kretek/white cigarette,
cheerot/cigarette

Andorra, Algeria

Tobacco content (dark/blonde or


dark/light)

Brazil, Mozambique, Uganda

soft/hard

India, Nepal, Hong Kong, Sri Lanka

Cigarette length

Andorra, Uzbekistan

Trade (domestic/imported)

Belize, New Zealand

Weight (tobacco content in cigarette)

Fiji

Leaf content (domestic/imported)

Type

Packaging

Seven countries differentiate their excises based on more than one criteria: Andorra, Belarus, India,
Indonesia, Mozambique, Nepal and Philippines. Sources TMA 2012 and WHO

Average price and excise tax


by tax structure, 2012
Average excise PPP

Average price PPP

Excise tax structure

1.57

3.73

Specific only

1.28

2.50

Ad valorem only

1.32

2.86

Mix system

1.67

3.84

Relying more on specific

1.11

2.29

Relying more on ad valorem

1.70

No excise
Source: WHO 2013

Cigarette Tax Structure & Prices


0.60

0.50

0.40

0.30
Standard Deviation, Prices of Top 5 Brands

0.20

0.10

0.00

Source: Chaloupka, et al., 2014

WHOs Best Practices in


Tobacco Taxation
Simpler is better
Complex tax structures more difficult to
administer
Greater opportunities for tax evasion and
tax avoidance under complex tax
structures
Where existing structure is more complex,
simplify over time with goal of achieving
single uniform tax

WHOs Best Practices in


Tobacco Taxation
Rely more on specific tobacco excises as the
share of total excises in prices increases
Greater public health impact of specific excises
given reduced opportunities for switching down in
response to tax/price increases
Sends clear message that all brands are equally
harmful
Where existing tax is ad valorem, adopt a specific
tax and increase reliance on specific tax over time

WHOs Best Practices in


Tobacco Taxation
Rely more on tobacco excise taxes rather
than on import duties
Various trade agreements reducing import duties,
implying reduced impact of tobacco product
duties on price, revenues, and public health
Import duties create more opportunities for tax
avoidance/evasion
Where existing system relies on import duties,
adopt tobacco excises and increase reliance on
excises over time

Article 6 Guidelines
Recommendations - Section 3 Tobacco
taxation systems
Parties should implement the simplest and most efficient
system that meets their public health and fiscal needs,
and taking into account their national circumstances.
Parties should consider implementing specific or mixed
excise systems with a minimum specific tax floor, as
these systems have considerable advantages over
purely ad valorem systems.

www.tobacconomics.org

WHOs Best Practices in


Tobacco Taxation
Adopt comparable taxes and tax increases on
all tobacco products
Reduces potential for substitution to other
products that would result from differential tax
treatment and/or tax increases
Maximizes public health and revenue impact of
taxes/tax increases

Harm reduction?

Tax as a Percent of Price, Various


Products, European Union, July 2012
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%

Cigarettes

Fine cut tobacco (RYO)

Cigars and cigarillos

Source: WHO, unpublished data

Taxable RYO and Pipe Tobacco


US, 2008-2009
2,000,000

1,500,000

P
o
u
n
d
s

1,000,000

500,000

RYO

Pipe Tobacco

Source: US Treasury Department, Alcohol and Tobacco Tax and Trade


Bureau

Article 6 Guidelines
Recommendations - Section 3 Tobacco taxation
systems
All tobacco products should be taxed in a comparable way as
appropriate, in particular where the risk of substitution exists.
Parties should ensure that tax systems are designed in a way
that minimises the incentive for users to shift to cheaper
products in the same product category or to cheaper tobacco
product categories as a response to tax or retail price
increases or other related market effects.
In particular, the tax burden on all tobacco products should be
regularly reviewed and, if necessary, increased and, where
appropriate, be similar.

www.tobacconomics.org

Tobacco Taxes, Prices


& Tobacco Use

Taxes, Prices &Tobacco Use


Increases in tobacco product taxes and prices:
Induce current users to try to quit

Many will be successful in long term

Keep former users from restarting


Prevent potential users from starting

Particularly effective in preventing transition from


experimentation to regular use

Reduce consumption among those who continue to use


Lead to other changes in tobacco use behavior,
including substitution to cheaper products or brands,
changes in buying behavior, and compensation
36

Taxes, Prices & Tobacco Use


Inflation
cigarette prices
and cigarette
Real
priceadjusted
and consumption
of cigarettes
inconsumption,
the UK
1971-1996
United Kingdom, 1971-1996

2.65

CONSUMPTION

16000

2.45

15000
14000

2.25

13000

2.05

12000

1.85

11000

1.65

PRICE

10000

1.45

9000
1971

1.25
1974

1977

1980

1983

1986

1989

1992

1995

Year
Source: Townsend 1998

P r ic e ( ) 1 9 9 4 va lu e

C ig a r e t t e C o n s u m p t io n
1 9 9 4 p r ic e s ( m )

17000

Cigarette Prices and Cigarette Sales


Kansas, 1966-2013, Inflation Adjusted
315
$5.00

295
275

$4.50

255
$4.00
235
$3.50

215

Price pe r Pack (Jan 2015 dollars)

Sale s (m illion pack s)

195

$3.00

175
$2.50
155
$2.00

135

$1.50

Price
Cigarette Tax Revenue Economic Report
J. Chaloupka

115

Sales (million packs)

Sources: Tax Burden on Tobacco, 2014; Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Authors Calculations

Frank

Taxes, Prices & Tobacco Use


Inflation Adjusted Cigarette Prices and
Cigarette Consumption, Morocco, 1965-2000

Source: Aloui, 2003

Cigarette Price & Consumption


Hungary, 1990-2011, Inflation Adjusted
27,000

700

25,000

600

23,000

500

Price, 2011 Forints/Pack


21,000

400

19,000

300

17,000

200

15,000

100

Million Sticks

13,000
0
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995
1996 1997Million
1998 Sticks
1999 2000 2001 Linear
2002 2003
2004 2005
2006Sticks)
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
Consumption,
(Consumption,
Million
Price, 2011 Forints
Linear (Price, 2011 Forints)

www.tobacconomics.org

Sources: EIU, ERC, and World Bank

Cigarette and Adult Smoking Prevalence


US States & DC, 2009
25

23

21

19

Prevalence

f(x) = - 0.01x + 25.52


R = 0.17

17

15

13

11

9
350

400

450

500

550

600

650

700

750

800

Average price, (in cents)

Source: BRFSS, Tax Burden on Tobacco, 2010, and authors calculations

850

Adult Prevalence & Price, Brazil


16

Adult Smoking Prevalence and Cigarette Price


Brazil, Inflation Adjusted, 2006-2013
5.4

16
15
15

4.9

14
14
Adult Smoking Prevaleence

Price per Pack, 2013 BRL


4.4

13
13
3.9

12
12
11
2006

2007

2008

2009

Sales, Million Sticks

2010

2011

2012

3.4
2013

Price per Pack, 2013 BRL

Sources: Ministry of Health, Brazil; EIU; World Bank

200,000

Monthly Quit Line Calls, United States


11/04-11/09
4/1/09 Federal Tax Increase

150,000

1/1/08 WI Tax Increase

100,000

50,000

Cigarette Prices and Cessation


US States & DC, 2009
70

65

f(x) = 0.03x + 43.08


R = 0.37

60

% Ever Smokers Who Have Quit


55

50

45
350

400

450

500

550

600

650

700

750

800

850

Average price (in cents)


Source: BRFSS, Tax Burden on Tobacco, 2010, and authors calculations

f(x) =
R = 0

Cigarette Prices and Youth Smoking Prevalence US States & DC, 2009
27

25

23

21

19

17

Prevalence
15

13

11

7
350

400

450

500

550

600

650

700

750

800

850

Average price (in cents)


Source: YRBS, Tax Burden on Tobacco, 2010, and authors calculations

Cigarette Price & Youth Smoking Prevalence


High School Seniors, United States, 1991-2013
$6.50
36

$5.75

Smoking Prevalence, 12th Grade Students

Price per Pack (1/14 Dollars)


31
$5.00

26
$4.25

21

$3.50

16
$2.75
1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

Cigarette Price

12th grade prevalence


Sources: Tax Burden on Tobacco, BLS, MTF, and authors
calculations

Price, Consumption & Lung Cancer, France


# cigarettes/adult/day
300

5.5
5.0
4.5

Lung cancer death rates per 100,000 (divided


by four): men age 35-44

250

4.0
200

3.5
3.0

150

2.5
Relative price

2.0

100

Price (% relative to 1980)

Number/adult/day and death rates

6.0

1.5
1.0

50
1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

Year

Sources: Jha & Hill, 2012

Other Issues in Tobacco


Taxation

WHOs Best Practices in Tobacco


Taxation
Automatically adjust specific tobacco taxes
for inflation
Unless adjusted, real value falls over time, as
does the real value of revenues generated by tax
Ensures the public health impact of tax is
maintained
To date, not widely done

Australia, New Zealand, a few others

WHOs Best Practices in Tobacco


Taxation
Increase tobacco taxes by enough to reduce
the affordability of tobacco products
In many low/middle income countries, positive
relationship between income and tobacco use
Implies consumption increases even as taxes
increase if increases in income larger

Depends on relative price, income elasticity

Increasing affordability will result in increasing


tobacco use, consequences

50

Cigarette Prices & Cigarette Consumption


China, 1996-2005, Inflation Adjusted

P
r
i
c
e
(
1
9
9
0
R
M
B
)

1.97

70.9

1.77

68.9

P
a
c
k
s

1.57

66.9

p
e
r

1.37

64.9

1.17

62.9

0.97

60.9
1

Real Price per Pack

Per Capita Consumption

www.tobacconomics.org

10

C
a
p
i
t
a

Income & Cigarette Consumption


China, 1996-2005, Inflation Adjusted
I
n
c
o
m
e
p
e
r
C
a
p
i
t
a
(
1
0
0
0
1
9
9
0
R
M
B
)

6.3

70.9

5.8
68.9

P
a
c
k
s

66.9

P
e
r

5.3

4.8

4.3
64.9
3.8
62.9
3.3

2.8

60.9
1

Real Income per Capita

Per Capita Consumption

www.tobacconomics.org

10

C
a
p
i
t
a

Affordability & Cigarette Consumption


China, 1996-2005, Inflation Adjusted
A 2.09
f
f
o
r
d 2.04
a
b
i
l 1.99
i
t
y
(
1
9
9
0
=
1
)

70.9

68.9

66.9

P
a
c
k
s
P
e
r

1.94

64.9 C
a
p
62.9 i
t
a

1.89

60.9
Affordability

Per Capita Consumption

www.tobacconomics.org

Inflati0n & Affordability Adjustments


Australia, 2000-2014, Inflation Adjusted
$16.00

$14.00

$12.00

$10.00

$8.00

$6.00

$4.00

$2.00

$0.00

Excise Tax

GST

Industry Price

Article 6 Guidelines
Recommendations - Section 3 Tobacco
taxation systems
Parties should establish coherent long-term policies on
their tobacco taxation structure and monitor on a
regular basis including targets for their tax rates, in
order to achieve their public health and fiscal objectives
within a certain period of time.
Tax rates should be monitored, increased or adjusted
on a regular basis, potentially annually, taking into
account inflation and income growth developments in
order to reduce consumption of tobacco products.

www.tobacconomics.org

Tobacco Taxes as Part


of Comprehensive
Approach

WHOs Best Practices in Tobacco


Taxation
Include tobacco excise tax increases as part
of a comprehensive strategy to reduce
tobacco use
Synergies with other policies called for by WHO
FCTC, MPOWER package
Comprehensive efforts strengthen social norms
against tobacco, build public and political support
for tax increases
Maximize the impact of the tax increases on
public health

But reduce revenue impact

WHOs Best Practices in Tobacco


Taxation
Use a portion of tobacco tax revenues to
support other tobacco control and/or health
promotion efforts
Growing number of governments use hard
earmark for tobacco control and/or health
promotion efforts; others use soft earmark
General opposition to earmarking amount MoF
officials, economists
Maximize the impact of the tax increases on public
health

But reduce revenue impact

Earmarked Tobacco Taxes

Source: WHO 2010

State Tobacco Control Program


Funding and Youth Smoking Prevalence, United States, 1991-2009
37
$1,000

35
33

$800
31
29

$600
Total Funding
$Millions (FY10 dollars)

27
$400

Percent Current Smoking

25
23

$200

21
$0

19

Year
total state program funding

high school prevalence

Source: ImpacTeen Project, UIC; YRBS

www.tobacconomics.org

Article 6 Guidelines
Recommendations - Section 5 Use of
Revenues Financing of Tobacco Control
Parties could consider, while bearing in mind
Article 26.2 of the WHO FCTC, and in accordance
with national law, dedicating revenue to tobaccocontrol programmes, such as those covering
awareness raising, health promotion and disease
prevention, cessation services, economically
viable alternative activities, and financing of
appropriate structures for tobacco control.

www.tobacconomics.org

WHOs Best Practices in Tobacco


Taxation
Set tobacco excise tax levels so that
they account for at least 70 percent of
the retail prices for tobacco products
Update of World Bank yardstick of any
taxes accounting for 2/3 to 4/5 of retail
prices
Well above where most countries are
currently
Further increases in countries that do reach
this target

Weighted average Price of the Most Sold


Brand & Excise Tax per pack, and Total Tax
Share
By Income Group 2012
65.90%
63.34%

5.82

58.40%
48.72%

50.31%

40.76%
PPP

3.12

3.29

3.00
2.67
1.65

1.57

0.61

High income

Upper middle

Lower middle

Retail price, PPP

1.35

1.18

0.97

0.31

Low income

Excise tax PPP

China

All

Total tax share (%)

Note : Averages were weighted by number of current cigarette smokers in each country.
Because of the very large number in China, China's estimates were added separately.
Source: WHO GTCR IV

Weighted average Price of the Most Sold


Brand & Excise Tax per pack, and Total Tax
Share
By Region 2012
4.66

4.49

73.16%

53.21%

55.92%

3.13
50.27%
48.06%

2.63

2.58

39.91%

PPP

1.92

1.77

1.62
1.17
0.80

0.70

AFRO

AMRO
Retail price, PPP

EMRO
Excise tax PPP

0.59

EURO

SEARO

WPRO

Total tax share (%)

Note : Averages were weighted by number of current cigarette smokers in each country.
Source: WHO GTCR IV

Article 6 Guidelines - Text


As recognized in Guiding Principle 1.1, Parties have the sovereign
right to determine and establish their taxation policies, including the
level of tax rates to apply. There is no single optimal level of
tobacco taxes that applies to all countries because of differences in
tax systems, in geographical and economic circumstances, and in
national public health and fiscal objectives. In setting tobacco tax
levels, consideration could be given to final retail prices rather than
individual tax rates. In this regard, WHO had made
recommendations on the share of excise taxes in the retail prices of
tobacco products1.
WHO technical manual on tobacco tax administration. Geneva, World Health
Organization, 2010. (Recommends that tobacco excise taxes account for at least
70% of the retail prices for tobacco products).
1

Economic Impact of
Tobacco Taxes

Oppositional Arguments

Wont generate additional revenues


Will harm the poor
Will adversely affect the economy
Will cause extensive tax avoidance &
tax evasion

Tobacco Taxes Oppositional Arguments:


Revenue Impact

Tobacco Taxes & Tax Revenues


Myth: increases in tobacco taxes will
lead to lower tobacco tax revenues
given reductions in tobacco use

www.tobacconomics.org

Tobacco Taxes & Tax Revenues


Fact: tobacco tax increases lead to
increased tax revenues
Tobacco taxes account for a fraction of tobacco
prices
Increase in tax leads to smaller increase in
price
Reductions in tobacco use less than
proportionate to price increase
www.tobacconomics.org

Cigarette real price & real tax


revenue United Kingdom
9000

2.90

8500
Taxation revenue
8000
( million)
7500

Price () 1994 value


Tax revenue

2.40

7000
1.90

6500
6000

Price

5500

1.40

Year
Source: Townsend, 2010

South Africa - Taxes, Prices, and Tax


Revenues, 1970-2012, Inflation Adjusted
25

9000

8000
20
7000

6000
15
5000
Rand per Pack

Tax Revenues, Million Rand


4000

10

3000

2000

1000

Industry Price

Excise Tax

VAT

Excise Tax Revenues

Tobacco excise tax & tax revenues:


Poland
The excise tax revenue is increasing along with the tax rates
Percentage
share of excise
tax in retail price
of MPPC
cigarettes
Tobacco excise
tax revenue in
Poland (in mln
PLN)
Source: Ministry of
Finances
Source: Stoklosa & Ciecierski, 2010
73

Tobacco Taxes Oppositional Arguments:


Impact on the Poor

Tobacco Control & the Poor

Myth: tobacco control harms the poor

www.tobacconomics.org

Tobacco Control & the Poor

Fact: tobacco use harms the poor

www.tobacconomics.org

Tobacco & Poverty


Family falls into poverty
Foregone income 3:
Breadwinner dies
prematurely
Poor men
smoke

Foregone income 2:
Treatment cost &
Lost working days &
income

Breadwinner gets
sick due to
tobacco use

Cycle of
tobacco and
poverty

Foregone income 1:
More money spent
Less money spent
on tobacco:
on Education, nutrition etc
High opportunity cost
Source: Yurekli, 2007

Source: Jha et al, 2006

Poverty and Tobacco Use


Burdens of poverty are compounded by
tobacco use

Responsible for impoverishment of over 50


million in China

Crowding out of other spending:

Smoking households in China spent less


on food, housing, clothing, and education
than non-smoking households

www.tobacconomics.org

Sources: Hu, et al., 2008; Liu, et al., 2006

Crowding Out

17 ITC Countries
Tobacco crowds out
spending on essentials.
Greater crowding out in
LMICs

Source: ITC Project, 2012

80

Tobacco Taxes & the Poor


Myth: tobacco tax increases harm the
poor

www.tobacconomics.org

Tobacco Taxes & the Poor


Fact: tobacco tax increases can be
progressive
Tobacco use among low-income
populations more responsive to price
Pay smaller share of tax increase
Receive greater share of health
benefits from higher tax

www.tobacconomics.org

Who Pays& Who Benefits


Turkey - 25% Tax Increase
9.7%

8.5%

9%
4%
-1%
-2.2%
-6%
-11%
-16%

-18.5%

-21%

-20.4%

-26%
-31%
-36%

-35.3%

Change in Consumption

Change in Taxes Paid


Source: Adapted from nder & Yrekli, 2014

Who Pays& Who Benefits, China

Low SES group:


Pays 6.4% of increased taxes
Receives 32.1% of health benefits
Health/tax ratio: 5.02
www.tobacconomics.org

Source: Jha, et al, 2012

Impact of Tobacco Taxes


on the Poor
Need to consider overall fiscal system

Key issue is whats done with the revenues generated


by the tax

Greater public support for tobacco tax increases when


revenues are used for tobacco control and/or other
health programs

Net financial impact on low income households can be


positive when taxes are used to support programs
targeting the poor

Concerns about regressivity offset by use of revenues


www.tobacconomics.org
for programs directed to poor

Tobacco Taxes Oppositional Arguments:


Impact on Employment

Tobacco Taxes & Employment


Myth: tobacco tax increases and
other tobacco control policies will
result in significant job losses as
tobacco use falls

www.tobacconomics.org

Tobacco Taxes & Employment


Fact: tobacco control will result in net
increase in jobs in most countries

www.tobacconomics.org

Tobacco-Related Employment

Very small share of employment dependent on


tobacco growing and manufacturing in most
countries

Economic presence does not imply economic


dependence
Employment in tobacco manufacturing falling over
time in response to tobacco industry shift to more
capital intensive production technologies.
Can use revenues from tobacco taxes to help those
in tobacco growing/manufacturing shift to other
sustainable livelihoods

www.tobacconomics.org

Impact of Tobacco Taxes on Jobs


Tobacco tax increases will lead to decreased
consumption of tobacco products
Small loss of jobs in tobacco sector

Money not spent on tobacco products will be


spent on other goods and services
Gains in jobs in other sectors

Increase in tobacco tax revenues will be spent


by government
Additional job gains in other sectors

Net increase in jobs in most countries


www.tobacconomics.org

Tobacco Taxes Oppositional Arguments:


Tax Avoidance & Evasion

Tobacco Taxes & Illicit Trade


Myth: tobacco tax increases will lead to
increases in illicit trade, eliminating the
public health and revenue benefits of
higher taxes

www.tobacconomics.org

Tobacco Taxes & Illicit Trade


Fact: tobacco use falls and tax revenues
increase following tax increases even in
the presence of illicit tobacco trade

www.tobacconomics.org

Tax Avoidance & Evasion Do NOT Eliminate


Health Impact of Higher Taxes

www.tobacconomics.org

Source: Schroth, 2014

Tax Avoidance & Evasion


Do NOT Eliminate Revenue Impact of
Higher Taxes

95

Tobacco Taxes & Illicit Trade


Fact: other factors more important than
tobacco taxes and tobacco control
policies in explaining illicit trade

www.tobacconomics.org

Illicit Cigarette Market Share


& Cigarette Prices, 2012
50.00%
45.00%
Illicit40.00%
trade share as % of legal cigarette consumption
35.00%
30.00%
25.00%
20.00%
15.00%
10.00%
5.00%
0.00%
0

f(x) =
R = 0

10

12

14

Price USD

www.tobacconomics.org

Sources: Euromonitor, WHO

Determinants of Illicit Tobacco


Corruption
Weak tax administration
Absence of tax stamps; weak or non-existent
physical controls; unlicensed manufacturers,
distributors, retailers; weak customs
authorities
Poor enforcement
Limited resources for border patrols, customs
authorities, etc; low penalties
www.tobacconomics.org

Smuggling and Corruption, 2011


0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

0.3

0.25
illicit cigarette trade volume
0.2

0.15

0.1

0.05

0
1

f(x)2=
R = 0

5
6
Transparency Index

10

Sources: Euromonitor, Transparency International

www.tobacconomics.org

Determinants of Illicit Tobacco


Presence of informal distribution channels
e.g. Street vendors, unlicensed distributors
Presence of criminal networks
e.g. Organized crime, terrorist organizations
Access to cheaper sources
e.g. duty free, cross border

www.tobacconomics.org

Controlling Illicit Tobacco Trade

Fact: there exist effective


interventions to reduce illicit trade
in tobacco products

www.tobacconomics.org

Cigarette Taxes and Illicit Cigarette


Market, Spain 1991-2008

www.tobacconomics.org

Combating Illicit Tobacco Trade


Illicit trade protocol to the WHO FCTC
Adopted November 2012; currently in process of being
signed/ratified; provisions calling for:
Strong tax administration
Prominent, high-tech tax stamps and other pack markings
Licensing of manufacturers, exporters, distributors, retailers
Export bonds
Unique identification codes on packages

Better enforcement
Increased resources
Focus on large scale smuggling

Swift, severe penalties


Multilateral/intersectoral cooperation
www.tobacconomics.org

Summary

Cost Effectiveness of Tobacco Taxes


Significant tobacco tax increases make good
economic sense:

Not just long-term public health, but near-term


health and economic benefits

Tobacco control will not harm economies

Substantial impact in reducing health care


costs, improving productivity, and fostering
economic development.
www.tobacconomics.org

Key Tobacco Control Policies


$6,000

Cost-Effectiveness

$5,000
$4,000
$3,000
$2,000
Cost per DALY Averted
$1,000
$0

High Income

Upper Middle Income

Lower Middle Income

Low Income
Source: WHO, unpublished data

The Business of Tobacco

Overview
Globally, the tobacco industry continues to
evolve and market power has increased
This has consequences for tobacco use and
tobacco control

Industry strategy can undermine tobacco


control
But a globalized industry now faces globalized
tobacco control

www.tobacconomics.org

The Tobacco Industry


Has Evolved

Factors Contributing to Industry


Evolution
Bilateral, regional, and global trade agreements
Loosening of restrictions on foreign direct
investment
Privatization of government run tobacco
companies
A few significant exceptions

Consolidation among multinational tobacco


companies
Diversification of product lines
Tobacco control policies & regulation

Trade Agreements
Global/Multilateral treaties:
e.g. GATT/World Trade Organization

Regional Agreements: similar efforts to reduce


trade barriers among countries in given region:
e.g NAFTA, EU, ASEAN, WAEMU, etc;

Bilateral Agreements: reduce trade barriers


between selected countries:
e.g China- ASEAN free trade market

Significant reductions in tariff and non-tariff


barriers to trade in tobacco leaf and tobacco
products

Global Leaf Tobacco Exports &


Value, 1961-2011

Exports, 1,000 Tonnes

3,000

$12,000

2,500

$10,000

2,000

$8,000

1,500

$6,000

1,000

$4,000

500

$2,000

Export Value, Million Dollars

$0

Exports, 1,000 Tonnes

Export Value, Million Dollars

Source: FAOSTAT 2014

Global Cigarette Exports & Value,


1961-2011
1,200

$25,000

1,000

$20,000

800
Million Tonnes

$15,000

Million Dollars

600
$10,000
400

$5,000

200

$0

Exports, 1,000 Tonnes

Export Value, Million Dollars


Source: FAOSTAT 2014

Trade Agreements - impact


Impact of freer trade on tobacco use
Chaloupka & Laixuthai (1996) examined impact of
Section 301 agreements
Significant increases in tobacco use, market share of US companies

Taylor, et al. (2000); Perucic, et al. (in progress)


global analyses separately for low, middle, and highincome countries
More open markets lead to significant increases in tobacco use
Greatest impact in lower income countries

Increased tobacco use likely the result of greater


competition:
Lower prices
Increased marketing

Direct Investment & Privatization


Opening of markets has also resulted in
increased openness to direct investment
Investment in new production facilities/capacity
owned and operated by multinational tobacco
companies
Privatization of former government owned/operated
tobacco companies
for example, Turkish TEKEL sold to BAT in 2008 after being
on the market for many years)

Joint ventures between local monopoly and


multinational tobacco companies
For example, PMI and CNTC, Vinataba, and other national
monopolies

Direct Investment & Privatization


Public health concerns about FDI and
privatization
Government efforts to attract investors/buyers can
lead to agreements that government wont adopt
higher taxes, strong tobacco control policies
Increased presence of multinationals will lead to
widespread use of sophisticated marketing practices
Tobacco use will be higher than it would be otherwise

Public health benefits of privatization


Eliminates conflict of interest between revenues
generated from production/sale of tobacco and
health/economic benefits of tobacco control

Impact of Direct Investment


Cigarette Prices, Ukraine, 2000-2006

Source: Ross et al., 2008

Impact of Direct Investment


Cigarette Consumption, Ukraine, 1990-2006

Source: Ross et al., 2008

Privatization with Strong Tobacco


Control: Turkey

www.tobacconomics.org

Source: CTFK, 2012

Mergers & Acquisitions


Considerable consolidation among tobacco
companies
Acquisition of local cigarette companies by
Multinationals (MTCs)
Acquisition of popular local brands (e.g. BAT acquisition of
Protabaco - 2nd largest Colombian company - in 2011)

Mergers between local tobacco companies and MTCs


For example, PMI and Fortune Tobacco Company merger in 2010
nearly monopolizes Philippine cigarette market

Acquisition of one MTC by another MTC


For example, Imperial Tobacco Groups acquisition of Altadis in
2008; RJR acquisition of Lorillard in US (2nd & 3rd largest US
companies)

Others to come?

Cigarette Company Market Shares


1985-2013, Selected Years
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
1985

1990

1995

CNTC

PMI+Altria

2000

BAT

2006

JTI

ITG

2010

2013

Others

Source: Maxwell Tobacco Fact Book, various years; Euromonitor, 2014

Mergers & Acquisitions


Increasingly, consolidation across products
Altria, US largest cigarette company, acquisition of US
Smokeless Tobacco Company in 2008, largest
smokeless company in the US
Lorillard Inc. acquisition of Blu, a leading e-cigarette
company
JTIs acquisition of Gryson, a leading RYO/MYO
manufacturer in Western Europe
PMIs purchase of Jed Roses patent for a nicotine
inhaler

Mergers & Acquisitions


Combined with development and marketing
of new products
Nearly every MTC developing/marketing electronic products and
other non-tobacco nicotine products
2011 - BAT creates Nicoventures to develop reduced risk
tobacco products, other nicotine delivery products
Seeking approval for Voke nicotine inhaler to be licensed as a
medical device
2012 - Altria markets Verve a non-tobacco, nicotine lozenge
2014 RJ Reynolds go nationwide with nicotine gum Zonnic,
marketed as cessation aid
2014 Heat not burn products emerging Ploom (partially
owned by JTI), iQOS HeatSticks (PMI), others
More to come

Global Tobacco Market, 2013

Euromonitor, 2015

Global Tobacco Market, 2013

Euromonitor, 2014

Global Tobacco Market, 2013

Euromonitor, 2015

Global Tobacco Market, 2013

Euromonitor, 2014

Euromonitor, 2014

Pricing Power

I'll tell you why I like the cigarette


business. It cost a penny to make. Sell it
for a dollar. It's addictive. And there's a
fantastic brand loyalty.
Warren Buffet
130

Pricing Power

Euromonitor, 2014

Brand Shares, 2013


7

3
2.4
2

2.4

2.3
2

1.9

1.9

1.9

1.8

1.7

1.7

1.6

1.5

1.4

1.4

1.3

1.3

1.2

1.2

1.1

1.1

1.1

Euromonitor, 2014

Brand Shares by Region, 2013

Euromonitor, 2014

Philip Morris International

Euromonitor, 2014

British American Tobacco

Euromonitor, 2014

Consequences of
Globalization for
Tobacco Control

Consequences of Globalization
Challenges to national tobacco
control policies
Challenges posed by new products
Regionalization of production
On the plus side: Global action to
counter a globalized industry

Challenges to National Tobacco


Control Policies
Within countries : national, subnational laws
Philip Morris challenge of Norway tobacco product display ban
Favorable EFTA ruling; ban upheld by Oslo District Court

State-State disputes trade treaties


Indonesia/US dispute over US ban on flavored cigarettes; Multiple
challenges to Australias tobacco plain packaging measure

Investor-State disputes - bilateral investment


treaties
Philip Morris Asia challenge of Australian plain packaging policy
under bilateral investment treaty between Hong Kong & Australia

Challenges Posed by New Products


Ways to avoid smoke-free policies
Unclear coverage of electronic products and
other novel prices under existing bans on
tobacco product advertising, promotion and
sponsorship
Significant tax/price advantages
Depends on how tobacco products are defined for
tax purposes
Also depends on tax structure

Renormalization

140

142

Regulatory Challenges for


New Products
Need for tobacco control policies & regulation to
maximize the net public health impact
Could include:

Limits on youth access


Inclusion of vaping products under smoke-free policies
Strong product standards

Differential taxation
Allow some forms of marketing

Net public health impact of ENDS, other


emerging products unclear

Regionalization of Production
Consolidation/centralization of production in
regional production hubs
Capitalize on significant economies of scale in
production of tobacco products
Take advantage of regional trade agreements that
greatly reduce or eliminate barriers to trade in tobacco
products
Generally located in:
Large consuming country within region
Country where labor, tobacco leaf, other costs are low

Not associated with tobacco tax rates

Total Tax as Percentage of Retail Price of Most


Sold Brand and Production as Percentage of
Total Supply, 2012
Hungary
UK
Chile
Belgium
Canada

Saudi Arabia
Azerbaijan

Kazakhstan
Cameroon
Nigeria

www.tobacconomics.org

Source: WHO, 2013

Globalization of Tobacco Control:


WHO FCTC and MPOWER
Gives priority to public health
Recognize need for international
action and cooperation
Evidence-based
Mindful of potential social and
economic impact of tobacco
control efforts
Concerned about role of industry
A global public good

Summary & Conclusions

Summary
Strong evidence base to support guiding
principles and recommendations
Involvement of many Parties in developing
guidelines
Considerable scope for strengthening tax
systems and increasing taxes
Increasing examples of best practices
globally
But still many more examples of less than best
practices

For more information:


Tobacconomics
http://www.tobacconomics.org
@tobacconomics
fjc@uic.edu

You might also like