You are on page 1of 40

Cagan and Lucas Models

Presented by Carolina Silva


01/27/2005

Introduction
I will present two models that determine nominal exchange rates:
The monetary model: Cagan model
Lucas Model
Even though the first one is an ad-hoc model, many of its
predictions are implied by models with solid microfoundations, and
it is the basis for work in other topics. The Lucas model is one of
those solid microfoundations exchange rate determination
models.

I. Cagan Model of Money and Prices


In his 1956 paper, Cagan studied seven cases of hyperinflation.
He defined periods of hyperinflations as those where the price
level of goods in terms of money rises at a rate averaging at
least 50% per month

This implies an annual inflation rate of almost 13,000


These huge inflations are not things of the past, for example,
between April 1984 and July 1985, Bolivias price level rose by
23,000%

Cagan Model
Let M denote a countrys money supply and P its price level,
Cagans model for the demand of real money balances M/P is:

mtd pt Et ( pt 1 pt )
where m log of nominalmoney balances held at the end of period t,
p log P and is the semielasticity of demand for real balances with
respect to expected inflation.
Cagan justifies the exclusion of real variables such as output and
interest rate from the money demand function, arguing that during
hyperinflation the expected future inflation swamps all other
influences on money demand.

Solving the Model


Which are the implication of Cagans demand function to the
relationship between money and the price level?
Assuming an exogenous money supply m, in equilibrium:

mtd mt , thus the money demand becomes :


mt pt Et ( pt 1 pt )

(1)

So, we have an equation explaining price-level dynamics in terms


of the money supply.

Solving the Model


First, for the nonstochastic perfect foresight, ie, mt pt ( pt 1 pt ) (2),
by successive substitution ofpt 2 , pt 3 ... we get that:

pt

1 s t 1

s t


pt T
ms lim
T 1

Assuming the second term to be zero (ie, no speculative bubbles)


we get that :

pt

1 s t 1

Is this a reasonable solution of (2)?

s t

ms

(3)

Simple Cases
1. Constant money supply: mt m t

mt pt ( pt 1 pt ) pt m
and also,

pt

1 s t 1

s t

ms pt m

Simple Cases
2. Constant percentage growth rate: mt m t
Guessing that the price level is also growing at rate , and
substituting this guess in equations (2) and (3), we get again
the same answer from both:

pt mt
3. Solution (3) also covers more general money supply
processes.

The Stochastic Cagan Model


Given the linearity of the Cagan equation, extending its solution
to a stochastic environment is straightforward. Under the no
bubble assumption, we have that:

pt

1 s t 1

s t

Et (ms )

(4)

The Cagan Model in Continuous Time


Sometimes is easier to work in continuous time. In this case, the
Cagan nonstochastic demand (2) becomes:

mt pt p t
using differential equations methods we get that :

1
pt exp[( s t ) / ]ms ds b0 exp(t / )
t
where the no bubble assumption implies b0 0

Seignorage
Definition: represents the real revenues a government acquires
by using newly issued money to buy goods and nonmoney
assets:
M t M t 1
Seignorage
Pt
Most hyperinflations stem from the governments need for
seignorage revenues. What is the seignorage-revenue-maximizing
rate of inflation? Rewriting seignorage as:
Seignorage

M t M t 1 M t
Mt
Pt

we can see that, if higher money growth raises expected inflation,


the demand for real balances M/P will fall, so that a rise in money
growth does not necessarily augment seignorage revenues.

Seignorage
Finding the seignorage-revenue-maximizing rate of inflation is
easy if we look only at constant rates of money growth:
1

Mt
P
t
M t 1 Pt 1

Now, exponentiating Cagans perfect foresight demand, we get:

M t Pt 1


Pt Pt

Substituting these in the second seignorage equation:


Seignorage

(1 ) (1 ) 1
1

Seignorage
Thus, the FOC with respect to is :
(1 )

( 1)(1 )

max

Cagan was surprised because, at least in a portion of each


hyperinflation he studied, governments seem to put the money
to grow at rates higher than the optimal one.
Adaptative expectations may imply short run benefits from
temporarily increasing the money growth rate.
Problem: even under rational expectations, if the government
can not commit to maintain the optimal rate, its revenues could
be lower.

A Simple Monetary Model of Exchange


Rates
A variant of Cagans model: a SOE with exogenous real output
and money demand given by:
mt pt i t 1 yt
(1),

where i log(1 i ) with i the nominal interest rate, p is the log of


price and y is the log of real output.
Let t be the nominal exchange rate (foreign in terms of home),
and P * denote the world foreign-currency price of the consumption
basket with home-currency price P .

Then PPP Pt t Pt* or in logs pt et pt*

(2)

t 1

and UIP 1 it 1 (1 i ) Et
t

(3)

*
t 1

A Simple Monetary Model of Exchange


Rates
An approximation in logs of UIP is:
i t 1 i*t 1 Et et 1 et

(4)

Substituting the log PPP and (4) in eq. (1) gives:

(mt yt i*t 1 pt* ) et ( Et et 1 et )

(5)

and the solution to the exchange rate is :



1

et

1 s t 1

s t

Et (ms y s i*s 1 ps* )

(6)

A Simple Monetary Model of Exchange


Rates
Even though data do not support generally this model in non
hyperinflation environment, this simple model yields one
important insight that is preserved in more general frameworks:
The nominal exchange rate must be viewed as an asset price
In the sense that it depends on expectations of future variables,
just like other assets.

Monetary Policy to Fix the Exchange


Rate
Consider a special case of the SOE Cagan exchange rate model:

mt et ( Et et 1 et )

(1)

Suppose the government fixes the nominal exchange rate


permanently at e , then substituting in (1) we get that:

mt m e
Thus, money supply becomes an endogenous variable,
implying that exchange rate targets implicitly entail decisions
about monetary policy.

Some observations
Can the exchange rate be fixed and the government still have
some monetary independence?
Adjusting government spending can relieve monetary policy of
some of the burden of fixing the exchange rate. But in practice,
fiscal policy is not a useful tool for exchange rate management,
because it takes too long to be implemented.
Financial policies can help also through sterilized interventions:
to keep the exchange rate fix, the government may have to buy
foreign currency denominated bonds with domestic currency. To
sterilize this, the government reverses its expansive impact by
selling home currency denominated bonds for home cash.

II. Lucas Model


One of the problems of Cagan model is that the money demand
function upon which it rest has no microfoundations. On the
other hand, Lucass neoclassical model of exchange rate
determination gives a rigorous theoretical framework for pricing
foreign exchange and other assets.
We will see three models:
The barter economy
The one money monetary economy
The two money monetary economy
In all these, markets have no imperfections and exhibit no
nominal rigidities. Agents have rational expectations and
complete information.

A. The Barter Economy


Here we will study the real part of the economy:
Two countries, each inhabited by a representative agent.
There is one firm in each country, which are pure endowment
streams that generate a homogeneous nonstorable countryspecific good, using no labor or capital input => fruit trees.
Evolution of output:

xt g t xt 1 and yt g t* yt 1 , where g t and g t* are random and its


stochastic processes are known by agents.
Each firm issues a perfectly divisible share of common stock
which is traded in a competitive market.

The Barter Economy


Firms pay out all of their output as dividends to shareholders,
which are the sole source of support for individuals.
We will let xt be the numeraire good.
Under this framework, the wealth a domestic agent brings to
period t is:

Wt wxt 1 ( xt et ) wyt 1 (qt y y et* )


And the agent has to allocate this wealth between consumption
and new share purchases:

Wt et wxt et* wyt c xt qt c yt

The Barter Economy


Equating the last two equations we get the budget constraint for
domestics:
c xt qt c yt et wxt et* wyt wxt 1 ( xt et ) wyt 1 (qt y y et* ) (1)
In this way, domestic agents have to choose sequences

xt j , c yt j , wxt j , w yt j

j 0

to solve:

Max Et

j 0

u ( c xt j , c y t j )

st. (1)

The Barter Economy


Thus, the domestic Euler equations are:

c yt :

qt u1 (c xt , c yt ) u 2 (c xt , c y y )

(2)

wxt : et u1 (c xt , c y y ) Et [u1 (c xt 1 , c yt 1 )( xt 1 et 1 )]

(3)

wyt : et*u1 (c xt , c y y ) Et [u1 (c xt 1 , c yt 1 )(qt 1 yt 1 et*1 )]

(4)

If we put an * over the variables cx , c y , wx , wy j 0 in the


domestic agent problem and in the domestic Euler equations, we
get the foreign agent problem and foreign Euler equations.
t j

t j

t j

t j

The Barter Economy


We need to add four more constraints to clear the markets:

wxt w*xt 1

(5)

wyt w*yt 1

(6)

c xt c *xt xt

(7)

c yt c *yt yt

(8)

The Barter Economy


Given that we have complete and competitive markets, we can
apply the welfare theorem and solve the social planner problem:
1
1
Max u (c xt , c yt ) u (c*xt , c*yt )
2
2
st. (7), (8)
and the solution will be an competitive equilibrium:

1
1

*
*
u1 (c xt , c yt ) u1 (c xt , c yt )
xt
yt

2
2
*
*
FOC :
c yt c yt
c xt c xt
1
1
2
2
*
*
u2 (c xt , c yt ) u 2 (c xt , c yt )
2
2

The Barter Economy


Now we have to look for the prices and shares that support this
equilibrium.
Shares: a stock portfolio that achieves complete insurance of
idiosyncratic risk is,

1
wxt w wyt w
2
*
xt

*
yt

Prices: to get an explicit solution we need to give a function form


to the utility, let

Ct cxt c1yt

Ct1
and u (c xt , c yt )
1

The Barter Economy


Under all what we have seen and assumed, the Euler equations
imply:

1 xt
qt
yt
C
et
Et t 1
xt
Ct

C
e
Et t 1
qt yt
Ct
*
t

et 1
1

xt 1

et*1
1

qt yt 1

B. The One-Money Monetary Economy


Here we introduce a single world currency and the idea is to do it
without changing the real equilibrium reached above.
For the money to have some value at equilibrium, Lucas
introduces a cash-in-advance constraint. As we enter period t:
1. Output levels are revealed.
2. Money evolves according to: M t t M t 1 where t
is known. The economy wide increment is distributed evenly
across H and F individuals as lump sum transfers. Each
receive:

M t
(t 1)( M t 1 / 2)
2

The One-Money Monetary Economy


3. A centralized securities market opens, where agents allocate
their wealth toward stock purchases and the cash they will need
for consumption.
4. Decentralized goods trading now takes place in the shopping
mall.
5.The cash value of goods sales is distributed to stockholders as
dividends, who carry these nominal payments into the next
period.
Observation: the state of the world is revealed before trading, thus
agents know exactly how much cash they need to finance the
current period consumption plan. So, it is no necessary to carry
cash from one period to the next, and they wont do it if the
nominal interest rate is positive.

The One-Money Monetary Economy


Given these assumptions, domestic agents period t wealth is:
Pt 1 ( wxt 1 xt 1 wyt 1 qt 1 yt 1 )

M t
Wt
wxt1 et wyt 1 e

P
2 Pt

t
ex dividend share value
dividends

*
t

money transfer

And in the security market, the agent allocate his wealth between:
Wt

mt
wxt et wyt et*
Pt

Assuming a positive nominal interest rate, the cash in advance


constraint binds:

mt Pt (c xt qt c yt )

The One-Money Monetary Economy


Using the last three equations, we get that the domestic agent
problem is:

Max Et

j 0

u (c xt j , c yt j )

Pt 1
M t
st.
( wxt 1 xt 1 wyt 1 qt 1 yt 1 )
wxt 1 et wyt 1 et*
Pt
2 Pt
c xt qt c y t wx et wy et*

The One-Money Monetary Economy


The domestic agent problem implies the following Euler
equations:

c yt :

qt u1 (c xt , c yt ) u2 (c xt , c y y )

Pt
wxt : et u1 (c xt , c y y ) Et [u1 (c xt 1 , c yt 1 )(
xt 1 et 1 )]
Pt 1

(1)
(3)

Pt
wyt : e u (c xt , c y y ) Et [u1 (c xt 1 , c yt 1 )(
qt 1 yt 1 et*1 )] (4)
Pt 1
*
t 1

The foreign agent has the same problem and Euler equations
but with an * over the variables that he chooses (consumption,
shares w and money holdings m).

The One-Money Monetary Economy


To clear the markets we need to add the constraints:

wxt w*xt 1

wyt w*yt 1

c xt c*xt xt

c yt c*yt yt

and

M t mt mt*

The equilibrium of the barter economy is still the perfect riskpooling equilibrium:
1
xt
yt
*
*
*
*
wxt wxt wyt wyt
c xt c xt
c yt c yt
and
2
2
2
The only thing that has changed is the equity pricing formulae,
which now include the inflation premium.

The One-Money Monetary Economy


Using the same constant relative risk aversion utility function we
used in the barter economy, we have that:

1 xt
qt
yt

Pt
M t xt 1

Pt 1 M t 1 xt
1

et
et 1
Ct 1 M t


Et

xt
Ct M t 1 xt 1
1
*

Ct 1 M t
et
et*1

Et

qt yt
Ct M t 1 qt yt 1

The One-Money Monetary Economy,


pricing other assets
At equilibrium, the price b of a nominal bond that pays 1 dollar at
the end of the period must satisfy:
u1 (c xt , c yt )bt / Pt Et (u1 (c xt 1 , c yt 1 ) / Pt 1 )


utility cost of buying the bond

If

it

marginal utility of payoff

is the nominal interest rate, then

bt (1 it ) 1
Thus, using the usual utility function, nominal interest rate will be
positive in all states if the endowment growth rate and monetary
growth rates are positive.

C. The Two-Money Monetary Economy


Let the home currency be the dollar, and the foreign, the euro.
Now, the home good x can only be purchased with dollars, and y
with euros. Besides, xs dividends are paid in dollars and ys in
euros. Agents can get the foreign currency during security market
trading.
Currencies evolve according to:

dollar : M t t M t 1
euro : N t *t N t _ 1
Now we will have a new product: claims to future dollar and euro
transfers. It will be assumed that initially the home agent is
endowed with the whole stream of dollars and the foreign, with the
hole stream of euros. Then they can trade.

The Two-Money Monetary Economy


Then, we have that the home agent current-period wealth is:
M t 1 M t Nt 1 St N t
Pt 1
St Pt*1
Wt
wxt 1 xt 1
wyt 1 yt 1

P
P
P
P
t t
t t
dividends

money transfers

wxt 1 et wyt 1 et* M t 1 rt N t 1 rt*



market value of sec urities

And this wealth will be allocated according to:

mt nt St
Wt wxt et wyt e M t rt N t rt

Pt
Pt
*
t

The Two-Money Monetary Economy


As before, the BC implied by the last two equations and the cash in advance
constraints mt Pt c xt and nt Pt *c yt imply the following Euler eqs :
c yt :

S t Pt *
u1 (c xt , c yt ) u 2 (c xt , c y y )
Pt

wxt :

et u1 (c xt , c y y ) Et [u1 (c xt 1 , c yt 1 )(

w yt :

S t 1 Pt *
e u (c xt , c y y ) Et [u1 (c xt 1 , c yt 1 )(
yt 1 et*1 )]
Pt 1

*
t 1

M t
: rt u1 (c xt , c yt ) Et [u1 (c xt 1 , c yt 1 )(
rt 1 )]
Pt 1

N :
t

Pt
xt 1 et 1 )]
Pt 1

N t 1S t 1
rt u1 (c xt , c y y ) Et [u1 (c xt 1 , c yt 1 )(
rt*1 )]
Pt 1
*

And again the foreign agent have a symmetric set of Euler eqs.

The Two-Money Monetary Economy


Together with the Euler eqs. We have the clear market conditions:
wxt w*xt 1

wyt w*yt 1

c xt c*xt xt

c yt c*yt yt

M t mt mt*

N t nt nt*

With these eqs. We have the following equilibrium:

wxt w wyt w M t
*
xt

and

*
yt

*
Mt

Nt

xt
yt
*
c xt c
c yt c y t
2
2
*
xt

*
Nt

The Two-Money Monetary Economy


From the first Euler equation, we get that the nominal exchange
rate is:

u2 (c xt , c yt ) M t yt
St
u1 (c xt , c yt ) N t xt
Conclusion: as in the monetary approach, the determinants of the
nominal exchange rate are relative money supply and relative
GDPs. Two major differences are that in the Lucas model:
S depends on preferences
S does not depend explicitly on expectations

You might also like