You are on page 1of 33

Chapter 6

Production and Cost: One


Variable Input

6/1

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Production Function
The

production function identifies


the maximum quantity of good y that
can be produced from any input
bundle (z1, z2).
A production function is stated as:
y=F(z1, z2).

6/2

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Production Functions
In

a fixed proportions production


function, the ratio in which the inputs
are used never varies.
In a variable proportion production
function, the ratio of inputs can vary.

6/3

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.1 Finding a production function

6/4

2009 Pearson Education Canada

From Figure 6.1


The

production function is:


F(z1z2)=(1200z1z2)1/2
This is a Cobb-Douglas production
function. The general form is given
below where A, u and v are positive
constants.

y Az z

u v
1 2

6/5

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Costs
Opportunity

cost is the value of the


highest forsaken alternative.
Sunk costs are costs that, once
incurred, cannot be recovered.
Avoidable costs are costs that need
not be incurred (can be avoided).
Fixed costs do not vary with output.
Variable costs change with output.
6/6

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Long-Run Cost Minimization

1.
2.

6/7

The goal is to choose quantities of


inputs z1 and z2 that minimize total
costs, subject to being able to
produce y units of output.
That is:
Minimize w1z1+w2z2 (w1,w2 are input
prices).
Choosing z1 and z2 subject to the
constraint y=F(z1, z2).
2009 Pearson Education Canada

Production: One Variable Input


Total

production function TP (z1)


(z2 fixed at 105) defined as:
TP (z1)=F(z1, 105)

Marginal

product MP(z1) is the rate


of output change when the variable
input changes (given fixed amounts
of all other inputs).
MP (z1)=slope of TP (z1)
6/8

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.2 A total product function

6/9

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.3 From total product to marginal product

6/10

2009 Pearson Education Canada

The Free-disposal Assumption


Because a production function gives the
maximum output from any input
combination, we assume that increased
amounts of inputs will not be used if they
negatively impact output.
This is sometimes called the freedisposal assumption and combined with
our definition of the production function,
implies that marginal product cannot be
negative.

6/11

2009 Pearson Education Canada

The Free-disposal Assumption


Given

the free-disposal assumption,


the marginal product of any input is
always greater than or equal to zero.
Furthermore, for any input bundle,
the marginal product of at least one
input is positive.

6/12

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Diminishing Marginal Productivity


Reflects the assumption that at some point the
rate of increase in total output (marginal
product) will begin to decline.
Suppose the quantities of all inputs except one
- say, input1- are fixed. There is a quantity of
input 1- say, z1 - such that whenever z1
exceeds z1, the marginal product of input 1
decreases as z1 increases.

6/13

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.4 From total product to


marginal product: Another illustration

6/14

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Average Product
Average

product (AP) of the variable


input equals total output divided by the
quantity of the variable input.
AP(z1)=TP(z1)/z1

6/15

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.5 From total product to


average product

6/16

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.6 Comparing the average and


marginal product functions

6/17

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Marginal and Average Product


1.
2.
3.

When
When
When

6/18

MP exceeds AP, AP is increasing.


MP is less than AP, AP declines.
MP=AP, AP is constant.

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Costs of Production: One Variable Input


The

cost-minimization problem is:


Minimize w1z1 by choice of z1.

Subject to constraint y=TP(z1).


The variable cost function, VC(y) is:
VC(y)=the minimum variable cost of
producing y units of output.

6/19

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.7 Deriving the variable cost


function

6/20

2009 Pearson Education Canada

More Costs
Average

variable cost is variable


cost per unit of output. AV(y)=VC(y)/y
Short-run marginal cost is the rate
at which costs increase in the shortrun. SMC(y)=slope of VC(y)

6/21

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.8 Deriving average variable


cost and short-run marginal cost

6/22

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Short-run Marginal Costs and


Average Variable Costs
1.

2.

3.

6/23

When SMC is below AVC, AVC


decreases as y increases.
When SMC is equal to AVC, AVC is
constant (its slope is zero).
When SMC is above AVC, AVC
increases as y increases.

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Average Product and Average Cost


AVC (y)=w1/AP(z1)
The

average variable cost function


is the inverted image of the average
product function.

6/24

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Marginal Product and Marginal Cost


SMC (y)=(w1z1)/(MP(z))
The

short-run marginal cost


function is the inverted image of the
marginal product function.

6/25

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.9 Comparing cost and product functions

6/26

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.10 Seven cost functions

6/27

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.11 The costs of commuting

6/28

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.12 Total commuting costs

6/29

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Figure 6.13 The allocation of commuters to


routes

6/30

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Application: The Allocation of


Output Among Different Plants
Let

us reinterpret the lessons from traffic


congestion to solve a problem related to
multi-plant firms.
The firms problem is to allocate output
to its two plants so as to minimize its
total variable cost.

6/31

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Application: The Allocation of


Output Among Different Plants
Think

of Figure 6.13 as the variable and


marginal cost functions associated with
two plants (TCC1, TCC2 and MC1, MC2)
respectively.
The curve TCC in Figure 6.13a tells us
that the firm can minimize the variable
costs of producing 5000 units by
allocating 2000 units to the first plant
and 3000 units to the second plant.
6/32

2009 Pearson Education Canada

Application: The Allocation of


Output Among Different Plants
Using

the logic from Figure 6.13b:

Total costs can be reduced by allocating


output from the high-marginal cost plant to
the low-cost marginal plant.
To minimize the total variable cost of
producing a given output in two or more
plants, a firm allocates output to the plants
so that short-run marginal cost is the same
in all plants.
6/33

2009 Pearson Education Canada

You might also like