You are on page 1of 17

Government Influence on

Exchange Rates
Understanding the role that
governments play in influencing
exchange rates
Government Activities that Influence
Spot Exchange Rates
• The foreign exchange regime that the
government adopts.
– Independent float, managed float and pegs.
– Recall that market forces can result in “forced”
changes in foreign exchange regimes.
• UK in 1992; Asian economies during the Asian currency
crisis of 1997, etc.
• Direct and indirect government intervention in
foreign exchange markets.
Why do Governments Attempt to
Influence Exchange Rates?
• To react to what the government feels is an
unwarranted level of the spot rate.
– Generally done when the exchange rate “threatens”
domestic economic activity.
• Japan’s intervention on September 15, 2010
• To respond to “temporary” disturbances.
– Generally done when sudden and unanticipated events
produce extreme moves in exchange rates.
• Offsetting safe haven effects.
• To establish and maintain implicit and explicit exchange
rate boundaries.
– Done within the context of a pegged or managed
exchange rate regime.
Direct and Indirect Intervention
• Direct Intervention:
– Buying and selling currencies in foreign exchange
markets.
• Buying weak (depreciating) currencies and selling strong
(appreciating) currencies.
• Indirect Intervention:
– Government adjusting domestic interest rate.
• Raising interest rates to support weak (depreciating)
currencies and lowering interest rates to offset strong
(appreciating) currencies.
– Foreign exchange controls.
• Restrictions on the exchange of currency (i.e., the type and
amount of transactions).
Direct Intervention
• Through direct intervention in foreign exchange markets,
governments are attempting to offset market forces on
spot exchange rates.
– If market forces strengthen a currency, a government (central
bank) could respond by selling the strong currency (and buying
the weak currency) into the foreign exchange market (thus
meeting market demand for the strong currency).
• When the government does so, it accumulates international reserves
(i.e., the “weak” currency it is buying).
– If market forces weaken a currency, a government (central bank)
could respond by buying the weak currency (and selling the
strong currency) on the foreign exchange market (thus reducing
the supply of the weak currency).
• When the government does so, it uses its international reserves (i.e.,
the “strong” currency it is selling).
Direct Intervention to Support a Weak
Currency
Why is the Currency Weakening? Impact of Intervention
• Markets moving out of that • As the government is buying its
currency into another currency weak currency, it is also supplying
(i.e., into the preferred the currency that the markets are
currency). moving into (i.e., the preferred
– Interest rate differentials, safe currency).
haven effects, trade flows, • In doing so, the government is
political and economic risk,
asset bubbles, expectations of reducing its international
changes in peg, etc. reserves (i.e., the key currency
• Government needs to buy its the market is preferring).
currency to offset market – Success of this direct intervention
selling. depends on government’s supply
of international reserves and
• Either unilaterally or through extent of international
cooperative intervention. cooperation.
Direct Intervention to Offset a Strong
Currency
Why is the Currency Strengthening? Impact of Intervention
• Markets moving into that • As the government is selling its
currency (i.e., the preferred strong currency, it is essentially
currency) and away from other supplying the currency that the
markets are moving into (i.e., the
currencies. preferred currency).
– Interest rate differentials, safe • In doing so, the government is
haven effects, trade flows, increasing the supply of its currency
political and economic risk, in foreign exchange markets and
expectations of changes in peg, also potentially in its own domestic
etc. market.
• Government needs to sell its – The potential impact of increasing
currency to offset market the country’s domestic money supply
is to accelerate inflationary pressures
demand. and inflationary expectations for that
• Either unilaterally or through economy.
cooperative intervention. • Success of this direct intervention
depends on the extent of
international cooperation.
Non-sterilized Versus Sterilized Direct
Intervention
Non-sterilized Intervention Sterilized Intervention
• Defined as a central bank not • Defined as a central bank using
taking any action to offset the monetary policy actions to offset
the increase (decrease) in the
increase (or decrease) in the country domestic money supply
country’s domestic supply resulting from direct intervention
resulting from direct to offset a strong (weak)
intervention to offset a strong currency.
– Usually done through central bank
(weak) currency. open market operations,
• Likely to be followed if the specifically selling or buying
government securities through
central bank is not concerned domestic financial institutions.
about inflationary impacts or • Sales of government securities will
reduce bank reserves and
impacts on economic activity. purchases of government
securities will increase bank
– For example, Japan today. reserves (see slides which follow).
Text Book Exhibit of Non-sterilized
Versus Sterilized Intervention
• The illustration below shows an example of the U.S.
Central Bank (i.e., the Federal Reserve)intervening to
offset a strong US dollar against the Canadian dollar.
– The Fed wants to weaken the U.S. dollar and strengthen
the Canadian dollar.
Text Book Exhibit of Non-sterilized
Versus Sterilized Intervention
• Intervention can also produce reductions in a country’s
domestic money supply (i.e., if the government is buying
its currency and selling the preferred currency).
– In the illustration below, the Fed has used direct
intervention to strengthen the U.S. dollar and weaken the
Canadian dollar (i.e., offset USD selling on FX markets)
Indirect Intervention
• Indirect intervention generally involves two possible
actions:
– Adjusting domestic interest rates.
• Raising interest rates to support a weak currency – i.e., increasing the
interest rate differential in favor of the weak currency country.
• September 18, 1992, the Swedish Central Bank raised its marginal lending rate
to 500% to temporarily stem speculative pressures against the krona (SEK). At
the time the krona was pegged to a trade-weighted basket of 15 foreign
currencies (peg was dropped in December of 1992 and an independent float
was adopted).
• Lowering interest rates to offset a strong currency – i.e., decreasing
the interest rate differential in favor of the strong currency country.
– Assumption is that by adjusting the interest rate differential, the
demand for the currency is affected.
– Problem with interest rate adjustments:
• This policy may be inconsistent with domestic economy conditions
and required monetary policy stance for those conditions.
– For example, the U.K. in 1992 when part of the Exchange Rate Mechanism
(ERM) – UK needed lower interest rates to stimulate domestic demand, but
higher interest rates to maintain exchange rate in ERM.
Raising Interest Rates to Defend a
Currency
Interest Rates During the Interest Rates in Argentina,
Asian Currency Crisis 2002 @ 125% in August
Indirect Intervention
• A second type of indirect intervention involves the use of foreign
exchange controls.
– Defined: Government restrictions on transactions in the foreign
exchange market.
• Regulations on convertibility:
– Setting the amount of foreign exchange a resident can purchase and/or setting limits on
the amount of foreign exchange a domestic company can hold (from foreign sales) and
thus must sell “excess” back to government.
– Viet Nam Ordinance On Foreign Exchange Controls (Jan 31, 2010): “Residents must
remit all foreign currency amounts derived from export of goods and services into
a foreign currency account opened at an authorized credit institution in Vietnam. If
residents wish to retain foreign currency overseas, they must obtain approval from
the State Bank of Vietnam.”
• Regulations on market makers:
– Central bank (or government agency) is the only bank authorized to conduct foreign
exchange transactions.
• Regulation on types of transactions (i.e., capital controls):
– Permitting foreign exchange transactions resulting from commercial transactions, but not
from “speculative” transactions (e.g., closing the markets for short term capital flows).
– In 1997 (Sep 1), Malaysia, in response to the ringgit currency attack, imposed
capital controls which essentially closed down transactions in short term capital
movements out of the ringgit by requiring that any investment transactions
involving ringgits had to be held for 12 months in approved banks. Restriction was
lifted in December 2000.
Case Study of Malaysia’s Response
to the 1997 Currency Crisis
Sequence of Events Exchange Rate: USD/MYR
• During the mid 1990s, Malaysia attracts a
substantial volume of volatile capital (short term
and portfolio; i.e., mobile capital) which were
driven by the boom in the equity market (an equity
bubble occurs).
– FDI investment peaks in 1996; but volatile capital
inflows continue to rise.
• May 14-15, 1997: Malaysia ringgit comes under
attack. At the time the ringgit is highly managed to
the USD (@a rate of 2.5).
– Part of a contagion effect in Asia (started in Thailand)
– Market concerns about weak corporate governance
and weakness in the financial sector in Malaysia
results in outflows of volatile capital.
• July 2, 1997, Malaysia drops its managed float, and
the ringgit falls 18%, but the government continues
to use direct intervention to support the currency.
Malaysia continues to raise interest rates during the
crisis.
• September 1, 1997, Malaysia imposes a set of
capital controls which shut down the “offshore”
market in ringgit and stop “speculative trading.”
• September 2, 1998, Malaysia introduces a peg
regime (@3.8).
• Capital controls are lifted from Feb 1999 through
Jan 2003.
• July 21, 2005, Malaysia announces abolition of the
ringgit peg in favor of a managed float.
Case Study of U.K. Currency Crisis
of 1992
Background Germany’s Role in the ERM
• Britain joined the European • While the ERM included many
Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) European countries, Germany
in October 1990. was the leading player because of
– ERM was designed to promote its economic dominance.
exchange rate stability within
Europe. – Thus, the German mark was also
• Under the ERM, European the dominant currency in this
currencies were “pegged” to one arrangement and German
another at agreed upon rates. monetary policy set the tone for
the rest of the ERM members.
– In October 1990, the British
pound was “locked” into the • Thus, German monetary policy
German Mark at a central had to be followed by the other
rate of about DM2.9/£ members in order for the other
– General feeling at the time member states to keep their
was that this rate overvalued currencies aligned with the
the pound against the mark. German mark.
– This was especially true with regard
to Germany’s interest rate.
Case Study of U.K. Currency Crisis
of 1992
Events Leading up to the
The Attack and Response
Speculative Attack • Pound currency attack begin in September
• While the markets felt the pound was 1992
“overvalued” when it joined the ERM, a – Short selling of the pound was led by
combination of two critical events, one just hedge funds: particularly George Soros.
before and a second just after Britain joined • The British Government’s initial response to
the ERM convinced some in the market that the attack occurred on Wednesday,
the pound was now ready for speculation. September 16
• These events were: – Government raised interest rates twice
– The fall of the Berlin Wall in Nov 1989 from 10% to 12 and then to 15%
– The economic “recession” in the U.K. in 1991- • Attempt to make U.K. investments more
92. attractive.
• Fall of the Berlin Wall: As a result, German • During the attack the Bank of England used
decided to raise interest rates in order to $4 billion in hard currency in defense of the
attract needed capital for the reunification of pound. Bank of England bought $4 billion
East and West Germany. worth of pounds which were being sold short
– Other ERM countries need to follow with (it did this by selling U.S. dollars and German
higher interest rates.
• UK Recession: However, the issue for the U.K. marks to speculators).
was having to raise interest rates during their – Estimates: 1/3 of its hard currency was
recession. spent.
– A recession would be properly addressed by • On Wednesday at 7pm (UK time), the U.K.
lower interest rates. government announced they would be
– Thus there was both a political and economic leaving the ERM the next day and that
component to the potential decision to raise interest rates would go back to 10%.
rates.
– Markets thought the UK would not be willing (referred to as “Black Wednesday”).
to raise rates to defend the pound. – Thursday, September 17, the pound
returned to an independent float.
• By late October, the pound had fallen about
13% against the mark and 25% against the
U.S.
Sterling Exchange Rate Around the
Time of the 1992 Crisis
GBP/DEM GBP/USD

You might also like